Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vvkck Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T14:39:49.405Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

11 - Resource constraints and linear programming

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 May 2010

Don Dayananda
Affiliation:
Central Queensland University
Richard Irons
Affiliation:
Central Queensland University
Steve Harrison
Affiliation:
University of Queensland
John Herbohn
Affiliation:
University of Queensland
Patrick Rowland
Affiliation:
Curtin University of Technology, Perth
Get access

Summary

So far we have assumed that the firm's market value or the shareholders' wealth is maximized by accepting every investment project that has a positive NPV. In the real world, however, there are limitations on the investment programme that prevent the firm from undertaking all such projects. There may, for example, be a limit on the amount of funds available for financing investment projects. This is often called capital rationing.

Clearly, capital rationing does exist in the real world. If projects have positive NPVs and both management and financiers are happy with the NPV estimates, then, in an efficient capital market, one would expect funds to be available for all positive NPV projects. Under these circumstances, capital rationing is irrational. Nevertheless, two types of capital rationing are often encountered. Sometimes, management imposes capital expenditure limits; this is called soft capital rationing. Sometimes, a firm is unable to raise funds to undertake all positive NPV projects, and this is referred to as hard capital rationing. Various reasons have been advanced as to why hard or soft capital rationing might exist (Weingartner, 1977).

Apparently viable projects can also be rejected because firms face various other resource constraints, such as the availability of particular types of labour and raw material. Government regulations or marketing strategies may also impose restrictions. Specific methods such as the profitability index, which involve ‘juggling’ positive NPV project expenditures to ensure that total combined NPV is maximized from the investment decision, can handle decisions associated with a single constraint.

Type
Chapter
Information
Capital Budgeting
Financial Appraisal of Investment Projects
, pp. 204 - 218
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2002

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×