Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T03:01:03.279Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Foreword

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Partha Dasgupta
Affiliation:
University of Cambridge
Charles Perrings
Affiliation:
University of York
Karl-Goran Maler
Affiliation:
Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics, Stockholm
Carl Folke
Affiliation:
Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics, Stockholm
C. S. Holling
Affiliation:
University of Florida
Bengt-Owe Jansson
Affiliation:
Stockholms Universitet
Get access

Summary

Resource economists typically view the natural environment through the lens of population ecology. Since the focus there is the dynamics of interacting populations of different species, it is customary to take the background environmental processes as exogenously given. The most wellknown illustration of this viewpoint is the use of the logistic function for charting the time path of the biomass of a single species offish enjoying a constant flow of food. Predator-prey models (e.g., that of Volterra) provide another class of examples: as do the May-MacArthur models of competition among an arbitrary number of species.

One or more of the populations in question may have a value. The value may be utilitarian (e.g., as a source of food or as a keystone species), it may be aesthetic, or it may be intrinsic: Indeed, it may be all these things. In some cases the populations would be valued directly (we would then regard them as consumption goods), in others indirectly (in these cases they are capital goods). Depending on the context, the flow of value could be a function of the rate at which a population is harvested, or it could be a function of the population size; in many cases, it would be a function of both. For example, annual commercial profits from a fishery depend not only on the rate at which it is harvested, but also on the stock of the fishery, because unit harvesting costs are typically low when stocks are large and high when stocks are low.

Type
Chapter
Information
Biodiversity Loss
Economic and Ecological Issues
, pp. vii - x
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×