Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-qsmjn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-16T19:56:39.466Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Charles H. Anderton
Affiliation:
College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts
John R. Carter
Affiliation:
College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Principles of Conflict Economics
A Primer for Social Scientists
, pp. 285 - 306
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

,ABC News (2005), “Will Aid Effort After Asia Quake Help U.S. Image?” http://abcnewsgo.com (downloaded 11/9/05).
,ACDA (various years), World Military Expenditures and Arms Transfers (Washington, DC: U.S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency).
Adams, Eldridge S. and Mesterton-Gibbons, Michael (2003), “Lanchester's Attrition Models and Fights among Social Animals,” Behavioral Ecology, 14(5), 719–723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, Karen R. (2003/04), “Attack and Conquer? International Anarchy and the Offense-Defense-Deterrence Balance,” International Security, 28(3), 45–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Addison, Tony and Murshed, S. Mansoob (eds.) (2003), “Special Issue: Explaining Violent Conflict: Going beyond Greed versus Grievance,” Journal of International Development, 14(4), 391–524.CrossRef
Alesina, Alberto and Spolaore, Enrico (1997), “On the Number and Size of Nations,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1027–1056.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Spolaore, Enrico (2003), The Size of Nations (Cambridge, MA:The MIT Press).Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Spolaore, Enrico (2006), “Conflict, Defense Spending, and the Number of Nations,” European Economic Review, 50(1), 91–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, Spolaore, Enrico, and Wacziarg, Romain (2000), “Economic Integration and Political Disintegration,” American Economic Review, 90(5), 1276–1296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allison, Graham (2004), Nuclear Terrorism: The Ultimate Preventable Catastrophe (New York: Times Books).Google Scholar
Amegashie, J. Atsu and Kutsoati, Edward (2007), “(Non)intervention in Intra-state Conflicts,” European Journal of Political Economy, 23(3), 754–767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ancker, C. J. (1995), “A Proposed Foundation for a Theory of Combat,” in Jerome Bracken, Moshe Kress, and Rosenthal, Richard E. (eds.), Warfare Modeling (Alexandria, VA: Military Operations Research Society), 165–197.Google Scholar
Anderson, James E. and Marcouiller, Douglas (2005), “Anarchy and Autarky: Endogenous Predation as a Barrier to Trade,” International Economic Review, 46(1), 189–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. (1990), “Teaching Arms-Race Concepts in Intermediate Microeconomics,” Journal of Economic Education, 21(2), 148–166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. (1992a), “A New Look at the Relationship among Arms Races, Disarmament, and the Probability of War,” in Chatterji, Manas and Forcey, Linda R. (eds.), Disarmament, Economic Conversion, and Management of Peace (New York: Praeger), 75–87.Google Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. (1992b), “Toward a Mathematical Theory of the Offensive/Defensive Balance,” International Studies Quarterly, 36(1), 75–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. (2003), “Conflict and Trade in a Predator/Prey Economy,” Review of Development Economics, 7(1), 15–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. and Carter, John R. (2003), “Does War Disrupt Trade?” in Gerald Schneider, Katherine Barbieri, and Gleditsch, Nils Petter (eds.), Globalization and Armed Conflict (Boulder, CO: Rowman & Littlefield), 299–310.Google Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. and Carter, John R. (2005), “On Rational Choice Theory and the Study of Terrorism,” Defence and Peace Economics, 16(4), 275–282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. and Carter, John R. (2006), “Applying Intermediate Microeconomics to Terrorism,” Journal of Economic Education, 37(4), 442–458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. and Carter, John R. (2007), “A Survey of Peace Economics,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 1211–1258.Google Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. and Carter, John R. (2008a), “Arms Trade,” in Durlauf, Steven and Blume, Lawrence (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. (New York: Palgrave Macmillan). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online, Palgrave Macmillan, 23 June 2008 (www.dictionaryofeconomics.com).Google Scholar
Anderton, Charles H. and Carter, John R. (2008b), “Vulnerable Trade: The Dark Side of an Edgeworth Box,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68(2), 422–432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderton, Charles H., Anderton, Roxane A., and Carter, John R. (1999), “Economic Activity in the Shadow of Conflict,” Economic Inquiry, 37(1), 166–179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arce, Daniel G. and Sandler, Todd (2003), “An Evolutionary Game Approach to Fundamentalism and Conflict,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 159(1), 132–154.Google Scholar
Arce, Daniel G. and Sandler, Todd (2005), “Counterterrorism: A Game-Theoretic Analysis,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(2), 183–200.Google Scholar
Aslam, Rabia (2007), “Measuring the Peace Dividend: Evidence from Developing Economies,” Defence and Peace Economics, 18(1), 39–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, Robert (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books).Google Scholar
Ballentine, Karen and Sherman, Jake (2003a), “Introduction,” in Ballentine, Karen and Sherman, Jake (eds.), The Political Economy of Armed Conflict (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner), 1–15.Google Scholar
Ballentine, Karen and Sherman, Jake (eds.) (2003b), The Political Economy of Armed Conflict (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner).Google Scholar
Banks, H. Thomas and Castillo-Chavez, Carlos (eds.) (2003), Bioterrorism: Mathematical Modeling Applications in Homeland Security, SIAM Series Frontiers in Applied Mathematics, vol. 28 (Philadelphia: Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics).CrossRef
Barbieri, Katherine and Reuveny, Rafael (2005), “Economic Globalization and Civil War,” The Journal of Politics, 67(4), 1228–1247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartrop, Paul (2002), “The Relationship between War and Genocide in the Twentieth Century: A Consideration,” Journal of Genocide Research, 4(4), 519–532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bearce, David H. and Omori, Sawa (2005), “How Do Commercial Institutions Promote Peace?” Journal of Peace Research, 42(6), 659–678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beardsley, Kyle C., Quinn, David M., Biswas, Bidisha, and Wilkenfeld, Jonathan (2006), “Mediation Style and Crisis Outcomes,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(1), 58–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary (1968), “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary (1976), The Economic Approach to Human Behavior (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Beckerman, Stephen (1991), “The Equations of War,” Current Anthropology, 32(5), 636–640.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellany, Ian (1999), “Modeling War,” Journal of Peace Research, 36(6), 729–739.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennett, D. Scott (1997), “Testing Alternative Models of Alliance Duration, 1816–1984,” American Journal of Political Science, 41(3), 846–878.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennett, D. Scott and Stam, Allan C. III (1996), “The Duration of Interstate Wars, 1816–1985,” American Political Science Review, 90(2), 239–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, Emile (1973), Defense and Economic Growth in Developing Countries (Boston: D.C. Heath).Google Scholar
Berdal, Mats and Malone, David M. (eds.) (2000), Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner).
Berman, Eli and Laitin, David D. (2008), “Religion, Terrorism and Public Goods: Testing the Club Model,” Journal of Public Economics, 92(10/11), 1942–1967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betts, Richard K. (1982), Conventional Deterrence: Predictive Uncertainty and Policy Confidence; Compound Deterrence vs. No-First-Use: What's Wrong is What's Right. Brookings General Series Reprint 412 (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution).Google Scholar
Bier, Vicki M. and Winterfeldt, Detlof (eds.) (2007), “Special Issue on Terrorism,” Risk Analysis, 27(3), 503–787.CrossRef
Binmore, Ken (2007), Playing for Real: A Text on Game Theory (New York: Oxford University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken and Samuelson, Larry (1994), “An Economist's Perspective on the Evolution of Norms,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 150(1), 45–63.Google Scholar
Björnehed, Emma (2004), “Narco-Terrorism: The Merger of the War on Drugs and the War on Terror,” Global Crime, 6(3&4), 305–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Jean [1899] (1903), The Future of War (Boston: Ginn).Google Scholar
Blomberg, S. Brock, Hess, Gregory D., and Orphanides, Athanasios (2004), “The Macroeconomic Consequences of Terrorism,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(5), 1007–1032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boehmer, Charles R. and Sobek, David (2005), “Violent Adolescence: State Development and the Propensity for Militarized Interstate Conflict,” Journal of Peace Research, 42(1), 5–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bogart, Ernest L. (1919), Direct and Indirect Costs of the Great World War (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Bolton, Patrick and Roland, Gerard (1997), “The Breakup of Nations: A Political Economy Analysis,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1057–1090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. (1962), Conflict and Defense: A General Theory (New York: Harper).Google Scholar
Braithwaite, Alex (2006), “The Geographic Spread of Militarized Disputes,” Journal of Peace Research, 43(5), 507–522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brams, Steven J. (1985), Superpower Games: Applying Game Theory to Superpower Conflict (New Haven: Yale University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brams, Steven J. and Taylor, Alan D. (1996), Fair Division: From Cake-Cutting to Dispute Resolution (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brauer, Jurgen (2002), “Survey and Review of the Defense Economics Literature on Greece and Turkey: What Have We Learned?Defence and Peace Economics, 13(2), 85–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brauer, Jurgen (ed.) (2003), “Special Issue: Economics of Conflict, War, and Peace in Historical Perspective,” Defence and Peace Economics, 14(3), 151–236.CrossRef
Brauer, Jurgen (2007), “Arms Industries, Arms Trade, and Developing Countries,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 973–1015.Google Scholar
Brauer, Jurgen and Roux, André (2000), “Peace as an International Public Good: An Application to Southern Africa,” Defence and Peace Economics, 11(6), 643–659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bremer, Stuart A. (2000), “Who Fights Whom, When, Where, and Why?” in Vasquez, John A. (ed.), What Do We Know About War? (New York: Rowman & Littlefield), 23–36.Google Scholar
Brito, Dagobert L. (1972), “A Dynamic Model of an Armaments Race,” International Economic Review, 13(2), 359–375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brito, Dagobert L. and Intriligator, Michael D. (1985), “Conflict, War and Redistribution,” American Political Science Review, 79(4), 943–957.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brito, Dagobert L. and Intriligator, Michael D. (1995), “Arms Races and Proliferation,” in Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier), 109–164.Google Scholar
Broadberry, Stephen and Harrison, Mark (eds.) (2005), The Economics of World War I (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRef
Brown, Michael E., Coté, Owen R.., Lynn-Jones, Sean M., and Miller, Steven E. (eds.) (2000), Rational Choice and Security Studies: Stephen Walt and His Critics (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).
Brown, Michael E., Coté, Owen R.., Lynn-Jones, Sean M., and Miller, Steven E. (eds.) (2004), Offense, Defense, and War (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press).Google Scholar
Brück, Tilman (ed.) (2006), The Economic Analysis of Terrorism (New York: Routledge).
Brunborg, Helge and Urdal, Henrik (eds.) (2005), “Special Issue on the Demography of Conflict and Violence,” Journal of Peace Research, 42(4), 371–519.CrossRef
Brzoska, Michael (1995), “World Military Expenditures,” in Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier), 45–67.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Faith, Roger L. (1987), “Secession and the Limits of Taxation: Towards a Theory of Internal Exit,” American Economic Review, 77(5), 1023–1031.Google Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno, Bruce, (1981), The War Trap (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Buhaug, Halvard (2006), “Relative Capability and Rebel Objective in Civil War,” Journal of Peace Research, 43(6), 691–708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buhaug, Halvard and Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede (2008), “Contagion or Confusion? Why Conflicts Cluster in Space,” International Studies Quarterly, 52(2), 215–233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Bureau of Justice Statistics (2008), “Direct Expenditure by Level of Government, 1982–2005,” available at http://www.ojp.usdoj.gov/bjs/glance/tables/expgovtab.htm (accessed September 24, 2008).
Bush, Winston C. (1972), “Individual Welfare in Anarchy,” in Tullock, Gordon (ed.), Explorations in the Theory of Anarchy (Blacksburg VA: Center for Study of Public Choice), 5–18.Google Scholar
Bush, Winston C. and Mayer, Lawrence S. (1974), “Some Implications of Anarchy for the Distribution of Property,”Journal of Economic Theory, 8(4), 401–412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bussmann, Margit and Schneider, Gerald (2007), “When Globalization Discontent Turns Violent: Foreign Economic Liberalization and Internal War,” International Studies Quarterly, 51(1), 79–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzan, Barry (1987), An Introduction to Strategic Studies: Military Technology and International Relations (London: Macmillan for International Institute for Strategic Studies).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carter, John R. and Anderton, Charles H. (2001), “An Experimental Test of a Predator-Prey Model of Appropriation,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 45(1), 83–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cauley, Jon and Sandler, Todd (1988), “Fighting World War III: A Suggested Strategy,” Terrorism: An International Journal, 11(3), 181–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cavanaugh, William T. (2004), “Sins of Omission: What ‘Religion and Violence’ Arguments Ignore,” The Hedgehog Review, 6(1), 34–50.Google Scholar
Cederman, Lars-Erik and Girardin, Luc (2007), “Beyond Fractionalization: Mapping Ethnicity onto Nationalist Insurgencies,” American Political Science Review, 101(1), 173–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Center for Migration Studies (2001), “Special Issue: UNHCR at 50: Past, Present, and Future of Refugee Assistance,” International Migration Review, 35(1), 1–384.Google Scholar
,Central Intelligence Agency (2008), The World Factbook 2008 (Washington, DC: Office of Public Affairs of the Central Intelligence Agency).Google Scholar
Cha, Victor D. and Kang, David C. (2005), Nuclear North Korea: A Debate on Engagement Strategies (New York: Columbia University Press).Google Scholar
Chang, Yang-Ming, Potter, Joel, and Sanders, Shane (2007), “War and Peace: Third-Party Intervention in Conflict,” European Journal of Political Economy, 23(4), 954–974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cirincione, Joseph, Wolfsthal, Jon, and Rajkumar, Miriam (2005), Deadly Arsenals: Nuclear, Biological, and Chemical Threats, 2nd ed. (Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace).Google Scholar
Clapham, Christopher (ed.) (1988), African Guerrillas (Oxford, UK: James Currey).
Colaresi, Michael P., Rasler, Karen, and Thompson, William R. (2007), Strategic Rivalries in World Politics: Position, Space and Conflict Escalation (New York: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Collier, Paul (1999), “On the Economic Consequences of Civil War,” Oxford Economic Papers, 51(1), 168–183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Paul (2000a), “Doing Well Out of War: An Economic Perspective,” in Berdal, Mats and Malone, David M. (eds.), Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner), 91–111.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul (2000b), “Rebellion as a Quasi-Criminal Activity,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(6), 839–853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Paul and Hoeffler, Anke (2004), “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4), 563–595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Paul and Hoeffler, Anke (2007a), “Civil War,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 711–739.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul and Hoeffler, Anke (2007b), “Unintended Consequences: Does Aid Promote Arms Races?” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 69(1), 1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Paul and Sambanis, Nicholas (eds.) (2002), “Special Issue: Understanding Civil War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(1), 1–170.CrossRef
Collier, Paul and Sambanis, Nicholas (eds.) (2005), Understanding Civil War: Evidence and Analysis, vols. 1 and 2 (Washington, DC: The World Bank).
Collier, Paul, Hoeffler, Anke, and Söderbom, Måns (2004), “On the Duration of Civil War,” Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 253–273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Paul, Elliott, Lani, Hegre, Håvard, Hoeffler, Anke, Reynal-Querol, Marta, and Sambanis, Nicholas (2003), Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy (Washington, DC: The World Bank).Google Scholar
Conybeare, John A. C., Murdoch, James, and Sandler, Todd (1994), “Alternative Collective-Goods Models of Military Alliances: Theory and Empirics,” Economic Inquiry, 32(4), 525–542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornes, Richard and Sandler, Todd (1984), “Easy Riders, Joint Production, and Public Goods,” Economic Journal, 94(3), 580–598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornes, Richard and Sandler, Todd (1996), The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods, 2nd ed. (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coulomb, Fanny (1998), “Adam Smith: A Defence Economist,” Defence and Peace Economics, 9(3), 299–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Kevin R., Low, Murray, and Robinson, Jennifer (eds.) (2008), The SAGE Handbook of Political Geography (London: Sage Publications).
Craft, Cassady B. (2000), “An Analysis of the Washington Naval Agreements and the Economic Provisions of Arms Control Theory,” Defence and Peace Economics, 11(2), 127–148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, Timothy W. and Kuperman, Alan J. (eds.) (2006), Gambling on Humanitarian Intervention: Moral Hazard, Rebellion and Civil War (New York: Routledge).
Crenshaw, Martha (2007), “Explaining Suicide Terrorism: A Review Essay,” Security Studies, 16(1), 133–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crescenzi, Mark J. C., Kathman, Jacob D., and Long, Stephen B. (2007), “Reputation, History, and War,” Journal of Peace Research, 44(6), 651–667.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cross, John G. (1977), “Negotiation as a Learning Process,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 21(4), 581–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cusack, Thomas, Glazer, Amihai, and Konrad, Kai A. (eds.) (2006), “Special Issue on Social Conflict,” Economics of Governance, 7(1), 1–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cutter, Susan L., Richardson, Douglas B., and Wilbanks, Thomas J. (eds.) (2003), The Geographical Dimensions of Terrorism (New York: Routledge).Google Scholar
Dallaire, Roméo (2004), Shake Hands with the Devil: The Failure of Humanity in Rwanda (New York: Carroll & Graf).Google Scholar
Dando, Malcolm (1994), Biological Warfare in the 21st Century (London: Brassey's).Google Scholar
Davis, Jim A. and Schneider, Barry R. (eds.) (2004), The Gathering Biological Warfare Storm (London: Praeger).
Deger, Saadet and Sen, Somnath (1995), “Military Expenditure and Developing Countries,” in Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier), 275–307.Google Scholar
Deininger, Klaus (2003), “Causes and Consequences of Civil Strife: Micro-level Evidence from Uganda,” Oxford Economic Papers, 55(4), 579–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeRouen, Karl R. and Bercovitch, Jacob (2008), “Enduring Internal Rivalries: A New Framework for the Study of Civil War,” Journal of Peace Research, 45(1), 55–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diehl, Paul F. (1983), “Arms Races and Escalation: A Closer Look,” Journal of Peace Research, 20(3), 205–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash (1987), “Strategic Behavior in Contests,” American Economic Review, 77(5), 891–898.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash and Nalebuff, Barry J. (1991), Thinking Strategically: The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics, and Everyday Life (New York: W. W. Norton).Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash and Skeath, Susan (2004), Games of Strategy, 2nd ed. (New York: W.W. Norton).Google Scholar
Doyle, Michael W. and Sambanis, Nicholas (2006), Making War and Building Peace (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Duffy, John and Kim, Minseong (2005), “Anarchy in the Laboratory (and the Role of the State),” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 56(3), 297–329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunne, J. Paul and Smith, Ron P. (2007), “The Econometrics of Military Arms Races,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 913–940.Google Scholar
Dunne, J. Paul, Smith, Ron P., and Willenbockel, Dirk (2005), “Models of Military Expenditure and Growth: A Critical Review,” Defence and Peace Economics, 16(6), 449–461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durham, Yvonne, Hirshleifer, Jack, and Smith, Vernon L. (1998), “Do the Rich Get Richer and the Poor Poorer? Experimental Tests of a Model of Power,” American Economic Review, 88(4), 970–983.Google Scholar
East, Maurice A. and Gregg, Phillip M. (1967), “Factors Influencing Cooperation and Conflict in the International System,” International Studies Quarterly, 11(3), 244–269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eck, Kristine and Hultman, Lisa (2007), “One-Sided Violence against Civilians in War: Insights from New Fatality Data,” Journal of Peace Research, 44(2), 233–246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, Isaac and Liu, Zhiqiang (eds.) (2006), The Economics of Crime (Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar).
Enders, Walter (2007), “Terrorism: An Empirical Analysis,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 815–866.Google Scholar
Enders, Walter and Sandler, Todd (1993), “The Effectiveness of Anti-Terrorism Policies: Vector-Autoregression-Intervention Analysis,” American Political Science Review, 87(4), 829–844.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enders, Walter and Sandler, Todd (1995), “Terrorism: Theory and Applications,” in Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier), 213–249.Google Scholar
Enders, Walter and Sandler, Todd (2000), “Is Transnational Terrorism Becoming More Threatening? A Times Series Investigation,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(3), 307–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enders, Walter and Sandler, Todd (2006a), The Political Economy of Terrorism (New York: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Enders, Walter and Sandler, Todd (2006b), “Distribution of Transnational Terrorism Among Countries by Income Class and Geography after 9/11,” International Studies Quarterly, 50(2), 367–393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enders, Walter, Sandler, Todd, and Cauley, Jon (1990), “Assessing the Impact of Terrorist-Thwarting Policies: An Intervention Time Series Approach,” Defence Economics, 2(1), 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engene, Jan Oskar (2006), “TWEED Code Book,” www.uib.no/people/sspje/tweed.htm (downloaded 6/6/08).
Epstein, , Joshua, M. (1985), The Calculus of Conventional War: Dynamic Analysis without Lanchester Theory (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution).Google Scholar
Epstein, Joshua M. (1990), Conventional Force Reductions: A Dynamic Assessment (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution).Google Scholar
Faria, João Ricardo and Daniel, G.Arce, M. (2005), “Terror Support and Recruitment,” Defence and Peace Economics, 16(4), 263–273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. (1995), “Rationalist Explanations for War,” International Organization, 49(3), 379–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. (2004), “Why Do Some Civil Wars Last So Much Longer than Others?” Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 275–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. and Laitin, David D. (2003), “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War,” American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fein, Helen (1993), Genocide: A Sociological Perspective (London: Sage Publications).Google Scholar
Feng, Yi and Kugler, Jacek (eds.) (2006), “Special Issue: Empirical Studies in International Mediation,” International Interactions, 32(4), 319–470.
Fetter, Steve (1991), “Ballistic Missiles and Weapons of Mass Destruction: What Is the Threat? What Should Be Done?” International Security, 16(1), 5–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Filson, Darren and Werner, Suzanne (2002), “A Bargaining Model of War and Peace: Anticipating the Onset, Duration, and Outcome of War,” American Journal of Political Science, 46(4), 819–838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, Dietrich (1984), Preventing War in the Nuclear Age (Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld).Google Scholar
Flint, Colin (ed.) (2004), The Geography of War and Peace: From Death Camps to Diplomats (New York: Oxford University Press).
,Florida Department of Corrections (2007), “Gang and Security Threat Group Awareness,” article available at www.dc.state.fl.us/pub/gangs/index.html (downloaded 11/30/07).
Fox, Jonathan (2004), “Is Ethnoreligious Conflict a Contagious Disease?” Studies in Conflict and Terrorism, 27(2), 89–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (2008), Microeconomics and Behavior, 7th ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill).Google Scholar
Frazier, Derrick V. and Dixon, William J. (2006), “Third-Party Intermediaries and Negotiated Settlements, 1946–2000,” International Interactions, 32(4), 385–408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. (2004), Dealing with Terrorism – Stick or Carrot? (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. and Luechinger, Simon (2003), “How to Fight Terrorism: Alternatives to Deterrence,” Defence and Peace Economics, 14(4), 237–249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, Roy (2003), Games for Business and Economics, 2nd ed. (New York: Wiley).Google Scholar
Garfinkel, Michelle R. (1990), “Arming as a Strategic Investment in a Cooperative Equilibrium,” American Economic Review, 80(1), 50–68.Google Scholar
Garfinkel, Michelle R. and Skaperdas, Stergios (2000a), “Conflict without Misperceptions or Incomplete Information: How the Future Matters,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(6), 793–807.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkel, Michelle R. and Skaperdas, Stergios (2000b), “Contract or War? On the Consequences of a Broader View of Self-Interest in Economics,” American Economist, 44(1), 5–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkel, Michelle R. and Skaperdas, Stergios (2007), “Economics of Conflict: An Overview,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 649–709.Google Scholar
Gartzke, Erik, Li, Quan, and Boehmer, Charles (2001), “Investing in the Peace: Economic Interdependence and International Conflict,” International Organization, 55(2), 391–438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gates, Scott and Strand, Håvard (2006), “Modeling the Duration of Civil Wars: Measurement and Estimation Issues,” Working Paper.
Gaver, Donald P. and Jacobs, Patricia A. (1997), “Attrition Modeling in the Presence of Decoys: An Operations-Other-Than-War Motivation,” Naval Research Logistics, 44(5), 507–514.3.0.CO;2-8>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geller, Daniel S. and Singer, J. David (1998), Nations at War: A Scientific Study of International Conflict (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghosn, Faten, Palmer, Glenn, and Bremer, Stuart (2004), “The MID3 Data Set, 1993–2001: Procedures, Coding Rules, and Description,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21(2), 133–154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibler, Douglas M. and Sarkees, Meredith Reid (2004), “Measuring Alliances: The Correlates of War Formal Interstate Alliance Dataset, 1816–2000,” Journal of Peace Research, 41(2), 211–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibler, Douglas M., Rider, Toby J., and Hutchison, Marc L. (2005), “Taking Arms Against a Sea of Troubles: Interdependent Racing and the Likelihood of Conflict in Rival States,” Journal of Peace Research, 42(2), 131–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibney, Mark (ed.) (2007), “Special Issue: Refugee Flight and Return,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 24(2), 83–157.CrossRef
Gleditsch, Nils Petter, Wallensteen, Peter, Eriksson, Mikael, Sollenberg, Margareta, and Strand, Håvard (2002), “Armed Conflict, 1946–2001: A New Dataset,” Journal of Peace Research, 39(5), 615–637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glick, Reuven and Taylor, Alan M. (2008), “Collateral Damage: The Economic Impact of War, 1870–1997,” Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Gochman, Charles S. and Maoz, Zeev (1990), “Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816–1976,” in Singer, J. David and Diehl, Paul F. (eds.), Measuring the Correlates of War (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press), 193–221.Google Scholar
Goddard, Stacie E. (2006), “Uncommon Ground: Indivisible Territory and the Politics of Legitimacy,” International Organization, 60(1), 35–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, Lyle J. (2006), Preventive Attack and Weapons of Mass Destruction: A Comparative Historical Analysis (Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press).Google Scholar
Goodwin, Craufurd D. (ed.) (1991), Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).
Gortzak, Yoav, Haftel, Yoram Z., and Sweeney, Kevin (2005), “Offense-Defense Theory: An Empirical Assessment,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(1), 67–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gowa, Joanne and Mansfield, Edward D. (2004), “Alliances, Imperfect Markets, and Major-Power Trade,” International Organization, 58(4), 775–805.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Herschel I. (1995), “Insurrections,” in Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier), 191–212.Google Scholar
Grossman, Herschel I. and Kim, Minseong (1995), “Swords or Plowshares? A Theory of the Security of Claims to Property,” Journal of Political Economy, 103(6), 1275–1288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guillemin, Jeanne (2005), Biological Weapons: From the Invention of State-Sponsored Programs to Contemporary Bioterrorism (New York: Columbia University Press).Google Scholar
Gurr, Ted Robert (1968), “A Causal Model of Civil Strife: Comparative Analyses Using New Indices,” American Political Science Review, 62(4), 1104–1124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Robert E. and Papell, David H. (2005), Macroeconomics: Economic Growth, Fluctuations, and Policy, 6th ed. (New York: W.W. Norton).Google Scholar
Hammond, Grant T. (1993), Plowshares into Swords: Arms Races in International Politics, 1840–1991 (Columbia:University of South Carolina Press).Google Scholar
Han, Sung Hun (2005), “Report on Critical Dimensions and Problems of the North Korean Situation (1995–2004),” Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy, 11(1), article 5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardesty, David C. (2005), “Space-Based Weapons: Long-Term Strategic Implications and Alternatives,” Naval War College Review, 58(2), 45–68.Google Scholar
Harff, Barbara (2003), “No Lessons Learned from the Holocaust? Assessing Risks of Genocide and Political Mass Murder Since 1955,” American Political Science Review, 97(1), 57–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harpviken, Kristian Berg (ed.) (2003), “Special Issue on the Future of Humanitarian Mine Action,” Third World Quarterly, 24(5), 773–908.
Harris, Geoff (1997), “Estimates of the Economic Cost of Armed Conflict: The Iran-Iraq War and the Sri Lankan Civil War,” in Brauer, Jurgen and Gissy, William G. (eds.), Economics of Conflict and Peace (Aldershot, UK: Avebury), 269–291.Google Scholar
Harrison, Mark (2000), “The Economics of World War II: An Overview,” in Harrison, Mark (ed.), The Economics of World War II (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press), 1–42.Google Scholar
Hartley, Dean S. III and Helmbold, Robert L. (1995), “Validating Lanchester's Square Law and Other Attrition Models,” Naval Research Logistics, 42(4), 609–633.3.0.CO;2-W>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartley, Keith (2006), “Defence Industrial Policy in a Military Alliance,” Journal of Peace Research, 43(4), 473–489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.) (1995), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier).
Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.) (2001), The Economics of Defense, vols. 1–3 (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).
Hausken, Kjell (2004), “Mutual Raiding of Production and the Emergence of Exchange,” Economic Inquiry, 42(4), 572–586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hegre, Håvard (2000), “Development and the Liberal Peace: What Does It Take to be a Trading State?Journal of Peace Research, 37(1), 5–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hegre, Håvard (ed.) (2004), “Special Issue on the Duration and Termination of Civil War,” Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 243–348.CrossRef
Hegre, Håvard, Ellingsen, Tanja, Gates, Scott, and Gleditsch, Nils Petter (2001), “Toward a Democratic Civil Peace? Democracy, Political Change, and Civil War, 1816–1992,” American Political Science Review, 95(1), 33–48.Google Scholar
Henderson, Errol A. and Singer, J. David (2000), “Civil War in the Post-Colonial World,” Journal of Peace Research, 37(3), 275–299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hensel, Paul R. (2000), “Territory: Theory and Evidence on Geography and Conflict,” in Vasquez, John A. (ed.), What Do We Know About War? (New York: Rowman & Littlefield), 57–84.Google Scholar
Herbst, Jeffrey (2004), “African Militaries and Rebellion: The Political Economy of Threat and Combat Effectiveness,” Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 357–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hess, Gregory D. (1995), “An Introduction to Lewis Fry Richardson and His Mathematical Theory of War and Peace,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 14(1), 77–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hewitt, J. Joseph (2003), “Dyadic Processes and International Crises,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(5), 669–692.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1985), “The Expanding Domain of Economics,” American Economic Review, 75(6), 53–68.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1987), Economic Behavior in Adversity (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1988), “The Analytics of Continuing Conflict,” Synthese, 76(2), 201–233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1991), “The Paradox of Power,” Economics and Politics, 3(3), 177–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1995), “Theorizing About Conflict,” in Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier), 165–189.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack, Glazer, Amihai, and Hirshleifer, David (2005), Price Theory and Applications: Decisions, Markets and Information, 7th ed. (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hitch, Charles J. and McKean, Roland N. (1960), The Economics of Defense in the Nuclear Age (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Bruce (1998), Inside Terrorism (New York: Columbia University Press).Google Scholar
Holmes, Leslie (ed.) (2007), Terrorism, Organised Crime and Corruption: Networks and Linkages (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).
Houghton, Brian K. (2008), “Terrorism Knowledge Base: A Eulogy,” Perspectives on Terrorism, 2(7), 18–19.Google Scholar
Howard, Russell D. and James, J. F. Forest (2008), Weapons of Mass Destruction and Terrorism (New York: McGraw-Hill).Google Scholar
Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1992), “Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-Riding in Cults, Communes, and Other Collectives,” Journal of Political Economy, 100(2), 271–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iannaccone, Laurence R. (2006), “The Market for Martyrs,” Interdisciplinary Journal of Research on Religion, 2(article 4), 1–29.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, Laurence R. and Berman, Eli (2006), “Religious Extremism: The Good, the Bad, and the Deadly,” Public Choice, 128(1–2), 109–129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,ICC International Maritime Bureau (various years), Piracy and Armed Robbery against Ships: Annual Report, 2006 and 2007 (Barking, UK: ICC International Maritime Bureau).
Ihori, Toshihiro (1999), “Protection against National Emergency: International Public Goods and Insurance,” Defense and Peace Economics, 10(2), 117–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,International Institute for Strategic Studies (1974), The Military Balance, 1974–1975 (London: The International Institute of Strategic Studies).Google Scholar
,International Institute of Strategic Studies (2008), The Military Balance, 2008 (London: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
,International Monetary Fund (2007), “World Economic Outlook Database, October 2007,” www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2007/02/ (data downloaded on 11/7/07).
Intriligator, Michael D. (1975), “Strategic Considerations in the Richardson Model of Arms Races,” Journal of Political Economy, 83(2), 339–353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Intriligator, Michael D. and Brito, Dagobert L. (1986), “Arms Races and Instability,” Journal of Strategic Studies, 9(4), 113–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Intriligator, Michael D. and Brito, Dagobert L. (1988), “A Predator-Prey Model of Guerrilla Warfare,” Synthese, 76(2), 235–244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isard, Walter (1969), General Theory: Social, Political, Economic, and Regional with Particular Reference to Decision-Making Analysis (Cambridge MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Isard, Walter (1988), Arms Races, Arms Control, and Conflict Analysis (New York: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Isard, Walter (2000), “Formative and Early Years of the Peace Science Society (International),” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 18(1), 1–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isard, Walter and Smith, Christine (1982), Conflict Analysis and Practical Conflict Management Procedures (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger).Google Scholar
Ivanova, Kate and Sandler, Todd (2007), “CBRN Attack Perpetrators: An Empirical Study,” Foreign Policy Analysis, 3(4), 273–294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackson, Matthew O. and Morelli, Massimo (2007), “Political Bias and War,” American Economic Review, 97(4), 1353–1373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Daniel M., Bremer, Stuart A., and Singer, J. David (1996), “Militarized Interstate Disputes, 1816–1992: Rationale, Coding Rules, and Empirical Patterns,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 15(2), 163–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Juergensmeyer, Mark (2000), Terror in the Mind of God: The Global Rise of Religious Violence (Berkeley:University of California Press).Google Scholar
Kadera, Kelly M. and Mitchell, Sara McLaughlin (eds.) (2005), “Special Issue: Model Specification and Control Variables,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 22(4), 273–363.CrossRef
Kahler, Miles and Walter, Barbara F. (eds.) (2006), Territoriality and Conflict in an Era of Globalization (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRef
Kahneman, Daniel (2003), “A Psychological Perspective on Economics,” American Economic Review, 93(2), 162–168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kemp, Geoffrey and Harkavy, Robert E. (1997), Strategic Geography and the Changing Middle East (Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, in cooperation with Bookings Institution Press).Google Scholar
Khanna, Jyoti and Sandler, Todd (1996), “NATO Burden Sharing: 1960–1992,” Defence and Peace Economics, 7(2), 115–133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khanna, Jyoti, Sandler, Todd, and Shimizu, Hirofumi (1998), “Sharing the Financial Burden for UN and NATO Peacekeeping: 1976–96,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(2), 176–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Suk Hi (2003), North Korea at a Crossroads (London: McFarland).Google Scholar
King, Robert G. and Plosser, Charles I. (eds.) (2004), “Special Issue on Economic Consequences of Terrorism,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(5), 861–1075.
Konrad, Kai A. and Skaperdas, Stergios (1998), “Extortion,” Economica, 65(260), 461–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koubi, Vally (2005), “War and Economic Performance,” Journal of Peace Research, 42(1), 67–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krain, Matthew (1997), “State-Sponsored Mass Murder: The Onset and Severity of Genocides and Politicides,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41(3), 331–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krause, Volker and Sprecher, Christopher (eds.) (2004), “Special Issue on Alliances,” International Interactions, 30(4), 281–397.CrossRef
Kreps, David M. (1990), A Course in Microeconomic Theory (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Krueger, Alan B. and Malečková, Jitka (2003), “Education, Poverty and Terrorism: Is There a Causal Connection?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(4), 119–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul R. and Obstfeld, Maurice (2009), International Economics: Theory and Policy, 8th ed. (Boston: Pearson).Google Scholar
Kuran, Timor (1989), “Sparks and Prairie Fires: A Theory of Unanticipated Political Revolution,” Public Choice, 61(1), 41–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lacina, Bethany (2006), “Explaining the Severity of Civil Wars,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(2), 276–289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lacina, Bethany and Gleditsch, Nils Petter (2005), “Monitoring Trends in Global Combat: A New Dataset of Battle Deaths,” European Journal of Population, 21(2–3), 145–166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laczko, Frank and Gozdziak, Elzbieta (eds.) (2005), “Special Issue: Data and Research on Human Trafficking: A Global Survey,” International Migration, 43(1/2), 1–343.CrossRef
LaFree, Gary and Dugan, Laura (2006), Global Terrorism Database 1.1, 1970–1997 [Computer file]. ICPSR22541-v1. College Park, MD: University of Maryland [producer], 2006. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2008–05–30.Google Scholar
Lafree, Gary and Dugan, Laura (2007a), Global Terrorism Database II, 1998–2004 [Computer file]. ICPSR22600-v1. College Park, MD: University of Maryland [producer], 2007. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2008–06–16.Google Scholar
Lafree, Gary and Dugan, Laura (2007b), Global Terrorism Database II, 1998–2004: Codebook and Data Documentation [Computer file]. ICPSR22600-v1. College Park, MD: University of Maryland [producer], 2007. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2008–06–16.Google Scholar
LaFree, Gary, Dugan, Laura, Fogg, Heather V., and Scott, Jeffrey (2006), “Building a Global Terrorism Database,” NCJ 214260, United States Department of Justice, National Institute of Justice, April 27, 2006.
Lai, Brian (ed.) (2007), “Special Issue: The Relationship between State Policies and Characteristics and Terrorism,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 24(4), 257–326.
Lanchester, Frederick W. (1916), Aircraft in Warfare, the Dawn of the Fourth Arm (London: Constable).Google Scholar
Landes, William M. (1978), “An Economic Study of U.S. Aircraft Hijacking, 1961–1976,” Journal of Law & Economics, 21(1), 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langford, R. Everett (2004), Introduction to Weapons of Mass Destruction: Radiological, Chemical, and Biological (Hoboken, NJ: Wiley).Google Scholar
Lapan, Harvey E. and Sandler, Todd (1988), “To Bargain or Not to Bargain? That is the Question,” American Economic Review, 78(2), 16–21.Google Scholar
Larsen, Jeffrey A. (2005), Historical Dictionary of Arms Control and Disarmament (Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press).Google Scholar
Lee, Dwight R. (1988), “Free Riding and Paid Riding in the Fight Against Terrorism,” American Economic Review, 78(2), 22–26.Google Scholar
Leeds, Brett Ashley (2003), “Do Alliances Deter Aggression? The Influence of Military Alliances on the Initiation of Militarized Interstate Disputes,” American Journal of Political Science, 47(3), 427–439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeds, Brett Ashley (2005), Alliance Treaty Obligations and Provisions (ATOP) Codebook, Department of Political Science, Rice University, available at http://atop.rice.edu/download/ATOPcdbk.pdf.
Leeds, Brett Ashley and Anac, Sezi (2005), “Alliance Institutionalization and Alliance Performance,” International Interactions, 31(3), 183–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeds, Brett Ashley, Ritter, Jeffrey M., Mitchell, Sara McLaughlin, and Long, Andrew G. (2002), “Alliance Treaty Obligations and Provisions, 1815–1944,” International Interactions, 28(3), 237–260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Michael A. and O, Michael E.'Hanlon (2005), The Future of Arms Control (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press).Google Scholar
Levy, Jack (2008), “Preventive War and Democratic Politics,” International Studies Quarterly, 52(1), 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard (2003), The Crisis of Islam: Holy War and Unholy Terror (New York: Modern Library).Google Scholar
Li, Quan (2003), “The Effect of Security Alliances on Exchange-Rate Regime Choices,” International Interactions, 29(2), 159–193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Quan (2005), “Does Democracy Promote or Reduce Transnational Terrorist Incidents?Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(2), 278–297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Long, Andrew G. and Leeds, Brett Ashley (2006), “Trading for Security: Military Alliances and Economic Agreements,” Journal of Peace Research, 43(4), 433–451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Thomas W. and Turkes, Turker (2003), “Fitting Lanchester Equations to the Battles of Kursk and Ardennes,” Naval Research Logistics, 51(1), 95–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lund, Michael S. (1996), “Early Warning and Preventive Diplomacy,” in Crocker, Charles A., Hampson, Fen Olser, and Aall, Pamella (eds.), Managing Global Chaos: Sources of and Responses to International Conflict (Washington, DC: U.S. Institute of Peace), 379–402.Google Scholar
Lynn-Jones, Sean M. (2004), “Preface,” in Brown, Michael E., Owen, R., Coté, ., Lynn-Jones, Sean M., and Miller, Steven E. (eds.), Offense, Defense, and War (Cambridge MA: MIT Press), xi–xxxvii.Google Scholar
Macnair, Elizabeth S., Murdoch, James C., Pi, Chung-Ron, and Sandler, Todd (1995), “Growth and Defense: Pooled Estimates for the NATO Alliance, 1951–1988,” Southern Economic Journal, 61(3), 846–860.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, N. Gregory (2007), Principles of Economics, 4th ed. (Mason, OH: South-Western).Google Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D. and Pollins, Brian M. (eds.) (2003), Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: New Perspectives on an Enduring Debate (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press).CrossRef
Marshall, Monty G. and Jaggers, Keith (2007), Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions: 1800–2006, available at http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm.
Marshall, Monty G., Gurr, Ted Robert, and Harff, Barbara (2001), “PITF Problem Set Codebook,” Political Instability Task Force, available at http://globalpolicy.gmu.edu/pitf/pitfcode.htm.
Martin, Philippe, Mayer, Thierry, and Thoenig, Mathias (2008), “Make Trade Not War?Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 865–900.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mas-Colell, Andreu, Whinston, Michael D., and Green, Jerry R. (1995), Microeconomic Theory (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
McGillivray, Mark and Morrissey, Oliver (2000), “Aid Fungibility in Assessing Aid: Red Herring or True Concern?” Journal of International Development, 12(3), 413–428.3.0.CO;2-P>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGuire, Martin C. (1965), Secrecy and the Arms Race (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Mcguire, Martin C. (1990), “Mixed Public-Private Benefit and Public-Good Supply with Application to the NATO Alliance,” Defence Economics, 1(1), 17–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mcguire, Martin C. (2002), “Property Distribution and Configuration of Sovereign States: A Rational Economic Model,” Defence and Peace Economics, 13(4), 251–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mcguire, Martin C. (2004), “Economics of Strategic Defense and the Global Public Good,” Defence and Peace Economics, 15(1), 1–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mearsheimer, John J. (1985), Conventional Deterrence (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press).Google Scholar
Merrouche, Ouarda (2008), “Landmines and Poverty: IV Evidence from Mozambique,” Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy, 14(1), article 2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mickolus, Edward F. (1980), Transnational Terrorism: A Chronology of Events, 1968–1979 (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press).Google Scholar
Mickolus, Edward F., Sandler, Todd, Murdock, Jean M., and Flemming, Peter A. (2003), “International Terrorism: Attributes of Terrorist Events, ITERATE, 1968–2002 Data Codebook,” Mimeo.
,Minorities at Risk Project (2005), College Park, MD: Center for International Development and Conflict Management, http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/mar/ (retrieved 2/12/07).
Montalvo, Jose G. and Reynal-Querol, Marta (2005), “Ethnic Diversity and Economic Development,” Journal of Development Economics, 76(2), 293–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mousseau, Demet Yalcin (2001), “Democratizing with Ethnic Divisions: A Source of Conflict?” Journal of Peace Research, 38(5), 547–567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murdoch, James C. and Sandler, Todd (1982), “A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of NATO,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 26(2), 237–263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murdoch, James C. and Sandler, Todd (2004), “Civil Wars and Economic Growth: Spatial Dispersion,” American Journal of Political Science, 48(1), 138–151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murshed, S. Mansoob (ed.) (2002), “Special Issue on Civil War in Developing Countries,” Journal of Peace Research, 39(4), 387–512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nafziger, Wayne and Auvinen, Juha (eds.) (2003), Economic Development, Inequality, and War: Humanitarian Emergencies in Developing Countries (New York: Palgrave Macmillan).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nalebuff, Barry and Riley, John (1985), “Asymmetric Equilibria in the War of Attrition,” Journal of Theoretical Biology, 113(3), 517–527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Air, National and Center, Space Intelligence (2006), Ballistic and Cruise Missile Threat (Wright-Patterson Air Force Base, OH: National Air and Space Intelligence Center).Google Scholar
Center, National Counterterrorism (2008), “2007 Report on Terrorism, 30 April 2008,” www.nctc.gov/ (downloaded on 6/6/08).
Natsios, Andrew S. (2001), The Great North Korean Famine (Washington, DC: U.S. Institute of Peace).Google Scholar
Neary, Hugh M. (1997), “Equilibrium Structure in an Economic Model of Conflict,” Economic Inquiry, 35(3), 480–494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicholson, Walter and Snyder, Christopher (2008), Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions, 10th ed. (Mason, OH: South-Western).Google Scholar
Niou, Emerson M. S. and Tan, Guofu (2005), “External Threat and Collective Action,” Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 519–530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nitsch, Volker and Schumacher, Dieter (2004), “Terrorism and International Trade: An Empirical Investigation,” European Journal of Political Economy, 20(2), 423–434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Balance, Edgar (1964), “Middle East Arms Race,” The Army Quarterly and Defence Journal, 88, 210–214.Google Scholar
O'Neill, Barry (1994), “Game Theory Models of Peace and War,” in Aumann, Robert J. and Hart, Sergiu (eds.), Handbook of Game Theory, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 995–1053.Google Scholar
O'Sullivan, Patrick (1991), Terrain and Tactics (New York: Greenwood Press).Google Scholar
,Office of Technology Assessment (1993), Proliferation of Weapons of Mass Destruction: Assessing the Risk (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office).Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur and Zeckhauser, Richard (1966), “An Economic Theory of Alliances,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 48(3), 266–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur and Zeckhauser, Richard (1967), “Collective Goods, Comparative Advantage, and Alliance Efficiency,” in McKean, Roland (ed.), Issues of Defense Economics (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research), 25–48.Google Scholar
Oneal, John R. and Diehl, Paul F. (1994), “The Theory of Collective Action and NATO Defense Burdens: New Empirical Tests,” Political Research Quarterly, 47(2), 373–396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oneal, John R. and Elrod, Mark A. (1989), “NATO Burden Sharing and the Forces of Change,” International Studies Quarterly, 33(4), 435–456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oneal, John R. and Russett, Bruce M. (2003a), “Assessing the Liberal Peace with Alternative Specifications: Trade Still Reduces Conflict,” in Schneider, Gerald, Barbieri, Katherine, and Gleditsch, Nils Petter (eds.), Globalization and Armed Conflict (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield), 143–163.Google Scholar
Oneal, John R. and Russett, Bruce M. (2003b), “Modeling Conflict While Studying Dynamics: A Response to Nathaniel Beck,” in Schneider, Gerald, Barbieri, Katherine, and Gleditsch, Nils Petter (eds.), Globalization and Armed Conflict (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield), 179–188.Google Scholar
,Online NewsHour (2006), “The Darfur Crisis,” posted April 7, 2006, to www.pbs.org/newshour/indepth_coverage/africa/darfur/rebel-groups.html (downloaded 11/30/07).
Peck, Merton J. and Scherer, Frederick M. (1962), The Weapons Acquisition Process: An Economic Analysis (Boston: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Perkins, Ray (1991), The ABCs of the Soviet-American Nuclear Arms Race (Pacific Grove, CA: Brooks/Cole).Google Scholar
Picarelli, John T. (2006), “The Turbulent Nexus of Transnational Organised Crime and Terrorism: A Theory of Malevolent International Relations,” Global Crime, 7(1), 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pickles, John (ed.) (2000), “Special Issue on Ethnicity, Violence, and Regional Change,” Growth and Change, 31(2), 139–337.CrossRef
Pindyck, Robert S. and Rubenfeld, Daniel L. (2009), Microeconomics, 7th ed. (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall).Google Scholar
Plowes, Nicola J. R. and Adams, Eldridge S. (2005), “An Empirical Test of Lanchester's Square Law: Mortality during Battles of the Fire Ant Solenopsis Invicta,” Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 272, 1809–1814.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Polachek, Solomon W. (1994), “Peace Economics: A Trade Theory Perspective,” Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy, 1(2), 12–15.Google Scholar
Polachek, Solomon W. and Seiglie, Carlos (2007), “Trade, Peace and Democracy: An Analysis of Dyadic Dispute,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 1017–1073.Google Scholar
Powell, Robert (2002), “Bargaining Theory and International Conflict,” Annual Review of Political Science, 5, 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert (2004), “Bargaining and Learning While Fighting,” American Journal of Political Science, 48(2), 344–361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert (2006), “War as a Commitment Problem,” International Organization, 60(1), 169–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przemieniecki, John S. (2000), Mathematical Methods in Defense Analyses, 3rd ed. (Reston, VA: American Institute of Aeronautics and Astronautics).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quackenbush, Stephen L. (2004), “The Rationality of Rational Choice Theory,” International Interactions, 30(2), 87–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raiffa, Howard (1982), The Art and Science of Negotiation (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Ram, Rati (1995), “Defense Expenditure and Economic Growth,” in Hartley, Keith and Sandler, Todd (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 1 (New York: Elsevier), 251–273.Google Scholar
Ramsay, Kristopher W. (2008), “Settling It on the Field: Battlefield Events and War Termination,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(6), 850–879.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, Anatol (1957), “Lewis F. Richardson's Mathematical Theory of War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 1(3), 249–299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rasler, Karen A. and Thompson, William R. (2006), “Contested Territory, Strategic Rivalries, and Conflict Escalation,” International Studies Quarterly, 50(1), 145–167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reed, William (2003), “Information and Economic Interdependence,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(1), 54–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Regan, Patrick M. and Aydin, Aysegul (2006), “Diplomacy and Other Forms of Intervention in Civil Wars,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(5), 736–756.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reiter, Dan (2003), “Exploring the Bargaining Model of War,” Perspectives on Politics, 1(1), 27–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, Harry W., Gordon, Peter, and Moore, James E. II (eds.) (2005), The Economic Impacts of Terrorist Attacks (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, Harry W., Gordon, Peter, and Moore, James E. II (eds.) (2007), The Economic Costs and Consequences of Terrorism (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, Lewis F. (1939), Generalized Foreign Politics (London: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Richardson, Lewis F. (1960a), Arms and Insecurity: A Mathematical Study of the Causes and Origins of War (Pittsburgh: Homewood).Google Scholar
Richardson, Lewis F. (1960b), Statistics of Deadly Quarrels (Pacific Grove, CA: Boxwood Press).Google Scholar
Rider, Robert (1999), “Conflict, the Sire of Exchange,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 40(3), 217–232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rider, Robert (2002), “Plunder or Trade?Defence and Peace Economics, 13(1), 199–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Julian Perry, Hedén, Carl-Göran, and Schreeb, Hans (1973), The Problem of Chemical and Biological Warfare, CB Weapons Today, vol. 2 (Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell).Google Scholar
Roemer, John E. (1985), “Rationalizing Revolutionary Ideology,” Econometrica, 53(1), 85–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ron, James (ed.) (2005), “Special Issue: Paradigm in Distress? Primary Commodities and Civil War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(4), 441–633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosendorff, B. Peter and Sandler, Todd (eds.) (2005), “Special Issue: The Political Economy of Transnational Terrorism,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(2), 171–314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotte, Ralph and Schmidt, Christoph M. (2003), “On the Production of Victory: Empirical Determinants of Battlefield Success in Modern War,” Defence and Peace Economics, 14(3), 175–192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rowley, Charles K. (ed.) (2006), “Special Issue: The Political Economy of Terrorism,” Public Choice, 128(1–2), 1–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rueckert, George L. (1998), On-Site Inspection in Theory and Practice: A Primer on Modern Arms Control Regimes (New York: Praeger).Google Scholar
Russett, Bruce M. and Oneal, John R. (2001), Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organization (New York: W.W. Norton).Google Scholar
Saaty, Thomas L. (1968), Mathematical Models of Arms Control and Disarmament (New York: Wiley).Google Scholar
Sagan, Scott D. and Waltz, Kenneth N. (2002), The Spread of Nuclear Weapons: A Debate Renewed (New York: W.W. Norton).Google Scholar
Sambanis, Nicholas (2000), “Partition as a Solution to Ethnic War: An Empirical Critique of the Theoretical Literature,” World Politics, 52(4), 437–483.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sambanis, Nicholas (2002), “A Review of Recent Advances and Future Directions in the Quantitative Literature on Civil War,” Defense and Peace Economics, 13(3), 215–243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sambanis, Nicholas (2004a), “Poverty and the Organization of Political Violence: A Review and Some Conjectures,” Unpublished manuscript.
Sambanis, Nicholas (2004b), “What Is Civil War? Conceptual and Empirical Complexities of an Operational Definition,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(6), 814–858.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sambanis, Nicholas (2004c), “Expanding Economic Models of Civil War Using Case Studies,” Perspectives on Politics, 2(2), 259–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sample, Susan G. (2002), “The Outcomes of Military Buildups: Minor States vs. Major Powers,” Journal of Peace Research, 39(6), 669–691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd (1977), “Impurity of Defense: An Application to the Economics of Alliances,” Kyklos, 30(3), 443–460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd (ed.) (1992), “Special Issue: Terrorism, Guerrilla Warfare, and Insurrections,” Defence and Peace Economics, 3(4), 259–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd (2000), “Arms Trade, Arms Control and Security: Collective Action Issues,” Defence and Peace Economics, 11(5), 533–548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd (2003), “Collective Action and Transnational Terrorism,” The World Economy, 26(6), 779–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Arce, Daniel G. (2007), “Terrorism: A Game-Theoretic Approach,” in Todd Sandler and Keith Hartley (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 775–813.Google Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Cauley, Jon (1975), “On the Economic Theory of Alliances,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 19(2), 330–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Enders, Walter (2004), “An Economic Perspective on Transnational Terrorism,” European Journal of Political Economy, 20(2), 301–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Forbes, John (1980), “Burden Sharing, Strategy, and the Design of NATO,” Economic Inquiry, 18(3), 425–444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (1995), The Economics of Defense (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (1999), The Political Economy of NATO (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (2001), “Economics of Alliances: The Lessons of Collective Action,” Journal of Economic Literature, 39(3), 869–896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.) (2003), The Economics of Conflict, vols. 1–3 (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).Google Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.) (2007), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier).Google Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Hegre, Håvard (eds.) (2002), “Special Issue on Economic Analysis of Civil Wars,” Defence and Peace Economics, 13(6), 429–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Murdoch, James C. (1990), “Nash-Cournot or Lindahl Behavior? An Empirical Test for the NATO Allies,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(4), 875–894.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Murdoch, James C. (2000), “On Sharing NATO Defense Burdens in the 1990s and Beyond,” Fiscal Studies, 21(3), 297–327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Siqueira, Kevin (2006), “Global Terrorism: Deterrence versus Preemption,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 39(4), 1370–1387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd, Tschirhart, John T., and Cauley, Jon (1983), “A Theoretical Analysis of Transnational Terrorism,” American Political Science Review, 77(1), 36–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sarkees, Meredith R. (2000), “The Correlates of War Data on War: An Update to 1997,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 18(1), 123–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sarkees, Meredith R., Wayman, Frank W., and Singer, J. David (2003), “Inter-state, Intra-state, and Extra-state Wars: A Comprehensive Look at Their Distribution Over Time, 1816–1997,” International Studies Quarterly, 47(1), 49–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. (1960), The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. (1966), Arms and Influence (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. (2006), “An Astonishing Sixty Years: The Legacy of Hiroshima,” American Economic Review, 96(4), 929–937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. and Halperin, Morton H. (1961), Strategy and Arms Control (London: Pergamon-Brassey's).Google Scholar
Schmid, Alex, Jongman, Albert, and Price, Eric (eds.) (2008), Handbook of Terrorism Research: Research, Theories and Concepts (New York: Routledge).Google Scholar
Schneider, Gerald and Barbieri, Katherine (eds.) (1999), “Special Issue on Trade and Conflict,” Journal of Peace Research, 36(4), 387–496.Google Scholar
Schneider, Gerald and Troeger, Vera E. (2006), “War and the World Economy: Stock Market Reactions to International Conflicts,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(5), 623–645.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, Gerald, Barbieri, Katherine, and Gleditsch, Nils Petter (2003), “Does Globalization Contribute to Peace? A Critical Survey of the Literature,” in Schneider, Gerald, Barbieri, Katherine, and Gleditsch, Nils Petter (eds.), Globalization and Armed Conflict (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield), 3–29.Google Scholar
Schrodt, Philip A. and Gerner, Deborah J. (2004), “An Event Data Analysis of Third-Party Mediation,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(3), 310–330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seiglie, Carlos (2007), “Efficient Peacekeeping for a New World Order,” Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy, 11(2), article 2.Google Scholar
Senese, Paul D. (2005), “Territory, Contiguity, and International Conflict: Assessing a New Joint Explanation,” American Journal of Political Science, 49(4), 769–779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shelley, Louise I. (2006), “Trafficking in Nuclear Materials: Criminals and Terrorists,” Global Crime, 7(3&4), 544–560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silke, Andrew (ed.) (2004), Research into Terrorism: Trends, Achievements and Failures (New York: Routledge).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simons, Lewis M. (2006), “Genocide and the Science of Proof,” National Geographic, 209(1), 28–35.Google Scholar
Singer, J. David (ed.) (1960), “Special Issue: The Geography of Conflict,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 4(1), 1–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singer, J. David (2000), “The Etiology of Interstate War: A Natural History Approach,” in Vasquez, John A. (ed.), What Do We Know About War? (New York: Rowman & Littlefield), 3–21.Google Scholar
Singer, J. David (2007), “Nuclear Proliferation and the Geo-Cultural Divide: The March of Folly,” International Studies Review, 9(4), 663–672.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singer, Peter W. (2005), Children at War (New York: Pantheon).Google Scholar
Singh, Sonali and Way, Christopher R. (2004), “The Correlates of Nuclear Proliferation,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(6), 859–885.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siverson, Randolph M. and Starr, Harvey (1990), “Opportunity, Willingness and the Diffusion of War, 1816–1965,” American Political Science Review, 84(1), 47–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siverson, Randolph M. and Starr, Harvey (1994), “Regime Change and the Restructuring of Alliances,” American Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 145–161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios (1992), “Cooperation, Conflict, and Power in the Absence of Property Rights,” American Economic Review, 82(4), 720–739.Google Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios (1996), “Contest Success Functions,” Economic Theory, 7(2), 283–290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios (2006), “Bargaining versus Fighting,” Defence and Peace Economics, 17(6), 657–676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios and Syropoulos, Constantinos (1997), “The Distribution of Income in the Presence of Appropriative Activities,” Economica, 64(253), 101–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios and Syropoulos, Constantinos (2002), “Insecure Property and the Efficiency of Exchange,” Economic Journal, 112(476), 133–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slantchev, Branislav L. (2003), “The Power to Hurt: Costly Conflict with Completely Informed States,” American Political Science Review, 47(1), 123–135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slantchev, Branislav L. (2004), “How Initiators End Their Wars: The Duration of Warfare and the Terms of Peace,” American Journal of Political Science, 48(4), 813–829.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Survey, Small Arms (2004), Small Arms Survey 2004: Rights at Risk (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Smith, Adam [1776] (1976), The Wealth of Nations (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Smith, Alastair and Stam, Allan C. (2004), “Bargaining and the Nature of War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(6), 783–813.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Glenn H. (1997), Alliance Politics (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press).Google Scholar
Solomon, Binyam (2007), “Political Economy of Peacekeeping,” in Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, vol. 2 (New York: Elsevier), 741–774.Google Scholar
Sorokin, Pitirim (1937), Social and Cultural Dynamics (New York: American Book Company).Google Scholar
Spolaore, Enrico (2008a), “Civil Conflict and Secessions,” Economics of Governance, 9(1), 45–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spolaore, Enrico (2008b), “Size of Nations, Economics Approach to the,” in Durlauf, Steven N. and Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. (New York: Palgrave Macmillan). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Palgrave Macmillan. 23 June 2008 (www.dictionaryofeconomics.com).Google Scholar
Sprecher, Christopher and Krause, Volker (eds.) (2006), “Special Issue on Alliances,” Journal of Peace Research, 43(4), 363–502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stanislawski, Bartosz H. (2008), “Para-States, Quasi-States, and Black Spots: Perhaps not States, But Not ‘Ungoverned Territories,’ Either,” International Studies Review, 10(2), 366–370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starr, Harvey and Thomas, G. Dale (2002), “The ‘Nature’ of Contiguous Borders: Ease of Interaction, Salience, and the Analysis of Crisis,” International Interactions, 28(3), 213–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2005), SIPRI Yearbook 2005 (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
,Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2007), SIPRI Yearbook 2007 (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
,Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2008a), “Multilateral Peace Operations Database,” available at http://www.sipri.org (data accessed 5/5/08).
,Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2008b), “SIPRI Data on Military Expenditure,” available at http://www.sipri.org (data accessed 10/16/07).
Tarar, Ahmer (2006), “Diversionary Incentives and the Bargaining Approach to War,” International Studies Quarterly, 50(1), 169–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, James G. (1983) Lanchester Models of Warfare, vols. 1 and 2 (Arlington, VA: Operations Research Society of America).Google Scholar
Taylor, John B. and Weerapana, Akila (2009), Principles of Macroeconomics, 6th ed. (Boston: Houghton Mifflin).Google Scholar
Tellis, Ashley J., Szayna, Thomas S., and Winnefeld, James A. (1997), Anticipating Ethnic Conflict (Santa Monica, CA: Rand).Google Scholar
Thompson, William R. (2001), “Identifying Rivals and Rivalries in World Politics,” International Studies Quarterly, 45(4), 557–586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tir, Jaroslav (2005), “Keeping the Peace after Secession: Territorial Conflicts Between Rump and Secessionist States,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(5), 713–741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tir, Jaroslav (2006), “Domestic-Level Territorial Disputes: Conflict Management via Secession,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 23(4), 309–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toft, Monica Duffy (2006), “Issue Indivisibility and Time Horizons as Rationalist Explanations for War,” Security Studies, 15(1), 34–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon (1974), The Social Dilemma: The Economics of War and Revolution (Blacksburg, VA: Center for the Study of Public Choice).Google Scholar
Nations, United (1969), Chemical and Bacteriological (Biological) Weapons and the Effects of Their Possible Use (New York: United Nations).Google Scholar
,United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (2006a), Helping Refugees: An Introduction to UNHCR (Geneva, Switzerland: UNHCR Media Relations and Public Information Service).Google Scholar
,United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (2006b), Internally Displaced People: Questions and Answers (Geneva, Switzerland: UNHCR Media Relations and Public Information Service).Google Scholar
,United States Census Bureau (various years), Statistical Abstract of the United States (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office).
,United States Government Accountability Office (2006), “Human Trafficking: Better Data, Strategy, and Reporting Needed to Enhance U.S. Antitrafficking Efforts Abroad,” GAO-06–825 (Washington, DC: US Government Accountability Office).,
Usher, Dan (1989), “The Dynastic Cycle and the Stationary State,” American Economic Review, 79(5), 1031–1044.Google Scholar
Vahabi, Mehrdad (2004), The Political Economy of Destructive Power (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valentino, Benjamin, Huth, Paul, and Balch-Lindsay, Dylan (2004), “‘Draining the Sea’: Mass Killing and Guerrilla Warfare,” International Organization, 58(2), 375–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evera, Stephen (1998), “Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War,” International Security, 22(4), 5–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evera, Stephen (1999), Causes of War: Power and the Roots of Conflict (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press).Google Scholar
Strihou, Ypersele, M, Jacques. (1967), “Sharing the Defense Burden among Western Allies,” Review of Economics and Statistics 49(4), 527–536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vasquez, John A. (ed.) (2000), What Do We Know About War? (New York: Rowman & Littlefield).Google Scholar
Victoroff, Jeff (ed.) (2006), Tangled Roots: Social and Psychological Factors in the Genesis of Terrorism (Amsterdam: IOS Press).Google Scholar
Waldman, Don E. (2009), Microeconomics, 2nd ed. (Boston: Pearson Addison Wesley).Google Scholar
Wall, James A., Stark, John B., and Standifer, Rhetta L. (2001), “Mediation: A Current Review and Theory Development,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(3), 370–391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallace, Michael D. (1979), “Arms Races and Escalation: Some New Evidence,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 23(1), 3–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walt, Stephen M. (1987), The Origins of Alliances (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press).Google Scholar
Walter, Barbara F. (2004), “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War,” Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 371–388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walter, Barbara F. (2006a), “Building Reputation: Why Governments Fight Some Separatists but Not Others,” American Journal of Political Science, 50(2), 313–330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walter, Barbara F. (2006b), “Information, Uncertainty, and the Decision to Secede,” International Organization, 60(1), 105–135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weiner, Myron (1996), “Bad Neighbors, Bad Neighborhoods: An Inquiry into the Causes of Refugee Flows,” International Security, 21(1), 5–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weiss, Herbert K. (1966), “Combat Models and Historical Data: The U.S. Civil War,” Operations Research, 14(5), 759–790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wessells, Michael (2006), Child Soldiers: From Violence to Protection (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Wiseman, Geoffrey (2002), Concepts of Non-Provocative Defence: Ideas and Practices in International Security (New York: Palgrave Macmillan).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, Donald (1979), “How a War Ends: A Rational Model Approach,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 23(4), 743–763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, Donald (2000), “The Wealth and Size of Nations,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(6), 868–884.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfson, Murray (1985), “Notes on Economic Warfare,” Conflict Management and Peace Science, 8(2), 1–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfson, Murray (1987), “A Theorem on the Existence of Zones of Initiation and Deterrence in Intriligator-Brito Arms Race Models,” Public Choice, 54(3), 291–297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wong, Kar-Yiu (1991), “Foreign Trade, Military Alliance, and Defence-Burden Sharing,” Defence Economics, 2(2), 83–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Quincy (1942), A Study of War, vols. 1 and 2 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Charles H. Anderton, College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts, John R. Carter, College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts
  • Book: Principles of Conflict Economics
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511813474.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Charles H. Anderton, College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts, John R. Carter, College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts
  • Book: Principles of Conflict Economics
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511813474.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Charles H. Anderton, College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts, John R. Carter, College of the Holy Cross, Massachusetts
  • Book: Principles of Conflict Economics
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511813474.016
Available formats
×