Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T19:55:50.781Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - Measuring earnings differentials with frontier functions and Rao distances

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 March 2010

Paul Marriott
Affiliation:
National University of Singapore
Mark Salmon
Affiliation:
City University Business School, London
Get access

Summary

Introduction

In a seminal paper Rao (1945) introduced the concept of ‘Geodesic Distance’ (or ‘Rao Distance’) into statistics. This concept has important theoretical properties and is based on the demanding differential-geometrical approach to statistics. These mathematical requirements and difficulties in its application are responsible for the low level of familiarity by econometricians with this generalisation of the well-known Mahalanobis distance. Econometricians require some detailed knowledge of Riemannian geometry to gain a complete understanding of Rao distances. Section 2 provides a short introduction to the necessary theory on Rao distances, hyperbolic curvature, isocircles and Rao distance tests.

Since their original development in the paper by Aigner and Chu (1968), frontier functions have served almost exclusively for estimating production and cost functions consistently with an economic theory of optimising behaviour. In section 3 of this chapter, an extended human capital model is estimated as a stochastic earnings frontier with data from the German socio-economic panel. This provides a deeper interpretation of the deviations of observed income from estimated income. Distinguishing between ‘potential human capital’ and ‘active human capital’ accounts for the partial failure of human capital models when estimated as average functions.

There has been a tendency in Germany for the number of years of education attained to increase, in part owing to the combination of an apprenticeship with university studies. Büchel and Helberger (1995) call this combination an inefficient ‘insurance strategy’ pursued mainly by children from low-income and low-education families because of low efficiency or high risk-aversion.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×