Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pftt2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-23T20:31:12.506Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - How Can Governments Be Accountable If Voters Vote Ideologically?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 October 2009

Ignacio Sánchez-Cuenca
Affiliation:
Doctor Miembro, Instituto Juan March; Associate Professor of Sociology, Universidad Complutense de Madrid; Professor of Political Science, Centro de Estudios Avanzados en Ciencias Sociales (Instituto Juan March)
José María Maravall
Affiliation:
Juan March Institute, Madrid
Ignacio Sánchez-Cuenca
Affiliation:
Juan March Institute, Madrid
Get access

Summary

Introduction

There are two very different logics of voting, the logic of ideology and the logic of the incumbent's performance. A citizen may vote out of ideological closeness to parties or candidates, but the citizen may also vote in an attempt to discipline and control the government. In the first case, only ideological closeness matters. In the second case, ideology does not play a role, and the voter only takes into account the government's performance. The underlying rule in each case is clear. For ideological voting, the voter follows a decision rule that is based on ideological closeness: vote for the party that minimizes ideological distance. For performance voting, the voter follows a decision rule about reelection: vote for the incumbent if the utility produced by the government's policies is higher than a certain preestablished value; otherwise, punish the incumbent.

Of course, these two logics correspond roughly to the distinction between prospective and retrospective voting (Manin, Przeworski, and Stokes 1999). As Fearon (1999) has put it, under prospective voting, elections are a matter of selecting good types, whereas under retrospective voting, elections are a matter of sanctioning poor performance. This basic distinction can also be expressed in terms of the problem that each logic of voting produces: prospective voting is associated with adverse selection, retrospective voting with moral hazard (Ferejohn 1995).

Each logic of voting has been investigated by apparently self-contained literatures. Ideological voting is studied by spatial models, whereas performance voting is studied by accountability models.

Type
Chapter
Information
Controlling Governments
Voters, Institutions, and Accountability
, pp. 45 - 81
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adams, James. 2001. Party Competition and Responsible Party Government. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, James, and Samuel, Merrill III. 1999. “Modeling Party Strategies and Policy Representation in Multiparty Elections: Why Are Strategies So Extreme?American Journal of Political Science 43 (3): 765–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almunia, Joaquín. 2001. Memorias políticas. Madrid: Aguilar.Google Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael, and Jonathan, Nagler. 1998. “When Politics and Models Collide: Estimating Models of Multiparty Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 42 (1): 55–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barreiro, Belén. 2002. “La progresiva desmovilización de la izquierda en España: un análisis de la abstención en las elecciones generales de 1986 a 2000.” Revista Española de Ciencia Política 6: 183–205.Google Scholar
Barreiro, Belén. 2004. “14-M: Elecciones a la sombra del terrorismo.” Claves de la Razón Práctica 141: 14–23.Google Scholar
Bawn, Kathleen. 1999. “Constructing ‘Us’: Ideology, Coalition Politics, and False Consciousness.” American Journal of Political Science 43 (2): 303–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budge, Ian. 1994. “A New Spatial Theory of Party Competition: Uncertainty, Ideology, and Policy Equilibria Viewed Comparatively and Temporally.” British Journal of Political Science 24 (4): 443–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caínzos, Miguel, and Jiménez, Fernando. 2000. “El impacto de los escándalos de corrupción sobre el voto en las elecciones generales de 1996.” Historia y Política 4: 93–133.Google Scholar
Carabaña, Julio. 2001. “Clase, voto y políticas sociales en España, 1982–2000.” Zona Abierta 96: 7–55.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Enelow, James M., and Melvin, J. Hinich. 1982. “Nonspatial Candidate Characteristics and Electoral Competition.” Journal of Politics 44 (1): 115–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enelow, James M., and Melvin, J. Hinich. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting. An Introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Enelow, James M., James W. Endersby, and Michael C. Munger. 1995. “A Revised Probabilistic Model of Elections: Theory and Evidence.” In Grofman, Bernard (ed.), Information, Participation, and Choice (pp. 125–40). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1999. “Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types Versus Sanctioning Poor Performance.” In Manin, Bernard, Przeworski, Adam, and Stokes, Susan (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation (pp. 55–97). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John. 1986. “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.” Public Choice 50 (1–1): 5–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferejohn, John. 1995. “The Spatial Model and Elections.” In Grofman, Bernard (ed.), Information, Participation, and Choice (pp. 107–24). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1990. “Information and Rationality in Elections.” In John, A. Ferejohn and James, H. Kuklinsky (eds.), Information and Democratic Processes (pp. 329–42). Urbana: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Gabel, Matthew J., and John, D. Huber. 2000. “Putting Parties in Their Place: Inferring Party Left–Right Ideological Positions from Party Manifestos Data.” American Journal of Political Science 44 (1): 94–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groseclose, Tim. 2001. “A Model of Candidate Location When One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (4): 862–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, Melvin J., and Michael, C. Munger. 1996. Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Hinich, Melvin J., and Michael, C. Munger. 1997. Analytical Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David. 1990. “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory.” In James, E. Alt and Kenneth, A. Shepsle (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy (pp. 90–143). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lago, Ignacio, and Montero, José Ramón. 2005. “Del 11-M al 14-M: los mecanismos del cambio electoral.” Claves de la Razón Práctica 149: 36–45.Google Scholar
Long, J. Scott, and Freese, Jeremy. 2001. Regression Models for Categorical Dependent Variables Using Stata. College Station, TX: Stata Press.Google Scholar
Manin, Bernard, Adam Przeworski, and Susan Stokes. 1999. “Elections and Representation.” In Manin, Bernard, Przeworski, Adam, and Stokes, Susan (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation (pp. 29–54). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Maravall, José María. 1999. “Accountability and Manipulation.” In Manin, Bernard, Przeworski, Adam, and Stokes, Susan (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation (pp. 154–96). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Merrill, Samuel III, and Grofman, Bernard. 1999. A Unified Theory of Voting. Directional and Proximity Spatial Models. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, Thomas R., and Keith, T. Poole. 1987. “The Relationship between Information, Ideology, and Voting Behavior.” American Journal of Political Science 31 (3): 511–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierce, Roy. 1995. Choosing the Chief. Presidential Elections in France and the United States. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powers, Daniel A., and Xie, Yu. 2000. Statistical Methods for Categorical Data Analysis. San Diego, CA: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Sánchez-Cuenca, Ignacio, and Barreiro, Belén. 2000. Los efectos de la acción de gobierno en el voto durante la etapa socialista (1982–1996). Madrid: Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas.Google Scholar
Thurner, Paul W. 2000. “The Empirical Application of the Spatial Theory of Voting in Multiparty Systems with Random Utility Models.” Electoral Studies 19 (4): 493–517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Torcal, Mariano y Lucía Medina. 2002. “Ideología y voto en España 1979–2000: los procesos de reconstrucción racional de la identificación ideológica.” Revista Española de Ciencia Política 6: 17–56.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×