Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-18T21:46:45.877Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conclusion: domestic structures and strategies of foreign economic policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Get access

Extract

An inventory of the objectives and instruments which characterize the differing political strategies of six advanced industrial states in the international economy yields three groups of states: the two Anglo-Saxon countries, mercantilist Japan, and the states of the European continent. Corresponding differences exist in the distinctive elements of domestic structure: the coalition between business and the state and the policy networks linking public and private sectors. An historical explanation of these differences is most appropriate. In the future, stresses in the relations between business and the state and contradictions between ruling coalitions and organized labor may lead to changes in political strategies.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See the special issue The Oil Crisis in Perspective,” Daedalus Vol. 104, No. 4 (Fall 1975)Google Scholar.

2 See the essay of Charles Maier in this volume.

3 See the introduction to this volume.

4 Krasner, Stephen D., Raw Materials Investments and American Foreign Policy (Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar, forthcoming), Chapter 2.

5 On the neglect of British industry in particular, see the essay by Stephen Blank in this volume.

6 For example, see Gilpin, Robert, US Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment (New York: Basic Books, 1975)Google Scholar. Despite that commitment, the British government was of course compelled to impose some restrictions on the outflow of sterling from 1966 on. See Hirsch, Fred, Money International (London: Allen Lane, the Penguin Press, 1967)Google Scholar.

7 Kiause, Lawrence B. and Sekiguchi, Sueo, “Japan and the World Economy,” in Asia's New Giant: How the Japanese Economy Works, Patrick, Hugh and Rosovsky, Henry, eds., (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1976), pp. 398402Google Scholar discuss the reasons why the Japanese strategy is not one of export-led growth.

8 With regard to import restrictions these three member states of the European Communities (EC) show relatively few differences.

9 LaPalombara, Joseph and Blank, Stephen, Multinational Corporations and National Elites: A Study in Tensions, A Research Report from The Conference Board's Division of Public Affairs Research (New York: The Conference Board, 1976), pp. 1317Google Scholar.

10 A search for patterns of policy should focus on the rows rather than the columns of Table 1. But such a search promises results only if the policy objectives were characterized more abstractly than is appropriate for this concluding essay.

11 Lowi, Theodore J., “American Business, Public Policy, Case-Studies, and Political Theory,” World Politics Vol. 16, No. 4 (07 1964): 677715Google Scholar. Schattschneider, Elmer E., Politics, Pressures and the Tariff (New York: Prentice-Hall, 1935)Google Scholar.

12 Gilpin, US Power and the Multinational Corporation.

13 On the system of administrative guidance in Japan see Trezise, Philip H. with the collaboration of Yukio Suzuki, “Politics, Government, and Economic Growth in Japan,” in Patrick, and Rosovsky, , p. 784Google Scholar.

14 See the essay by John Zysman in this volume.

15 Banca Commerciale Italiana, “The Italian Economy: Monetary Trends,” produced by the Research Department with the collaboration of Mario Monti (Università Bocconi and Università di Torino) 1 (09 1975): 11Google Scholar.

16 Huntington, Samuel P., “The Democratic Distemper,” The Public Interest 41 (Fall 1975): 2328Google Scholar.

17 Schurmann, Franz, The Logic of World Power: An Inquiry into the Origins, Currents, and Contradictions of World Politics (New York: Random House, 1974)Google Scholar, Part I.

18 Kirkpatrick, J. Sale, Power Shift: The Rise of the Southern Rim and its Challenge to the Eastern Establishment (New York: Random House, 1975)Google Scholar. Gelb, Leslie H., “The New American Establishment is Called the Community,” The New York Times, 12 19, 1976. Section 4, p. 1Google Scholar. See also Block, Fred, “Beyond Corporate Liberalism,” to be published in Social Problems, 1977Google Scholar.

19 Schurmann, pp. 8–13.

20 Wallace, William, The Foreign Policy Process in Britain (London: The Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1975), pp. 156–88Google Scholar. Riemer, Jeremiah M., “Challenging the Banker's View in Britain and West Germany,” (Ithaca: Cornell University, 1976)Google Scholar.

21 The overhang of sterling assets held abroad was of course an additional factor constraining British policy.

22 Blank, Stephen, Industry and Government in Britain: The Federation of British Industries in Politics, 1945–65 (Westmead, England and Lexington, Mass.: Saxon House and Lexington Books, 1973)Google Scholar.

23 Immenga, Ulrich, Participation by Banks in Other Branches of the Economy, Competition–Approximation of Legislation Series No. 25 (Brussels: Commission of the European Communities, 1975), pp. 2025Google Scholar. Due to the high rate of self-financing of British corporations the industrial and financial sectors of the British economy are less intimately linked than in other countries. See Channon, Derek F., The Strategy and Structure of British Enterprise (Boston: Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1973), p. 38Google Scholar.

24 Cowart, Andrew T., “The Economic Policies of European Governments: Part I, Monetary Policy,” prepared for delivery at the 1976 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, The Palmer House, Chicago, Illinois, 09 2–5, 1976, p. 7Google Scholar. Brenner, Michael J., “Functional Representation and Interest Group Theory: Some Notes on British Practice,” Comparative Policies Vol. 2, No. 1 (10 1969): 125Google Scholar. Beer, Samuel H., British Politics in the Collectivist Age (New York: Random House Vintage Books, 1969)Google Scholar.

25 McConnell, Grant, Private Power and American Democracy (New York: Random House Vintage Books, 1966), pp. 246–97Google Scholar.

26 Shapiro, Eli, Solomon, Ezra, and White, William L., Money and Banking, 5th ed. (New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, 1968)Google Scholar. Horvitz, Paul M., Monetary Policy and the Financial System (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1969)Google Scholar. Salamon, Lester M. et al. , The Money Committees: A Study of the House Banking and Currency Committee and the Senate Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs Committee The Ralph Nader Congress Project (New York: Grossman Publishers, 1975)Google Scholar.

27 Pastor, Robert A., “Legislative-Executive Relations and US Foreign Trade Policy: The Case of the Trade Act of 1974,” paper prepared for delivery at the 1976 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, The Palmer House, Chicago, Illinois, 09 25, 1976Google Scholar.

28 Brittain, Samuel, Steering the Economy: The Role of the Treasury, revised edition (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1971)Google Scholar.

29 Shonfield, Andrew, Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power (London: Oxford University Press, 1970), pp. 88120Google Scholar. Smith, Trevor, “Britain,” in Hayward, Jack and Watson, Michael, eds., Planning, Politics and Public Policy: The British, French and Italian Experience (London: Cambridge University Press, 1975), pp. 5269Google Scholar.

30 Thayer, Nathaniel B., How the Conservatives Rule Japan (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969)Google Scholar. Fukui, Haruhiro, Party in Power: The Japanese Liberal Democrats and Policy Making (Canberra: Australian National University Press, 1970)Google Scholar.

31 A number of readers of earlier drafts of this paper have pointed out to me that this interpretation of Japan's domestic structure is in partial disagreement with recent writings which stress the pluralist character of Japanese politics. This disagreement, I believe, is due to the difference in perspective. Japan specialists rightly point to the numerous and intense political conflicts which accompany policy making as evidence speaking against the interpretation of “Japan Incorporated.” What is striking, though, in comparative analysis is the fundamental underlying consensus which unites business, the government bureaucracy, and the LDP leadership, and which contains these conflicts. For a discussion of Japanese pluralism, sectionalism, and fractionalism see Patrick, Hugh and Rosovsky, Henry, “Japan's Economic Performance: An Overview,” in Patrick, and Rosovsky, , pp. 4851Google Scholar; Trezise and Suzuki, pp. 761, 786. Vogel, Ezra F., “Introduction: Toward More Accurate Concepts,” in Modern Japanese Organization and Decision-Making, Vogel, Ezra F., ed., (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975), pp. xv–xviiiGoogle Scholar. See also Gerald L. Curtis, “Big Business and Political Influence,” ibid., pp. 33–70.

32 For contrasting interpretations see, for example,The Japan-US Assembly: Proceedings of a Conference on Japan-US Economic Policy, 2 vols. (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 19751976)Google Scholar and Halliday, Jon and McCormack, Gavan, Japanese Imperialism Today: Co-prosperity in Greater East Asia (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1973)Google Scholar. See also Hellmann, Donald C., Japanese Foreign Policy and Domestic Politics (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1969)Google Scholar.

33 Yanaga, Chitoshi, Big Business in Japanese Politics (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971)Google Scholar. Yamamura, Kozo, Economic Policy in Postwar Japan: Growth versus Economic Democracy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1967)Google Scholar. Kaplan, Eugene J., Japan: The Government-Business Relationship (Washington, D.C.: US Department of Commerce, 1972)Google Scholar.

34 Johnson, Chalmers, ‘The Reemployment of Retired Government Bureaucrats in Japanese Big Business,” Asian Survey 14 (11 1974): 128Google Scholar. Pempel, T.J., “The Bureaucratization of Policymaking in Postwar Japan,” American Journal of Political Science Vol. 18, No. 4 (11 1974): 647–64Google Scholar.

35 Friedrich, Carl-Joachim, “The Political Thought of Neo-Liberalism,” American Political Science Review Vol. 49, No. 2 (06 1955): 509–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36 Willeke, Franz-Ulrich et al. , “Die Aufwertungsdebatte in der BRD in den Jahren 1968 und 1969,” Hamburger Jahrbuch fur Wirtschafts-und Gesellschaftspolitik 16 (1971): 287316Google Scholar.

37 Hankel, Wilhelm, “West Germany Before and After the Oil Shock: Crisis Management or Adjustment of a Free Market Economy?” (Washington, Georgetown University, 1976)Google Scholar. Hankel, Wilhelm, “Germany's Postwar Economic Policy: The Case for a Neo-Mercantilist Approach,” prepared for delivery at the XVII Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, 02 1976, Toronto, CanadaGoogle Scholar. Kindleberger, Charles P., “Germany's Persistent Balance-of Payments Disequilibrium Revisited,” German Studies Notes (Bloomington, Institute of German Studies, Indiana University, 1976)Google Scholar. For a more general and somewhat dated but still useful discussion see MacLennan, Malcolm, Forsyth, Murray, and Denton, Geoffrey, Economic Planning and Policies in Britain, France and Germany (New York: Praeger, 1968)Google Scholar.

38 Suleiman, Ezra N., Politics, Power and Bureaucracy in France: The Administrative Elite (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1974), pp. 352–71Google Scholar.

39 Shonfield, pp. 71–87, 121–75. Hayward and Watson.Zysman, John, Political Strategies for Industrial Order: Market, State and Industry in France (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977)Google Scholar. Cohen, Stephen, Modern Capitalist Planning: The French Experience, 2nd ed. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1976)Google Scholar.

40 Tarrow, Sidney, “The Italian Party System Between Crisis and Transition,” American Journal of Political Science (1977)Google Scholar.

41 Pasquino, Gianfianco and Pecchini, Umberto, “Italy,” in Hayward, and Watson, , pp. 7092Google Scholar. Prodi, Romano, “Italy,” in Big Business and the State: Changing Relations in Western Europe, Vernon, Raymond, ed., (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1974), pp. 4563Google Scholar.

42 Gilpin.p. 108.

43 Mayntz, Renate and Scharpf, Fritz, Policy-Making in the German Federal Bureaucracy (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1975)Google Scholar. Johnson, Nevil, Government in the Federal Republic of Germany: The Executive at Work (Oxford: Pergamon Press, 1973)Google Scholar.

44 Braunthal, Gerard, The Federation of German Industry in Politics (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1965)Google Scholar. Simon, Walter, Macht und Herrschaft der Unternehmerverbände BDI, BDA und DIHT (Cologne: Pahl-Rugenstein, 1976)Google Scholar.

41 Wadbrbok, William P., West German Balance-of-Payments Policy: The Prelude to European Monetary Integration (New York: Praeger, 1972)Google Scholar. See also the special issue of the WSI Mitteilungen Vol. 28, No. 7 (07 1975)Google Scholar.

46 Ehrmann, Henry W., Organized Business in France (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957)Google Scholar. McArthur, John H. and Scott, Bruce R., Industrial Planning in France (Boston: Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1969)Google Scholar.

47 Michalet, Charles-Albert, “France,” in Vernon, , Big Business and the State, pp. 105–25Google Scholar. Dyas, Gareth P. and Thanheiser, Heinz T., The Emerging European Enterprise: Strategy and Structure in French and German Industry (Boulder: Westview Press, 1977)Google Scholar.

48 Thoenig, Jean-Claude, “La Rélation entre le Centre et la Périphérie en France: Une Analyse Systematique,” Bulletin de l'Institut International d'Administration Publique 35 (12 1975): 77123Google Scholar.

49 LaPalombara, Joseph, Interest Groups in Italian Politics (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964)Google Scholar. Graziano, Luigi, A Conceptual Framework for the Study of Clientelism, Occasional Paper 2, Ithaca, Cornell University, Western Societies Program, 1975Google Scholar. Graziano, Luigi, “Patron-Client Relationships in Southern Italy,” European Journal of Political Research 1 (1973): 334Google Scholar.

50 Shonfield.p. 180.

51 Graziano, Luigi, “Center-Periphery Relations and the Italian Crisis: The Problem of Clientelism,” in Territorial Politics in Industrial Nations, Tarrow, Sidney, Katzenstein, Peter J., and Graziano, Luigi, eds., (New York: Praeger, forthcoming, 1978)Google Scholar.

52 Prodi, in Vernon, p. 61. See also LaPalombara, Joseph, Italy: The Politics of Planning (Syracuse: Syracuse University Press, 1966)Google Scholar. Holland, Stuart, ed., The State as Entrepreneur: New Dimensions for Public Enterprise: The IRI State Shareholding Formula (London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1972)Google Scholar.

53 Huntington, Samuel P., Political Order and Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968), pp. 93139Google Scholar. Gerschenkion, Alexander, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays (Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1962), pp. 530Google Scholar. Moore, Barrington, Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966)Google Scholar. This historical analysis of domestic structures has also been influenced by Bendix, Reinhard, Nation-Building and Citizenship: Studies of Our Changing Social Order (New York: John Wiley, 1964)Google Scholar. Binder, Leonard et al. , Crises and Sequences in Political Development (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971)Google Scholar. Almond, Gabriel, Flanagan, Scott C. and Mundt, Robert J., Crisis, Choice and Change: Historical Studies of Political Development (Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1973)Google Scholar. Tilly, Charles, ed., The Formation of National States in Western Europe (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975)Google Scholar.

54 Schmitter, Philippe C., “Still the Century of Corporatism?The Review of Politics Vol. 36, No. 1 (01 1974): 85131Google Scholar. Winkler, Henrich A., ed., Organisierter Kapitalismus: Voraussetzungen und Anfange (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck and Ruprecht, 1974)Google Scholar.

55 Hartz, Louis, The Liberal Tradition in America (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1955)Google Scholar. Lipset, Seymour Martin, The First New Nation: The United States in Historical and Comparative Perspective (New York: Basic Books, 1963)Google Scholar. Vogel, David, “Why Businessmen Mistrust Their State: The Political Consciousness of American Corporate Executives,” Paper prepared for delivery at the 1976 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, The Palmer House, Chicago, Illinois, 09 2–5, 1976Google Scholar.

56 Moore, pp. 3–39.Hill, J.E. Christopher, Puritanism and Revolution: Studies in the Interpretation of the English Revolution of the 17th Century (London: Seeker and Warburg, 1958)Google Scholar. Nef, John U., Industry and Government in France and England 1540–1640 (Philadelphia: The American Philosophical Society, 1940)Google Scholar.

57 Huntington, pp. 93–139.

58 Armstrong, John A., The European Administrative Elite (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1973)Google Scholar.

59 Moore, pp. 228–313.Lockwood, William W., The Economic Development of Japan: Growth and Structural Change 1868–1938 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1954)Google Scholar. Lockwood, William W., ed., The State and Economic Enterprise in Japan: Essays in the Political Economy of Growth (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965)Google Scholar.

60 Yanaga, pp. 32, 87–88.

61 Moore, pp. 433–52. Carsten, F.L., The Origins of Prussia (London: The Clarendon Press, 1954)Google Scholar. Gerschenkron, Alexander, Bread and Democracy in Germany (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1943)Google Scholar. Hamerow, Theodore S., Restoration, Revolution, Reaction: Economics and Politics in Germany, 1815–1871 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1958)Google Scholar.

62 Varain, Heinz Josef, ed., Interessenverbände in Deutschland (Cologne: Kiepenheuer and Witsch, 1973)Google Scholar.

63 Montgomery, John D., Forced to be Free: The Artificial Revolution in Germany and Japan (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1957)Google Scholar. Lichtfield, Edward H. et al. , Governing Postwar Germany, 2 vols (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1953)Google Scholar.

64 Potter, David, People of Plenty: Economic Abundance and the American Character (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1954)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

65 Moore, pp. 40–110. Ford, Franklin L., Robe and Sword: The Regrouping of the French Aristocracy after Louis XIV (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1953)Google Scholar. Zeldin, Theodore, France, 1848–1945 (Oxford: The Clarendon Press, 1973)Google Scholar.

66 Weber, Max, The Theory of Social and Economic Organization (New York: The Free Press, 1964), p. 315Google Scholar.

67 Shefter, Martin, “Patronage and its Opponents: A Theory and Some European Cases,” paper prepared for delivery at the Conference on the Scope and Practice of Social Science History, sponsored by the Western European Area Studies Program, University of Wisconsin, Madison, and the Social Science History Association, 04 23–24, 1976Google Scholar, Madison, Wisconsin.

68 I would like to thank Miles Kahler for pointing out to me this connection between the Gaullist reform period and the Meiji Restoration. His comment was prompted by Trimberger, Ellen Kay, “A Theory of Elite Revolutions,” Studies in Comparative International Development Vol. 7, No. 3 (1973): 191207CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

69 Gramsci, Antonio, Selections from the Prison Notebooks (New York: International Publishers, 1971), pp. 44121Google Scholar. Graziano, “Center-Periphery Relations.”

70 Gerschenkron, pp. 72–118. Gerschenkron, Alexander, Continuity in History and Other Essays (Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1968), pp. 98127Google Scholar. Kurth, James R., “Industrial Structure and Comparative Politics,” (Cambridge, Center for European Studies, 1975), pp. 612Google Scholar.

71 Besides the sources in footnote 57, this section is also heavily indebted to Gerschenkron, , Continuity in History, pp. 7797Google Scholar.

72 Lindbeig, Leon N. et al. , eds., Stress and Contradiction in Modern Capitalism (Lexington, Mass.: D.C. Heath, 1975)Google Scholar.

73 Junne, Gerd, Der Eurogeldmarkt: Seine Bedeutung für Inflation und Inflationsbekämpfung (Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, 1976)Google Scholar.

74 Kelley, Janet, Bankers and Borders: The Case of the American Banks in Britain (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, in press)Google Scholar, Table 8.1.

75 Sawyer, Malcolm, “Income Distribution in OECD Countries,” OECD Economic Outlook: Occasional Studies (Paris: OECD, 1976)Google Scholar. See also United Nations, Secretariat of the Economic Commission for Europe, Incomes in Postwar Europe: A Study of Politics, Growth, and Distribution, Economic Survey of Europe in 1965: Part 2 (Geneva: United Nations Publications, 1967)Google Scholar. Pyror, Frederic L., Property and Industrial Organization in Communist and Capitalist Nations (Bloomington: Indian University Press, 1973)Google Scholar. Schnitzer, Martin, Income Distribution: A Comparative Study of the United States, Sweden, West Germany, East Germany, the United Kingdom, and Japan (New York: Praeger, 1974)Google Scholar. Cameron, David R., “Inequality and the State: A Political-Economic Comparison,” paper prepared for delivery at the 1976 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, The Palmer House, Chicago, Illinois, 09 2–5, 1976Google Scholar.

76 The role of labor movements more generally is discussed in Barkin, Solomon, ed., Worker Militancy and its Consequences 1965–1975 (New York: Praeger, 1975)Google Scholar and in two issues edited by John P. Windmuller dealing with European Labor and Politics. See Industrial and Labor Relations Review Vol. 28, No. 1 (10 1974)Google Scholar and Vol. 28, No. 2 (January 1975).