Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-r5zm4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-19T15:30:34.622Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Energy Politics in Canada, 1980–1981: Threat Power in a Sequential Game*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 November 2009

Patrick James
Affiliation:
Florida State University

Abstract

Over a decade ago, the federal Liberal government announced one of the most controversial policy initiatives in Canadian history, the National Energy Program (NEP). The bargaining that followed the NEP's announcement on October 28, 1980 is easily recalled; intense disagreements focussed on economic, partisan and, ultimately, constitutional issues. While these events have stimulated a wide range of investigations, a prominent gap exists in the scholarship: very few studies adopt a game-theoretic perspective. In seeking to explain strategic interaction over energy policy, such an approach might increase understanding of the difficult political processes surrounding the NEP in a wider context.

These are five stages to the game-theoretic investigation that follows. First, a brief history of the phase of confrontation is provided. Second, the game-theoretic interpretation is presented in general terms, including participants, strategies and potential outcomes. Relevant measurements are derived in the third phase. In the fourth stage, the process of a sequential game is analyzed, in both abstract and operational terms. Fifth, and finally, policy-related implications of the analysis are discussed, along with possible directions for further research.

Résumé

Il y a plus d'une décennie, le gouvernement fédérale libéral annonçait une politique parmi les plus controversées dans l'histoire du Canada: le Programme national de l'énergie (PNE). On se souviendra facilement des négociations qui ont suivi l'annonce du PNE le 28 octobre 1980; des désaccords violents se concentraient sur les questions économiques, partisanes, et constitutionnelles. Quoique ces événements aient suscité une pléthore d'investigations, une lacune évidente existe dans la documentation: très peu d'études suivent le modèle de la théorie des jeux. Quand on cherche à expliquer l'intéraction stratégique concernant la politique énergétique, une telle approche pourrait clarifier les procédures politiques difficiles autour du PNE dans un contexte plus large.

Il y a cinq étapes à l'investigation basée sur le modèle de la théorie des jeux suivant. Premièrement, un bref historique de la phase de confrontation est fourni. Deuxièmement, l'interprétation selon le modèle de la théorie des jeux est présentée en termes généraux, par exemple, participants, stratégies, et conséquences éventuelles. Des mesures pertinentes viennent de la troisième phase. À la quatrième étape, le processus d'un jeu séquentiel est analysé, dans le sens abstrait comme dans le sens pratique. À la cinquième étape, finalement, on décrit des conséquences liées à la politique de l'analyse, avec des voies de recherche éventuelles.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association (l'Association canadienne de science politique) and/et la Société québécoise de science politique 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Pollard, Bruce G., “Canadian Energy Policy in 1985: Toward a Renewed Federalism?,” Publius 16 (1986), 164.Google Scholar

2 Jenkins, Barbara, “Reassessing the ‘Obsolescing Bargain’: A Study of Canada's National Energy Program,” International Organization 40 (1986), 139–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Doern, G. Bruce and Toner, Glen, The Politics of Energy: The Development and Implementation of the NEP (Toronto: Methuen, 1985).Google Scholar

4 James, Patrick and Michelin, Robert, “The Canadian National Energy Program and Its Aftermath: Perspectives on an Era of Confrontation,” American Review of Canadian Studies 19 (1989), 5981.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

5 Excellent introductions to game theory may be obtained from Davis, Morton D., Game Theory: A Nontechnical Introduction (rev. ed.; New York: Basic Books, 1983)Google Scholar; Friedman, James W., Game Theory with Applications to Economics (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; Shubik, Martin, Game Theory in the Social Sciences: Concepts and Solutions (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1982)Google Scholar; and Zagare, Frank C., Game Theory (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1984).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6 Uslaner, Eric M., Shale Barrel Politics: Energy and Legislative Leadership (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1989)Google Scholar; and James, Patrick, “The Canadian National Energy Program and Its Aftermath: A Game-theoretic Analysis,” Canadian Public Policy 16 (1990), 174–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 Doern, and Toner, , The Politics of Energy, 7.Google Scholar

8 The following description of the Alberta proposals is based on Scarfe, Brian L., “The Federal Budget and Energy Program, October 28th, 1980: A Review,” Canadian Public Policy 7 (1981), 11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 James, , “The Canadian National Energy Program,” 182.Google Scholar

10 Doern, and Toner, , The Politics of Energy, 45.Google Scholar

11 Ibid., 44. Usianer's study of voting in that election supports the position that energy policy affected the outcome significantly: the energy issue seemed to mobilize strong supporters of each party “above and beyond the effects of party I.D. and party leader evaluations.” See Uslaner, Eric M., “Looking Forward and Looking Backward: Prospective and Retrospective Voting in the 1980 Federal Election in Canada,” British Journal of Political Science 19 (1989), 495513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 When provincial leaders have adopted platforms that emphasize conciliation, potential benefits for the province, as opposed to the national interest, are stressed when communicating with voters.

13 The Albertans knew that the Trudeau government intended to tie the NEP to patriation of the constitution; in fact, when signing the 1981 Agreement (to be described at a later point), Lougheed emphasized his continuing opposition to Ottawa's patriation plan (The Globe and Mail, September 3, 1981, 11Google Scholar). The Albertans hoped that retaliation would delay implementation of the NEP long enough that, in order to succeed with the constitutional initiative, the federal Liberals would have to drop the energy issue.

14 Doern, and Toner, , The Politics of Energy, 44.Google Scholar

15 The full statement of the Program appears in Energy, Mines and Resources Canada, The National Energy Program (Ottawa, 1980).Google Scholar

16 Grant, John, “Foreign Investment: Turning Off and Turning On,” Canadian Public Policy 9 (1983), 33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

17 The Globe and Mail, November 3, 1980, 1Google Scholar; and November 1, 1980, 14. Scarfe (“The Federal Budget and Energy Program,” 11) summed up the general reaction within Alberta to the federal initiatives: “Perhaps it is understandable why so many Western Canadians, and not just those resident in Alberta, are angered and bewildered by the Lalonde energy policy and the MacEachen budget, and why the oil and gas producing industry is considering drastic retrenchment of its activities. For the energy program contained in the budget is an affront to our economic intelligence, and an attack on our regional interests.”

18 The Globe and Mail, November 1, 1980, 14.Google Scholar

19 Maclean's, March 2, 1981.Google Scholar

20 The Globe and Mail, March 3, 1981, 1.Google Scholar

21 The following description of the Agreement is taken from The Globe and Mail, September 2, 1981, 1.Google Scholar

22 The Agreement also restricted taxation changes during the life of the Agreement. One study described the IORT as follows: “[It] is to be levied at 50 per cent of the incremental revenues on old oil. These revenues are equal to production of old oil times the difference between the old oil price and the price established in the NEP, after subtracting the provincial royalties from both prices.” See Helliwell, John F. and McRae, Robert N., “Resolving the Energy Conflict: From the National Energy Program to the Energy Agreement,” Canadian Public Policy 8 (1982), 16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 James, and Michelin, , “The Canadian National Energy Program and Its Aftermath”Google Scholar; Nordlinger, Eric A., On the Autonomy of the Democratic State (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1981), 1.Google Scholar

24 James, and Michelin, , “The Canadian National Energy Program and Its Aftermath,” 69Google Scholar, described that type of behaviour as a reflection of Type II state autonomy (Nordlinger, , On the Autonomy of the Democratic StateGoogle Scholar). When state and societal preferences diverge initially, public officials “attempt to change societal preferences and, once successful, to translate the now-similar preferences into public policy.”

25 Uslaner, (Shale Barrel Politics, 178Google Scholar) also concluded in favour of a two-person game, implicitly noting the role of other actors such as interest groups: “we can readily model events as a two-person (two-party) game. Cleavages reinforce each other so that the bargaining model is easier to depict.”

26 Milne, David, Tug of War: Ottawa and the Provinces under Trudeau and Mulroney (Toronto: James Lorimer, 1986).Google Scholar

27 Dome Petroleum should be noted as an exception within A's implicit coalition. It took advantage of federal initiatives and supported the general aims of the NEP. However, neither Dome nor other companies functioned as independent players in the EG, so the two-actor assumption is not threatened by the existence of this anomaly.

28 Friedman, , Game Theory, 148.Google Scholar

29 In James, , “The Canadian National Energy Program and Its Aftermath,” 177Google Scholar, which focussed strictly on outcomes, intergovernmental bargaining is described as leaning toward “the co-operative end of the game spectrum” and suitable for consideration “in the context of co-operative game theory.” The EG, however, remains non-co-operative in the literal sense, because the players can reject the details of an agreement derived at any intermediate stage. The arguments about costs of breaking an agreement become relevant only when a formal, public deal exists.

30 Simeon, Richard, “Natural Resource Revenues and Canadian Federalism: A Survey of the Issues,” Canadian Public Policy 6 (1980), 182CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Courchene, Thomas J., “Energy Revenues: Consequences for the Rest of Canada,” Canadian Public Policy 6 (1980), 192CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Norrie, Kenneth, “Energy, Canadian Federalism and the West,” Publius 14 (1984), 7991Google Scholar; and Ruitenbeek, Jack, “Economics of In-Situ Oilsands Production: Some Implications for Public Policy,” Canadian Public Policy 11 (1985), 407–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

31 Helliwell, and McRae, , “Resolving the Energy Conflict.”Google Scholar

32 Zagare, , Game Theory, 37.Google Scholar

33 Doern, and Toner, , The Politics of Energy, 311.Google Scholar

34 Helliwell, John F. and McRae, Robert N., “The National Energy Conflict,” Canadian Public Policy 7 (1981), 20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 The Globe and Mail, November 1, 1980, 1.Google Scholar

36 Doern, and Toner, , The Politics of Energy, 312Google Scholar; Helliwell, and McRae, , “The National Energy Conflict”Google Scholar and “Resolving the Energy Conflict.”

37 Uslaner, , Shale Barrel Politics, 177.Google Scholar

38 Helliwell, and McRae, , “Resolving the Energy Conflict.”Google Scholar

39 Uslaner, (Shale Barrel Politics, 174)Google Scholar compared rent shares for Albertans to those of Canadians outside of Alberta (as computed by Helliwell, and McRae, , “The National Energy Conflict,” 17Google Scholar), rather than looking at the rents accruing directly to the governments. However, for present purpuses, that would build in an undesired element of pure conflict. In the sequential game, F also had a long-term interest in every province's degree of satisfaction with the result. Although it wanted to limit A's revenues, an extreme outcome would spell a virtual end to further national integration. To incorporate this federal priority, it is appropriate to look at overall revenues. Given the nature of the data generated by Helliwell and McRae, that entails a comparison of federal-provincial rents.

40 James, , “The Canadian National Energy Program.”Google Scholar

41 The cumulative rents over the life of each scenario also would be a useful indicator of relative worth. However, devising a means of comparison among O1 through O4 is complicated by the need to decide a relevant “lifetime” for each scenario, along with the performance of calculations further removed from the original data.

42 Helliwell, and McRae, , “Resolving the Energy Conflict,” 14.Google Scholar

43 Helliwell, and McRae, , “The National Energy Conflict.”Google Scholar Another aspect concerns the comparability of statistics. Other reliable sources do not provide data on the complete set of outcomes. Examples are Gorbet, F. W., “Energy Self-Sufficiency: A Realistic and Desirable Goal?,” Canadian Public Policy 6 (1980), 472–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Copithorne, Lawrence, MacFadeyn, Alan and Bell, Bruce, “Revenue Sharing and the Efficient Valuation of Natural Resources,” Canadian Public Policy 11 (1985), 465–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

44 A game is considered strictly ordinal when all preferences over outcomes are expressed as “X is better than Y,” as opposed to permitting weak preferences such as “X is at least as good or better than Y.”

45 The game corresponds to #63 and #47 in the respective lists from Brams, Steven J., “Deception in 2 × 2 Games,” Journal of Peace Science 2 (1977), 171203CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Rapoport, Anatol and Guyer, M., “A Taxonomy of 2 × 2 Games,” General Systems: Yearbook of the Society for General Systems Research 13 (1966), 195201.Google Scholar

46 Brams, Steven J. and Wittman, Donald, “Nonmyopic Equilibria in 2 × 2 Games,” Conflict Management and Peace Science 6 (1981), 3962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

47 See, for example, Deutsch, Karl W., The Analysis of International Relations (3rd ed.; Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1988), 156.Google Scholar

48 See Selten, R., “Chain-Store Paradox,”Google Scholar Working Paper no. 18, Institute of Mathematical Economics, Universitat Bielefeld. In Ordeshook's presentation of the Paradox, specification of the players' strategies entails estimates of probabilities that can change over iterations of the game; for example, at each stage it is necessary to update the probability that a potential antagonist believes that the principal player (known as the “chain store”) will resist competition. See Ordeshook, Peter C., Game Theory and Political Theory: An Introduction (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), 451–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

49 A few possibilities would include potash in Saskatchewan, hydro-electric power produced in Newfoundland, sulphur in Alberta and pulpwood in British Columbia. See Bushnell, S. I., “The Control of Natural Resources through the Trade and Commerce Power and Property Rights,” Canadian Public Policy 6 (1980), 313–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Copithorne, Lawrence, “Natural Resources and Regional Disparities: A Skeptical View,” Canadian Public Policy 5 (1979), 181–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Laforest, Gerald V., “Jurisdiction over Natural Resources: Provincial and Federal,” in Crabbe, Philippe and Spry, Irene M., eds., Natural Resources Development in Canada: Multi-Disciplinary Seminar (Ottawa: University of Ottawa Press, 1973).Google Scholar

50 Brams, and Wittman, , “Nonmyopic Equilibria.”Google Scholar

51 Brams, Steven J. and Hessel, Marek P., “Threat Power in Sequential Games,” International Studies Quarterly 28 (1984), 26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

53 Ibid., 27.

55 Ibid., 29.

56 Ibid., 33.

57 Ibid., 30.

58 For a helpful discussion of risk-taking and brinkmanship, see Dixit, Avinash K. and Nalebuff, Barry J., Thinking Strategically (New York: W. W. Norton, 1991), 286–99.Google Scholar

59 Uslaner, , Shale Barrel Politics, 174, 176Google Scholar; and Helliwell, and McRae, , “The National Energy Conflict,” 17.Google Scholar

60 Uslaner, (Shale Barrel Politics, 176)Google Scholar found CC to be the “Nash solution” to the bargaining problem of maximizing the product of joint gains for A and F relative to the stalemate.

61 One other factor points toward F's preference for the stalemate: following A's retaliation, the pricing and taxation incentives and subsidies in the NEP would make exploration in the Canada Lands even more attractive than before.

62 Young, Robert A., “Political Scientists, Economists, and the Canada-US Free Trade Agreement,” Canadian Public Policy 15 (1989), 54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

63 James, , “The Canadian National Energy Program.”Google Scholar

64 Helliwell, John F. et al. , “The Western Accord and Lower World Oil Prices,” Canadian Public Policy 12 (1986), 344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

65 Pollard, , “Canadian Energy Policy in 1985,” 169Google Scholar. The Accord called for the deregulation of domestic crude oil prices as of June 1, 1985, effectively dismantling the complex, two-tier pricing system which had been established by the 1981 Agreement. It marked the end of the Petroleum Compensation Charge (PCC) and the Oil Export Charge (OEC). The Accord also removed all transportation subsidies in the energy sector and every control on shortterm oil exports. Furthermore, it eliminated the IORT and the NGGLT. Although already at zero and thus not major financial concerns of the negotiators, the removal of these taxes had symbolic importance. The Accord also saw the phasing out of the Petroleum Incentives Payments (PIP), which Alberta followed up with termination of its own, similar program (Helliwell, et al. , “The Western Accord,” 344).Google Scholar

66 Helliwell, et al. , “The Western Accord,” 342.Google Scholar

67 For an introduction to the concept of a scientific research enterprise, consult James, Patrick, “Neorealism as a Research Enterprise: Toward Elaborated Structural Realism,” International Political Science ReviewGoogle Scholar, forthcoming.