Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-5g6vh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T11:59:46.966Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Incentive Problems with Discretionary Central Banking

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 May 2021

Peter J. Boettke
Affiliation:
George Mason University, Virginia
Alexander William Salter
Affiliation:
Texas Tech University
Daniel J. Smith
Affiliation:
Middle Tennessee State University
Get access

Summary

Orthodox monetary policy scholarship assumes that central bankers act to maximize the public welfare. If imperfect incentives enter the model, it is on the part of the public. We challenge this assumption. Monetary policymakers are just as prone to incentive problems, which cause them to act according to their own self-interest. Furthermore, the self-interest of policymakers is not always the same thing as the public welfare. The two diverge frequently, in fact. We survey the history of the Federal Reserve and show the numerous ways discretionary central bankers have been compromised. These incentive problems are an inherent feature of discretion. They can only be eliminated by embracing true monetary rules.

Type
Chapter
Information
Money and the Rule of Law
Generality and Predictability in Monetary Institutions
, pp. 58 - 93
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abrams, Burton (2006). How Richard Nixon Pressured Arthur Burns: Evidence from the Nixon Tapes. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(4), 177188.Google Scholar
Alchian, Allen (1950). Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211221.Google Scholar
Allen, Stuart and Smith, Michael (1983). Government Borrowing and Monetary Accommodation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(4), 605616.Google Scholar
Allen, Stuart (1986). The Fed and the Electoral Cycle: Note. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 18(1), 8894.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allison, John (2012). The Financial Crisis and the Free Market Cure: How Destructive Banking Reform Is Killing the Economy. McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Auerbach, Robert (1985). Politics and the Fed. Contemporary Economic Policy, 3(5), 4358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auerbach, Robert (1991). Institutional Preservation at the Federal Reserve. Contemporary Economic Policy, 9(3), 4658.Google Scholar
Auerbach, Robert (2008). Deception and Abuse at the Fed: Henry B. Gonzalez Battles Alan Greenspan’s Bank. University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
Axilrod, Stephen H. (2011). Inside the Fed. The MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bach, George (1971). Making Monetary and Fiscal Policy. Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Ball, Laurence (2008). Helicopter Drops and Japan’s Liquidity Trap. Monetary and Economic Studies, 26(December), 87106.Google Scholar
Ball, Laurence (2016). Ben Bernanke and the Zero Bound. Contemporary Economic Policy, 34(1), 720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballhaus, Rebecca, Restuccia, Andrew, and Kiernan, Paul (2019). Trump Calls for a Big Fed Rate Cut, Again Criticizes Central Bank Chairman. The Wall Street Journal, August 19. Available online (accessed August 20, 2019), www.wsj.com/articles/trump-calls-for-a-big-fed-rate-cut-again-criticizes-central-bank-chairman-11566230832Google Scholar
Barro, Robert (1978). Comment from an Unreconstructed Ricardian. Journal of Monetary Economics, 4(3), 569581.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert (1982). United States Inflation and the Choice of Monetary Standard. In Hall, Robert E. (Ed.), Inflation: Causes and Effects. University of Chicago Press, pp. 99110.Google Scholar
Barron, C. W. (1914). The Federal Reserve Act. Boston New Bureau Company.Google Scholar
Bassetto, Marco and Sargent, Thomas J. (2020). Shotgun Wedding: Fiscal and Monetary Policy. NBER Working Paper No. 27004. Available online (accessed May 27, 2020), www.nber.org/papers/w27004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel (1982). Presidential Influence on the Fed in the 1970s. American Journal of Political Science, 26(3), 415445.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel (1984). Domestic Political Sources of American Monetary Policy: 1955–1982. Journal of Politics, 46(3), 786817.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel (1987). Elections and the Fed: Is There a Political Monetary Cycle? American Journal of Political Science, 31(1), 194216.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. (2007). Economic Theory (2nd Edition). Routledge.Google Scholar
Beckworth, David (Ed.) (2012). Boom and Bust Banking: The Causes and Cures of the Great Recession. The Independent Institute.Google Scholar
Beckworth, David (2018a). Donald Trump’s Real Influence on Fed Policy. Alt-M. August 15. Available online (accessed May 28, 2020), www.alt-m.org/2018/08/15/donald-trumps-real-influence-on-fed-policy/Google Scholar
Beckworth, David (2018b). The Great Divorce: The Federal Reserve’s Move to a Floor System and the Implications for Bank Portfolios. Mercatus Center at George Mason University. Available online (accessed September 4, 2019), www.mercatus.org/system/files/beckworth-great-divorce-mercatus-research-v6.pdfGoogle Scholar
Bell, Stephanie (2000). Do Taxes and Bonds Finance Government Spending? Journal of Economic Issues, 34(3), 603620.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben (2002). On Milton Friedman’s Ninetieth Birthday. Remarks at the Conference to Honor Milton Friedman. University of Chicago, Chicago. November 8. Available online (accessed July 10, 2019), www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2002/20021108/Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben (2003). “Constrained Discretion” and Monetary Policy. Remarks before the Money Marketeers of New York University, New York. February 3. Available online (accessed May 31, 2019), www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2003/20030203/default.htm#fn4Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben (2010a). Central Bank Independence, Transparency, and Accountability. Speech at the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies International Conference at the Bank of Japan, Tokyo, Japan. Available online (accessed May 16, 2019), www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100525a.htmGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, Ben (2010b). Monetary Policy and the Housing Bubble. Speech given at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. January 3, Atlanta, GA. Available online (accessed June 1, 2020), www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100103a.htmGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, Ben (2013). The Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben, Lauback, Thomas, Mishkin, Frederic, and Posen, Adam (2001). Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben and Mishkin, Frederic (1997). Inflation Targeting: A New Framework for Monetary Policy? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(2), 97116.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Jake (2014). Inside the New York Fed: Secret Recordings and a Culture Clash. ProPublica. September 26. Available online (accessed November 7, 2019), www.propublica.org/article/carmen-segarras-secret-recordings-from-inside-new-york-fedGoogle Scholar
Binder, Sarah and Spindel, Mark (2017). The Myth of Independence: How Congress Governs the Federal Reserve. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Blinder, Alan (1982). Issues in the Coordination of Monetary and Fiscal Policy. Monetary Policy Issues in the 1980s [Symposium Sponsored by the Fed Bank of Kansas City]. Available online (accessed May 29, 2020), www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/1982/S82.pdfGoogle Scholar
Blinder, Alan (1983). On the Monetization of Deficits. In Meyer, Laurence H. (Ed.), The Economic Consequences of Government Deficits. Economic Policy Conference Series, volume 2. Springer, pp. 3973.Google Scholar
Blinder, Alan (2000). Central-Bank Credibility: Why Do We Care? How Do We Build It? The American Economic Review, 90(5), 14211431.Google Scholar
Blinder, Alan (2010). How Central Should the Central Bank Be? Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 123133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blinder, Alan (2019). A New Tactic in Trump’s War on the Fed. The Wall Street Journal. July 15.Google Scholar
Boettke, Peter J. and Coyne, Christopher J. (2009). Context Matters: Institutions and Entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 5(3), 135209.Google Scholar
Boettke, Peter J. and Smith, Daniel (2013). Federal Reserve Independence: A Centennial Review. Journal of Prices & Markets, 1(1), 3148.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael and Prescott, Edward (2019). Federal Reserve Structure, Economic Ideas, and Monetary and Financial Policy. The National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 26098. Available online (accessed August 1, 2019), www.nber.org/papers/w26098#fromrssGoogle Scholar
Boyes, William, Mounts, Williams Stewart, and Sowell, Clifford (1988). The Federal Reserve as a Bureaucracy: An Examination of Expense-Preference Behavior. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20(2), 181190.Google Scholar
Bradley, Michael (1985). Federal Deficits and the Conduct of Monetary Policy. Journal of Macroeconomics, 6(4), 411431.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James (2008). Same Players, Different Game: How Better Rules Make Better Politics. Constitutional Political Economy, 19(3), 171179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James and Wagner, Richard (1977 [2000]). Democracy in Deficit. Liberty Fund, Inc.Google Scholar
Burck, Gilbert (1959). A New Kind of Stock Market. Fortune, March, 120–121, 199, 201.Google Scholar
Caballero, Ricardo and Farhi, Emmanuel (2018). The Safety Trap. Review of Economic Studies, 85(1), 223274.Google Scholar
Calabria, Mark (2012, March 27). Wall Street’s Seat at the Fed? Cato@Liberty. Available online (accessed June 1, 2020), www.cato-at-liberty.org/wall-streets-seat-at-the-federal-reserve/Google Scholar
Canzoneri, Matthew, Cumby, Robert, and Diba, Behzad (2011). The Interaction between Monetary and Fiscal Policy. In Friedman, Benjamin M. and Woodford, Michael (Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, volume 3B. North-Holland, pp. 935999.Google Scholar
Caplan, Bryan (2009, March). Two Mea Culpas. EconLog. Library of Economics and Liberty. Available online (accessed May 28, 2020), http://econlog.econlib.org/archives/2009/03/two_mea_culpas.htmlGoogle Scholar
Caplan, Bryan (2012, February 18). The Mystery of Bernanke Solved, EconLog. Library of Economics and Liberty. Available online (accessed May 28, 2020), http://econlog.econlib.org/archives/2012/02/the_mystery_of_2.htmlGoogle Scholar
Caporale, Tony and Grier, Kevin (1998). A Political Model of Monetary Policy with Application to the Real Fed Funds Rate. Journal of Law and Economics, 41(2), 409428.Google Scholar
Caporale, Tony and Grier, Kevin (2005a). How Smart Is My Dummy? Time Series Tests for the Influence of Politics. Political Analysis, 13(1), 7794.Google Scholar
Caporale, Tony and Grier, Kevin (2005b). Inflation, Presidents, Fed Chairs, and Regime Shifts in the U.S. Real Interest Rate. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 37(6), 11531163.Google Scholar
Cargill, Thomas and O’Driscoll, Gerald Jr. (2013). Federal Reserve Independence: Reality or Myth? Cato Journal, 33(3), 417435.Google Scholar
Chappell, Henry, Havrilesky, Thomas, and McGregor, Rob Roy (1993). Partisan Monetary Policies: Presidential Influence through the Power of Appointment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(1), 185218.Google Scholar
Chappell, Henry, McGregor, Rob Roy, and Vermilyea, Todd (2005). Committee Decisions on Monetary Policy: Evidence from Historical Records of the Federal Open Market Committee. The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Clifford, Jerome (1965). The Independence of the Fed System. University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Clymer, Adam (1982). Kennedy Urges End to Federal Reserve Autonomy. New York Times. April 7.Google Scholar
Condon, Christopher (2019). Here’s a Timeline of All Trump’s Key Quotes on Powell and the Fed. Bloomberg. June 11. Available online (accessed July 1, 2019), www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-06-11/all-the-trump-quotes-on-powell-as-fed-remains-in-the-firing-lineGoogle Scholar
Conti-Brown, Peter (2015). The Institutions of Federal Reserve Independence. Yale Journal on Regulation, 32(2), 257310.Google Scholar
Cullity, John (1992). Arthur F. Burns (1904–1987). In Katz, Bernard S. (Ed.), Biographical Dictionary of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Greenwood Press, pp. 3849.Google Scholar
Dokko, James, Doyle, Brian, Kiley, Michael, Kim, Jinill, Sherlund, Shane, Sim, Jae, and Van den Heuvel, Skander (2009). Monetary Policy and the Housing Bubble. Finance and Economics Discussion Series No. 49. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal System. December 22. Available online (accessed June 8, 2020), www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2009/200949/200949pap.pdfCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drazen, Allan (2000). The Political Business Cycle after 25 Years. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15, 75117.Google Scholar
Drazen, Allan (2005). “Lying Low” during Elections: Political Pressure and Monetary Accommodation. University of Maryland Working Paper. Available online (accessed June 8, 2020), http://econweb.umd.edu/~drazen/Lying%20Low102005ee.pdfGoogle Scholar
Dudley, Bill (2019). The Fed Shouldn’t Enable Donald Trump. Bloomberg Opinion. August 27. Available online (accessed September 4, 2019), www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2019-08-27/the-fed-shouldn-t-enable-donald-trumpGoogle Scholar
Ehrmann, Michael and Fratzscher, Marcel (2011). Politics and Monetary Policy. Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(3), 941960.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry (2010, March 26). The Last Temptation of Risk. The National Interest (May–June). Available online (accessed July 10, 2019), http://nationalinterest.org/article/the-last-temptation-of-risk-3091Google Scholar
Ellis, Michael and Schansberg, Eric (2000). The Determinants of Tenures on the Federal Reserve Board of Governors: Should I Stay or Should I Go? Applied Economics, 32(2), 231237.Google Scholar
Engen, Eric and Hubbard, Glenn (2005). Federal Government Debt and Interest Rates. In Gertler, Mark and Rogoff, Kenneth (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, volume 19. The MIT Press, pp. 83160.Google Scholar
English, William, Erceg, Christopher, and Lopez-Salido, David (2017). Money-Financed Fiscal Programs: A Cautionary Tale. Hutchins Center Working Paper No. 31.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald and Carrick-Hagenbarth, Jessica (May 2011). Avoiding Group Think and Conflicts of Interest: Widening the Circle of Central Bank Advice. Central Banking Journal, 21(4), 6168.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald and Carrick-Hagenbarth, Jessica (2012). Dangerous Interconnectedness: Economists’ Conflicts of Interest, Ideology and Financial Crisis. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 36(1), 4363.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald and Schor, Juliet (2003). Corporate Profitability as a Determinant of Restrictive Monetary Policy: Estimates for the Postwar United States. In Mayer, Thomas (Ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy. Cambridge University Press, pp. 4962.Google Scholar
European Central Bank. (2011). Protocol on the Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank. Available online (accessed May 28, 2020), www.ecb.europa.eu/ecb/legal/pdf/en_statute_2.pdfGoogle Scholar
Evans, Paul (1985). Do Large Deficits Produce High Interest Rates? The American Economic Review, 75(1), 6887.Google Scholar
Fand, David I. (1986). Fed Hegemony and Monetary Surprises. Cato Journal, 6(2), 581586.Google Scholar
Farnsworth, Clyde H. (1982). Monetarists Divided on Fed’s Stand. New York Times, October 12. Section D, p. 1, Column 3.Google Scholar
Faust, Jon and Irons, John (1999). Money, Politics, and the Post-War Business Cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 43(1), 6189.Google Scholar
Federal Reserve (2020). Review of Monetary Policy Strategy, Tools, and Communications. Updated May 12, 2020. Available online (accessed May 27, 2020), www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-and-communications.htmGoogle Scholar
Ferrell, Robert (Ed.) (1981). The Eisenhower Diaries. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Freedman, Charles, Kumhof, Michael, Laxton, Douglas, Muir, Dirk, and Mursula, Susanna (2010). Global Effects of Fiscal Stimulus during the Crisis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 57(5), 506526.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1970a). A New Chairman at the Fed. Newsweek. February 2.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1970b). Burns and Guidelines. Newsweek, 86. June 15.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1978). Burns on the Outside. Newsweek. January 9.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1982). Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 14(1), 98118.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna (1963). A Monetary History of the United States, 1863–1960. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Froyen, Richard, Havrilesky, Thomas, and Waud, Roger (1997). The Asymmetric Effects of Political Pressures on US Monetary Policy. Journal of Macroeconomics, 19(3), 471493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Froyen, Richard and Waud, Roger (2002). The Determinants of Fed Policy Actions: A Re-Examination. Journal of Macroeconomics, 24(3), 413428.Google Scholar
Gandrud, Christopher and Grafström, Cassandra (2012). Does Presidential Partisanship Affect Fed Inflation Forecasts? APSA 2012 Annual Meeting Paper. Available online (accessed June 8, 2020), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2105301Google Scholar
Gildea, John A. (1993). Explaining FOMC Members’ Votes. In Mayer, Thomas (Ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy. Cambridge University Press, pp. 211228.Google Scholar
Gode, Dhananjay and Sunder, Shyam (1993). Allocative Efficiency of Markets with Zero-Intelligence Traders: Market as a Partial Substitute for Individual Rationality. Journal of Political Economy, 101(1), 119137.Google Scholar
Government Accountability Office (2011). Federal Reserve Bank Governance: Opportunities Exist to Broaden Director Recruitment Efforts and Increase Transparency. United States Government Accountability Office. Available online (accessed July 16, 2019), www.sanders.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/d1218%20(2).pdfGoogle Scholar
Grier, Kevin B. (1987). Presidential Elections and Fed Policy: An Empirical Test. Southern Economic Journal, 54(2), 475486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grier, Kevin B. (1989). On the Existence of a Political Monetary Cycle. American Journal of Political Science, 33(2), 376389.Google Scholar
Grier, Kevin (1991). Congressional Influence on U.S. Monetary Policy: An Empirical Test. Journal of Monetary Economics, 28(2), 201220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grier, Kevin (1996). Congressional Oversight Committee Influence on U.S. Monetary Policy Revisited. Journal of Monetary Economics, 38(3), 571579.Google Scholar
Grier, Kevin and Neiman, Howard (1987). Deficits, Politics and Money Growth. Economic Inquiry, 25(2), 201214.Google Scholar
Grim, Ryan (2009, October 23). Priceless: How the Fed Bought the Economics Profession. Huffington Post. Available online (accessed June 1, 2020), www.huffingtonpost.com/2009/09/07/priceless-how-the-federal_n_278805.htmlGoogle Scholar
Greenspan, Alan (1988, February 2). Testimony before the United States Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs. Available online (accessed May 28, 2020), https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/files/docs/historical/greenspan/Greenspan_19880202.pdfGoogle Scholar
Greenspan, Alan (2007). The Age of Turbulence. The Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Greider, William (1987). Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country. Random House.Google Scholar
Hamburger, Michael and Zwick, Burton (1981). Deficits, Money and Inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 7(1), 141150.Google Scholar
Hakes, David (1990). The Objective and Priorities of Monetary Policy under Different Fed Chairmen. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 22(3), 327337.Google Scholar
Harris, Ethan (2008). Ben Bernanke’s Fed. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Harrison, William (1991). Fed District Directors: Support System for a Public Institution. Journal of Economics and Business, 43(3), 271282.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas (1987). A Partisanship Theory of Fiscal and Monetary Regimes. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 19(3), 308325.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas (1988). Monetary Policy Signaling from the Administration to the Federal Reserve. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20(1), 83101.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas (1990). The Influence of the Federal Advisory Council on Monetary Policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 22(1), 3750.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas (1993). The Politicization of Monetary Policy: The Vice Chairman as the Administration’s Point Man. Cato Journal, 13(1), 137142.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas (1995a). The Pressures on American Monetary Policy (2nd Edition). Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas and Gildea, John (1990). Packing the Board of Governors. Challenge, 33(2), 5255.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas and Gildea, John (1991). The Policy Preferences of FOMC Members as Revealed by Dissenting Votes: Comment. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 23(1), 130138.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas and Gildea, John (1992). Reliable and Unreliable Partisan Appointees to the Board of Governors. Public Choice, 73(4), 397417.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas and Katz, Bernard S. (1992). Alan Greenspan (1926–). In, Katz, Bernard S. (Ed.), Biographical Dictionary of the Board of Governors of the Fed. Greenwood Press, pp. 103113.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas, Chappell, Henry, Gildea, John, and McGregor, Rob (1993). Congress Threatens the Fed. Challenge, 36(2): 5057.Google Scholar
Havrilesky, Thomas, Yohe, William, and Schirm, David (1973). The Economic Affiliations of Directors of Federal Reserve Banks. Social Science Quarterly, 54(4), 608622.Google Scholar
Hein, Scott (1981). Deficits and Inflation. Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 63(3), 310.Google Scholar
Hellerstein, Rebecca (2007). Is There a Dead Spot? New Evidence on FOMC Decisions before Elections. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39(6), 14111427.Google Scholar
Hess, Gregory and Shelton, Cameron (2016). Congress and the Federal Reserve. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48(4), 603633.Google Scholar
Hetzel, Robert (2008). The Monetary Policy of the Federal Reserve: A History. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hetzel, Robert and Leach, Ralph (2001). The Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord: A New Narrative Account. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 87(1), 3355.Google Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas (1977). Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. American Political Science Review, 71(4), 14671487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas (1987). The American Political Economy: Macroeconomics and Electoral Politics. Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hogan, Thomas, Le, Linh, and Salter, Alexander William (2015). Ben Bernanke and Bagehot’s Rules. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 47(2–3), 333348.Google Scholar
Horwitz, Steven (2012). Causes and Cures of the Great Recession. Economic Affairs, 32(3), 6569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyman, Sidney (1976). Marriner S. Eccles: Private Entrepreneur and Public Servant. Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Iacoviello, Matteo and Neri, Stefano (2010). Housing Market Spillovers: Evidence from an Estimated DSGE Model. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(2), 125164.Google Scholar
Igan, Deniz, Mishra, Prachi, and Tressel, Thierry (2012). A Fistful of Dollars: Lobbying and the Financial Crisis. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 26(1), 195230.Google Scholar
Ioannidis, John, Stanley, T., and Doucouliagos, Chris (2017). The Power of Bias in Economics Research. The Economic Journal, 127(605), F236F265.Google Scholar
Johnson, Lyndon (1967). State of the Union Address. January 10, 1967, Washington, DC. Available online (accessed August 5, 2019), https://millercenter.org/the-presidency/presidential-speeches/january-10-1967-state-union-addressGoogle Scholar
Jordan, Jerry and Luther, William (2019). Central Bank Independence and the Federal Reserve’s New Operating Regime. AIER Sound Money Project Working Paper No. 2019-07.Google Scholar
Kane, Edward (1974). The Re-politicization of the Fed. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 9(5), 743752.Google Scholar
Kane, Edward (1980). Politics and Federal Reserve Policymaking: The More Things Change the More they Remain the Same. Journal of Monetary Economics, 6(2), 199211.Google Scholar
Kane, Edward (1993). Bureaucratic Self-Interest as an Obstacle to Monetary Reform. In Mayer, Thomas (Ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy. Cambridge University Press, pp. 283298.Google Scholar
Keech, William (1995). Economic Politics: The Costs of Democracy. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Keech, William and Morris, Irwin (1997). Appointments, Presidential Power, and the Federal Reserve. Journal of Macroeconomics, 19(2), 253267.Google Scholar
Kettl, Donald (1986). Leadership at the Fed. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Kirman, Alan (1992). Whom or What Does the Representative Individual Represent? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(2), 117136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Aaron and Weiss, Olivia (2015). Reform the Fed? Get Rid of Groupthink. Bipartisan Policy Center Blog. April 7. Available online (accessed July 10, 2019), https://bipartisanpolicy.org/blog/reform-the-fed-get-rid-of-groupthink/Google Scholar
Krause, George (1994). Fed Policy Decision Making: Political and Bureaucratic Influences. Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 124144.Google Scholar
Kuttner, Kenneth (2014). Low Interest Rates and Housing Bubbles: Still No Smoking Gun. In Buiter, Willem H., (Ed.), The Role of Central Banks in Financial Stability: Has It Changed? World Scientific, pp. 159185.Google Scholar
Laney, Leroy and Willett, Thomas (1983). Presidential Politics, Budget Deficits, and Monetary Policy in the United States; 1960–1976. Public Choice, 40(1), 5369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laubach, Thomas (2009). New Evidence on the Interest Rate Effects of Budget Deficits and Debt. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(4), 858885.Google Scholar
Luckett, Dudley G. and Potts, Glenn T (1980). Monetary Policy and Partisan Politics: Note. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 12(3), 540546.Google Scholar
Luther, William (2019). Stephen Morre, Herman Cain, and the Myth of Independence. American Institute for Economic Research. Thursday, April 11. Available online (accessed July 1, 2019), www.aier.org/article/sound-money-project/stephen-moore-herman-cain-and-myth-independenceGoogle Scholar
Maier, Philipp (2002). Rhetoric and Action: What Are Central Banks Doing During Elections? Public Choice, 112(3/4), 235258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maisel, Sherman J. (1973). Managing the Dollar: An Inside View by a Recent Governor of the Fed Board. W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.Google Scholar
Mallaby, Sebastian (2016). The Man Who Knew: The Life and Times of Alan Greenspan. Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Maloney, Kevin J. and Smirlock, Michael L. (1981). Business Cycles and the Political Process. Southern Economic Journal, 48(2), 377392.Google Scholar
Mankiw, Gregory (2006). The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(4), 2946.Google Scholar
Marcussen, Martin (2006). Transnational Governance Network of Central bankers. In Djelic, Marie-Lauri and Sahlin-Andersson, Kerstin (Eds.), Transnational Governance Institutional Dynamics of Regulation. Cambridge University Press, pp. 180204.Google Scholar
Mayer, Thomas (1993). Minimizing Regret: Cognitive Dissonance as an Explanation of FOMC Behavior. In Mayer, Thomas (Ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy. Cambridge University Press, pp. 241254.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre and Ziliak, Stephen (1996). The Standard Error of Regressions. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 97114.Google Scholar
McMillin, Douglas (1981). A Dynamic Analysis of the Impact of Fiscal Policy on the Money Supply: Note. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 13(2), 221226.Google Scholar
McMillin, Douglas and Beard, Thomas (1982). “Deficits, Money and Inflation”: Comment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10(2), 273277.Google Scholar
McShane, Blakeley, Gal, David, Gelman, Andrew, Robert, Christian, and Tackett, Jennifer (2019). Abandon Statistical Significance. The American Statistician, 73(suppl. 1), 235245.Google Scholar
Meade, Ellen and Sheets, Nathan (2005). Regional Influences on FOMC Voting Patterns. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 37(4), 661677.Google Scholar
Meiselman, David I. (1986). Is There a Political Monetary Cycle? Cato Journal, 6(2), 563586.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H. (2005). Origins of the Great Inflation. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87(2, Part 2), 145176.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H. (2009a). A History of the Fed, volume 2, Book 1, 1951–1969. The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Alan H. (2009b). Inflation Nation. The New York Times. May 3. Available online (accessed July 21, 2020), www.nytimes.com/2009/05/04/opinion/04meltzer.htmlGoogle Scholar
Meyer, Laurence (2004). A Term at the Fed: An Insider’s View. Collins.Google Scholar
Mishkin, Frederic S. (2011a). Politicians Are Threatening the Fed’s Independence. The Wall Street Journal. September 29. Available online (accessed May 22, 2020), www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052970204831304576597200646525870Google Scholar
Mishkin, Frederic S. (2011b). Over the Cliff: From the Subprime to the Global Financial Crisis. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(1), 4970.Google Scholar
Morris, Irwin (2002). Congress, the President, and the Federal Reserve. University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Mueller, Paul and Wojnilower, Joshua (2016). The Federal Reserve’s Floor System: Immediate Gain for Remote Pain? Journal of Private Enterprise, 31(2), 1540.Google Scholar
Munger, Michael, and Roberts, Brian. (1993). The Federal Reserve and Its Institutional Environment: A Review. In Mayer, Thomas (Ed.), The Political Economy of American Monetary Policy. Cambridge University Press, pp. 8398.Google Scholar
Newton, Maxwell (1983). The Fed: Inside the Federal Reserve, the Secret Power Center that Controls the American Economy. Times Books.Google Scholar
Niskanen, William (1978). Deficits, Government Spending, and Inflation: What Is the Evidence? Journal of Monetary Economics, 4(3), 591602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97112.Google Scholar
Nozick, Robert (1974). Anarchy, State, and Utopia. Basic Books, Inc.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor (2005). Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Plosser, Charles (2018). The Risks of a Fed Balance Sheet Unconstrained by Monetary Policy. In Bordo, Michael, Cochrane, John, and Seru, Amit (Eds.), The Structural Foundations of Monetary Policy. Hoover Institution Press, pp. 116.Google Scholar
Potts, Glenn and Luckett, Dudley. (1978). Policy Objectives of the Fed System. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 92(3), 525534.Google Scholar
Puckett, Richard (1984). Federal Open Market Committee Structure and Decisions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 14(1), 97104.Google Scholar
Rajan, Raghuram. (2010). Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Reagan, Michael (1961). The Political Structure of the Fed System. American Political Science Review, 55(1), 6476.Google Scholar
Reinhart, Carmen, Reinhart, Vincent, and Rogoff, Kenneth (2012). Public Debt Overhangs: Advanced-Economy Episodes since 1800. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(3), 6986.Google Scholar
Reuss, Henry (1976). Fed Directors: A Study of Corporate and Banking Influence. Staff Report for the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing. House of Representatives.Google Scholar
Rolnick, Arthur (1985). Research Activities and Budget Allocations among Fed Banks: Comment. Public Choice, 45(2), 193195.Google Scholar
Romer, Paul (2016). The Trouble with Macroeconomics. Working Paper. Available online (accessed July 10, 2019), https://paulromer.net/trouble-with-macroeconomics-update/WP-Trouble.pdfGoogle Scholar
Rose, Sanford (1974). The Agony of the Federal Reserve. Fortune, July.Google Scholar
Rubin, Robert E. and Weisberg, Jacob (2004). In an Uncertain World: Tough Choices from Wall Street to Washington. Random House.Google Scholar
Safire, William (1975). Before the Fall: An Inside View of the Pre-Watergate Whitehouse. Doubleday & Company, Inc.Google Scholar
Salter, Alexander William and Luther, William (2019). Adaptation and Central Banking. Public Choice, 180(3–4), 243256.Google Scholar
Salter, Alexander William and Smith, Daniel (2019). Political Economists or Political Economists? The Role of Political Environments in the Formation of Fed Policy under Burns, Greenspan, and Bernanke. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 71(1), 113.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas (1983). Confrontations over Deficits. New York Times, August 12.Google Scholar
Selgin, George (2016). Real and Pseudo Rules. Cato Journal, 36(2), 279296.Google Scholar
Selgin, George (2018). Floored!: How a Misguided Fed Experiment Deepened and Prolonged the Great Recession. Cato Institute.Google Scholar
Selgin, George (2019). The Fed’s Chicago Shindig. Alt-M. June 26. Available online (accessed July 10, 2019), www.alt-m.org/2019/06/26/the-feds-chicago-shindig/Google Scholar
Selgin, George (2020). The Menace of Fiscal QE. Cato Institute.Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert (2008, November 1). Challenging the Crowd in Whispers, Not Shouts. New York Times. Available online (accessed May 15 2020), www.nytimes.com/2008/11/02/business/02view.html?_r=1&pagewanted=printGoogle Scholar
Shughart II, William and Tollison, Robert (1983). Preliminary Evidence on the Use of Inputs by the Fed System. The American Economic Review, 73(3), 291304.Google Scholar
Silber, William (2012). Volcker: The Triumph of Persistence. Bloomsbury Press.Google Scholar
Smialek, Jeanna (2019). Trump’s Feud with the Fed Is Rooted in Presidential History. The New York Times. June 24. Available online (accessed June 27, 2019), www.nytimes.com/2019/06/24/business/economy/federal-reserve-trump.html?smid=nytcore-ios-shareGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam (1776 [1976]). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Liberty Fund, Inc.Google Scholar
Smith, Daniel J. and Boettke, Peter J. (2015). An Episodic History of Modern Federal Reserve Independence. The Independent Review: A Journal of Political Economy, 20(1), 99120.Google Scholar
Stigler, George (1971). The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 321.Google Scholar
Subcommittee on Domestic Finance, Committee on Banking and Currency (1964). A Primer on Money. House of Representatives 88th Congress, 2nd Session.Google Scholar
Taylor, John (2009). Getting off Track: How Government Actions and Interventions Caused, Prolonged, and Worsened the Financial Crisis. Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, John (2010). The Fed and the Crisis: A Reply to Ben Bernanke. The Wall Street Journal. January 10. Available online (accessed May 15 2020), https://web.stanford.edu/~johntayl/2010_pdfs/Fed-Crisis-A-Reply-to-Ben-Bernanke-WSJ-Jan-10-2010.pdfGoogle Scholar
Taylor, John (2012). First Principles: Five Keys to Restoring America’s Prosperity. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Thornton, Daniel (1984). Monetizing the Debt. Economic Synopses, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 66 (December), 3043.Google Scholar
Timberlake, Richard (1993). Monetary Policy in the United States: An Intellectual and Institutional History. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Timiraos, Nick (2019). Fed Chief Wedged between a Slowing Economy and an Angry President. The Wall Street Journal. August 18. Available online (accessed May 15 2020), www.wsj.com/articles/fed-chief-wedged-between-a-slowing-economy-and-an-angry-president-11566166246Google Scholar
Toma, Mark (1982). Inflationary Bias of the Fed System: A Bureaucratic Perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10(2), 163190.Google Scholar
Toma, Eugenia Froedge and Toma, Mark (1985a). Research Activities and Budget Allocations among Fed Banks. Public Choice, 45(2), 175191.Google Scholar
Toma, Eugenia Froedge and Toma, Mark (1985b). Research Activities and Budget Allocations among Fed Banks: Reply. Public Choice, 45(2), 197198.Google Scholar
Tuccille, Jerome (2002). Alan Shrugged. John Wiley & Sons, Inc.Google Scholar
Tufte, Edward R. (1978). Political Control of the Economy. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tymoigne, Eric (2014). Modern Money Theory, and Interrelations between the Treasury and Central Bank: The Case of the United States. Journal of Economic Issues, 48(3), 641662.Google Scholar
Vencill, Daniel (1992). William McChesney Martin, Jr. (1906–). In Katz, Bernard S. (Ed.), Biographical Dictionary of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Greenwood Press, pp. 192210.Google Scholar
Volcker, Paul (1978). The Role of Monetary Targets in an Age of Inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 4(2), 329339.Google Scholar
Volcker, Paul, Greenspan, Alan, Bernanke, Ben, and Yellen, Janet (2019). America Needs an Independent Fed. The Wall Street Journal. August 5. Available online (accessed August 6, 2019), www.wsj.com/articles/america-needs-an-independent-fed-11565045308Google Scholar
Wallace, Myles and Warner, John (1984). Fed Policy and Presidential Elections. Journal of Macroeconomics, 6(1), 7988.Google Scholar
Waller, Christopher J. (1992). A Bargaining Model of Partisan Appointments to the Central Bank. Journal of Monetary Economics, 29(3), 411428.Google Scholar
Wapshott, Nicholas. (2011). Keynes Hayek: The Clash that Defined Modern Economics. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Weintraub, Robert (1978). Congressional Supervision of Monetary Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 4(2), 341362.Google Scholar
Weise, Charles (2008). Private Sector Influences on Monetary Policy in the United States. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40(2–3), 449462.Google Scholar
Weise, Charles (2012). Political Pressures on Monetary Policy during the US Great Inflation. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(2), 3364.Google Scholar
Wells, Wyatt C. (1994). Economist in an Uncertain World: Arthur F. Burns and the Federal Reserve 1970–1978. Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Wessel, David. (2018). Report: Alternatives to the Fed’s 2 Percent Inflation Target. Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy at Brookings. Available online (accessed May 25, 2020), www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2018/06/ES_20180607_Hutchins-FedInflationTarget.pdfGoogle Scholar
White, Lawrence (2005). The Federal Reserve System’s Influence on Research in Monetary Economics. Econ Journal Watch, 2(2), 325354.Google Scholar
Williams, John T. (1990). The Political Manipulation of Macroeconomic Policy. The American Political Science Review, 84(3), 767795.Google Scholar
Williamson, Stephen (2019). The Fed’s Operating Framework: How Does It Work and How Will It Change? Cato Journal, 39(2), 303316.Google Scholar
Winder, Robert C. (1992). Martha Romayne Seger (1932–). In Katz, Bernard S. (Ed.), Biographical Dictionary of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Greenwood Press, pp. 295299.Google Scholar
Woodward, Bob (2000). Maestro: Greenspan’s Fed and the American Boom. Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Woolley, John (1984). Monetary Politics: The Fed and the Politics of Monetary Policy. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Woolley, John (1988). Partisan Manipulation of the Economy: Another Look at Monetary Policy with Moving Regression. The Journal of Politics, 50(2), 335360.Google Scholar
Zingales, Luigi (2012). A Capitalism for the People: Recapturing the Lost Genius of American Prosperity. Basic Books.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×