Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vfjqv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T22:15:48.828Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - Dyadic contests: modelling fights between two individuals

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2013

Ian C. W. Hardy
Affiliation:
University of Nottingham
Mark Briffa
Affiliation:
University of Plymouth
Get access

Summary

Summary

Animal contests were the focal topic that brought game theory to the attention of behavioural ecologists, giving rise to evolutionary game theory. Game theory has remained by far the most popular method of deriving theoretical predictions ever since, although it nowadays coexists with other methods of analysis. Here I review the developments to date and highlight similarities and differences between models. There is a clear progression from simple two-player models with fixed payoffs to explicit tracking of fitness consequences in a population context. In many cases this development has helped to discover that some of the early predictions may have been misleading. Despite the large number of current models, there are still gaps in the theoretical literature: sometimes simplifying assumptions have been relaxed in one context but not another. I hope that by highlighting these gaps theoreticians will be provided with new research ideas, and empiricists will be encouraged not only to distinguish between existing models but to be able to point out assumptions that are essential for deriving a result yet may be violated in existing systems, thus directing new modelling in the most useful direction.

Introduction

Until the mid 1960s, animal contests were viewed using group selectionist thinking. Julian Huxley (1966) thought that ritualised fights evolved to limit intraspecific damage, partly based on Konrad Lorenz's (1964, 1965) ideas that species need to evolve mechanisms that limit aggression in species that possess dangerous weapons for other reasons, e.g. as adaptations for capturing prey. Following George C. Williams’ (1966) book Adaptation and Natural Selection: A Critique of Some Current Thought, however, biologists became aware of the need to distinguish between explanations that are based on benefits to the individual versus those that rely on benefits accruing to a group (or a species).

Type
Chapter
Information
Animal Contests , pp. 5 - 32
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adams, ES & Mesterton-Gibbons, M (1995) The cost of threat displays and the stability of deceptive communication. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 175, 405–421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnott, G & Elwood, RW (2009) Assessment of fighting ability in animal contests. Animal Behaviour, 77, 991–1004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austad, SN, Jones, WT & Waser, PM (1979) Territorial defence in speckled wood butterflies: Why does the resident always win?Animal Behaviour, 27, 960–961.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backwell, PRY & Jennions, MD (2004) Coalition among male fiddler crabs. Nature, 430, 417.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Backwell, PRY, Christy, JH, Telford, SR, et al. (2000) Dishonest signalling in a fiddler crab. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B, 267, 719–724.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belsky, G & Gilovich, T (1999) Why smart People Make Big Money Mistakes – And How to Correct Them: Lessons from the New Science of Behavioral Economics. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Bishop, DT & Cannings, C (1978) A generalized war of attrition. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 70, 85–124.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bishop, DR, Cannings, C & Maynard Smith, J (1978) The war of attrition with random rewards. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 74, 377–388.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cant, MA & Johnstone, RA (2000) Power struggles, dominance testing and reproductive skew. American Naturalist, 155, 406–417.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cant, MA, English, S, Reeve, HK, et al. (2006). Escalated conflict in a social hierarchy. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B, 273, 2977–2984.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, CW (1994) Antipredator behavior and the asset-protection principle. Behavioral Ecology, 5, 159–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crowley, PH (2000) Hawks, doves, and mixed-symmetry games. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 204, 543–563.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Crowley, PH (2001) Dangerous games and the emergence of social structure: Evolving memory-based strategies for the generalized Hawk–Dove game. Behavioral Ecology, 12, 753–760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Curio, E (1987) Animal decision-making and the Concorde fallacy. Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 2, 148–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, NB (1978) Territorial defence in the speckled wood butterfly (Pararge aegeria): The resident always wins. Animal Behaviour, 26, 138–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, NB (1979) Game theory and territorial behaviour in speckled wood butterflies. Animal Behaviour, 27, 961–962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunham, ML, Warner, RR & Lawson, JW (1995) The dynamics of territory acquisition: A model of two coexisting strategies. Theoretical Population Biology, 47, 347–364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elwood, RW & Briffa, M (2001) Information gathering and communication during agonistic encounters: A case study of hermit crabs. Advances in the Study of Behaviour, 30, 53–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enquist, M (1985) Communication during aggressive interactions with particular reference to variation in choice of behaviour. Animal Behaviour, 33, 1152–1161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enquist, M & Leimar, O (1983) Evolution of fighting behaviour: Decision rules and assessment of relative strength. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 102, 387–410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enquist, M & Leimar, O (1987) Evolution of fighting behaviour: The effect of variation in resource value. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 127, 187–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enquist, M & Leimar, O (1990) The evolution of fatal fighting. Animal Behaviour, 39, 1–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eshel, I (2005) Asymmetric population games and the legacy of Maynard Smith: From evolution to game theory and back?Theoretical Population Biology, 68, 11–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eshel, I & Sansone, E (1995) Owner–intruder conflict, Grafen effect and self-assessment. The Bourgeois principle re-examined. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 177, 341–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eshel, I & Sansone, E (2001) Multiple asymmetry and concord resolutions of a conflict. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 213, 209–222.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Falster, DS & Westoby, M (2003) Plant height and evolutionary games. Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 18, 337–343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, SA & Hardy, ICW (2000) Butterfly contests: Contradictory but not paradoxical. Animal Behaviour, 59, F1–F3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, RA (1930) The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fromhage, L & Schneider, JM (2005) Virgin doves and mated hawks: Contest behaviour in a spider. Animal Behaviour, 70, 1099–1104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grafen, A (1979) The Hawk–Dove game played between relatives. Animal Behaviour, 27, 905–907.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grafen, A (1987) The logic of divisively asymmetric contests: Respect for ownership and the desperado effect. Animal Behaviour, 35, 462–467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haccou, P & Glaizot, O (2002) The ESS in an asymmetric generalized war of attrition with mistakes in role perception. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 214, 329–349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamblin, S & Hurd, PL (2007) Genetic algorithms and non-ESS solutions to game theory models. Animal Behaviour, 74, 1005–1018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, WD (1967) Extraordinary sex ratios. Science, 156, 477–488.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hammerstein, P (1981) The role of asymmetries in animal contests. Animal Behaviour, 29, 193–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammerstein, P & Parker, GA (1982) The asymmetric war of attrition. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 96, 647–682.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammerstein, P & Riechert, SE (1988) Payoffs and strategies in territorial contests: ESS analyses of two ecotypes of the spider Agelenopsis aperta. Evolutionary Ecology, 2, 115–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Härdling, R (1999) Arms races, conflict costs and evolutionary dynamics. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 196, 163–167.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Härdling, R & Kokko, H (2005) The evolution of prudent choice. Evolutionary Ecology Research, 7, 697–715.Google Scholar
Hardy, ICW & Field, SA (1998) Logistic analysis of animal contests. Animal Behaviour, 56, 787–792.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hernández, MIM & Benson, WW (1998) Small-male advantage in the territorial tropical butterfly Heliconius sara (Nymphalidae): A paradoxical strategy? Animal Behaviour, 56, 533–540.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Houston, AI & McNamara, JM (1991) Evolutionarily stable strategies in the repeated Hawk–Dove game. Behavioral Ecology, 2, 219–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsu, Y, Earley, RL & Wolf, LL (2006) Modulation of aggressive behaviour by fighting experience: Mechanisms and contest outcomes. Biological Reviews, 81, 33–74.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hurd, PL (1997) Is signalling of fighting ability costlier for weaker individuals?Journal of Theoretical Biology, 184, 83–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hurd, PL & Enqvist, M (1998) Conventional signalling in aggressive interactions: The importance of temporal structure. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 192, 197–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hurd, PL & Ydenberg, RC (1996) Calculating the ESS level of information transfer in aggressive communication. Evolutionary Ecology, 10, 221–232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huxley, JS (1966) Introduction: A discussion on ritualization of behaviour in animals and man. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 251, 249–271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnstone, RA & Norris, K (1993) Badges of status and the cost of aggression. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology, 32, 127–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jormalainen, V (1998) Precopulatory mate guarding in crustaceans: Male competitive strategy and intersexual conflict. Quarterly Review of Biology, 73, 275–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Just, W & Morris, MR (2003) The Napoleon complex: Why small males pick fights. Evolutionary Ecology, 17, 509–522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Just, W, Morris, MR & Sun, X (2007) The evolution of aggressive losers. Behavioural Processes, 74, 342–350.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kemp, DJ (2006) Ageing, reproductive value, and the evolution of lifetime fighting behaviour. Biological Journal of the Linnean Society, 88, 565–578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kemp, DJ & Wiklund, C (2004) Residency effects in animal contests. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B, 271, 1707–1711.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kokko, H (1997) Evolutionarily stable strategies of age-dependent sexual advertisement. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology, 41, 99–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kokko, H (2007) Modelling for Field Biologists and Other Interesting People. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kokko, H & López-Sepulcre, A (2007) The ecogenetic link between demography and evolution: Can we bridge the gap between theory and data?Ecology Letters, 10, 773–782.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kokko, H, López-Sepulcre, A & Morrell, LJ (2006) From hawks and doves to self-consistent games of territorial behavior. American Naturalist, 167, 901–912.Google ScholarPubMed
Korona, R (1991) On the role of age and body size in risky animal contests. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 152, 165–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kummer, H (1971) Primate Societies. Chicago, IL: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Leimar, O & Enquist, M (1984) Effects of asymmetries in owner–intruder conflicts. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 111, 475–491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López-Sepulcre, A & Kokko, H (2005) Territorial defence, territory size, and population regulation. American Naturalist, 166, 317–329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lorenz, K (1964) Ritualized fighting. In: Carthy, JD & Ebling, FJ (eds.) The Natural History of Aggression, pp. 39–50. London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Lorenz, K (1965) On Aggression (translated from Das Sogenannte Böse. Vienna: Borotha-Shoeler, 1963). London: Methuen & Co. Ltd.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, J (1974). The theory of games and the evolution of animal conflicts. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 47, 209–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J (1976) Evolution and the theory of games. American Scientist, 64, 41–45.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, J (1982) Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J & Harper, DGC (1988) The evolution of aggression: Can selection generate variability?Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 319, 557–570.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Maynard Smith, J & Parker, GA (1976) The logic of asymmetric contests. Animal Behaviour, 4, 159–175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J & Price, GR (1973) The logic of animal conflict. Nature, 246, 15–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McElreath, R, Luttbeg, B, Fogarty, SP, et al. (2007) Evolution of animal personalities. Nature, 450, E5.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McGill, BJ & Brown, JS (2007) Evolutionary game theory and adaptive dynamics of continuous traits. Annual Review of Ecology, Evolution and Systematics, 38, 403–435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, JM & Houston, AI (2005) If animals know their own fighting ability, the evolutionary stable level of fighting is reduced. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 232, 1–6.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McNamara, JM, Webb, JN, Collins, EJ, et al. (1997) A general technique for computing evolutionarily stable strategies based on errors in decision-making. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 189, 211–225.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mesterton-Gibbons, M (1992) Ecotypic variation in the asymmetric Hawk–Dove game: When is Burgeois an evolutionarily stable strategy?Evolutionary Ecology, 6, 198–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesterton-Gibbons, M (2000) An Introduction to Game-Theoretic Modelling, 2nd edn. Rhode Island: American Mathematical Society.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesterton-Gibbons, M & Adams, ES (1998) Animal contests as evolutionary games. American Scientist, 86, 334–341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesterton-Gibbons, M & Adams, ES (2003) Landmarks in territory partitioning: A strategically stable convention? American Naturalist, 161, 685–697.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mesterton-Gibbons, M, Marden, JH & Dugatkin, LA (1996) On wars of attrition without assessment. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 181, 65–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meszéna, G, Kisdi, É, Dieckmann, U, et al. (2001) Evolutionary optimization methods and matrix games in the unified perspective of adaptive dynamics. Selection, 2, 193–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrell, LJ & Kokko, H (2003) Adaptive strategies of territory formation. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology, 54, 385–395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrell, LJ & Kokko, H (2005) Bridging the gap between mechanistic and adaptive explanations of territory formation. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology, 57, 381–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrell, LJ, Lindström, J & Ruxton, GD (2005) Why are small males aggressive? Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B, 272, 1235–1241.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Parker, GA (1974) Assessment strategy and the evolution of fighting behaviour. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 47, 223–243.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Parker, GA & Rubenstein, DI (1981) Role assessment, reserve strategy, and acquisition of information in asymmetric animal conflicts. Animal Behaviour, 29, 221–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parker, GA & Thompson, EA (1980) Dung fly struggles: A test of the war of attrition. Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology, 7, 37–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, RJH (1998) Gradually escalating fights and displays: The cumulative assessment model. Animal Behaviour, 56, 651–662.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rankin, DJ, Bargum, K & Kokko, H (2007) The tragedy of the commons in evolutionary biology. Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 22, 643–651.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rudin, FS & Briffa, M (2012) Is boldness a resource-holding potential trait? Fighting prowess and changes in startle response in the sea anemone, Actinia equina. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B, 279, 1904–1910.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Selten, R (1980) A note on evolutionarily stable strategies in asymmetric animal conflicts. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 84, 93–101.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sih, A, Bell, A & Johnson, JC (2004) Behavioural syndromes: An ecological and evolutionary overview. Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 19, 372–378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stake, JE (2004) The property ‘instinct’. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 359, 1763–1774.Google Scholar
Stamps, JA & Krishnan, VV (2001) How territorial animals compete for divisible space: A learning-based model with unequal competitors. American Naturalist, 157, 154–169.Google ScholarPubMed
Switzer, PV, Stamps, JA & Mangel, M (2001) When should a territory resident attack? Animal Behaviour, 62, 749–759.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Számadó, S (2000) Cheating as a mixed strategy in a simple model of aggressive communication. Animal Behaviour, 59, 221–230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Számadó, S (2003) Threat displays are not handicaps. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 221, 327–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Temeles, EJ (1994) The role of neighbours in territorial systems: When are they dear enemies?Animal Behaviour, 47, 339–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, GC (1966) Adaptation and Natural Selection: A Critique of some Current Thought. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wilson, AJ, Boer, M, Arnott, G, et al. (2011) Integrating personality research and animal contest theory: Aggressiveness in the green swordtail Xiphophorus helleri. PLoS ONE, 6, e28024.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wolf, M, Doorn, GS, Leimar, O, et al. (2007) Life-history trade-offs favour the evolution of animal personalities. Nature, 447, 581–585.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zahavi, A (1975) Mate selection – a selection for the handicap. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 53, 205–214.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zahavi, A (1977) The cost of honesty (further remarks on the handicap principle). Journal of Theoretical Biology, 67, 603–605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×