Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-x4r87 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T09:00:11.919Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 March 2015

Richard Bronk
Affiliation:
London School of Economics and Political Science
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Romantic Economist
Imagination in Economics
, pp. 354 - 366
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abrams, M. H., The Mirror and the Lamp – Romantic Theory and the Critical Tradition, Oxford University Press, 1953Google Scholar
Abrams, M. H. (ed.), English Romantic Poets – Modern Essays in Criticism, Oxford University Press, 1975
Adler, Emanuel, ‘Constructivism and International Relations’, chapter 5 in Handbook of International Relations, ed. Carlsnaes, W.et al., Sage, 2002Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A. and Yellen, Janet L., ‘The Fair Wage–Effort Hypothesis and Unemployment’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(2) (May 1990), pp. 255–83CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albert, Michel, Capitalism Against Capitalism, Whurr Publishers, 1993Google Scholar
Armstrong, Charles I., Romantic Organicism – From Idealist Origins to Ambivalent Afterlife, Palgrave Macmillan, 2003Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth, J., Social Choice and Individual Values, John Wiley & Sons, 1951Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., ‘The Place of Institutions in the Economy: A Theoretical Perspective’, in The Institutional Foundations of East Asian Economic Development, ed. Hayami, Y. and M. Aoki, Macmillan, 1998; reproduced as chapter 3 in Readings in Political Economy, ed. Basu, Kaushik, Blackwell, 2003Google Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian, ‘Positive Feedbacks in the Economy’, Scientific American, February 1990, pp. 80–5Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E., The Penguin History of Economics, Penguin, 2002Google Scholar
Bagehot, Walter, ‘The Preliminaries of Political Economy’ and ‘The Postulates of English Political Economy’, in his posthumous Economic Studies, ed. Hutton, R. H., 2nd edn., Longmans, Green & Co., 1888Google Scholar
Baldwin, R. E., ‘The Eastern Enlargement of the European Union’, European Economic Review, 39, 1995, pp. 474–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnard, F. M., Herder's Social and Political Thought – From Enlightenment to Nationalism, Oxford University Press, 1965Google Scholar
Barnard, F. M. (trans.), J. G. Herder on Social and Political Culture, Cambridge University Press, 1969
Basu, Kaushik (ed.), Readings in Political Economy, Blackwell, 2003
Bate, Jonathan, The Song of the Earth, Picador, 2000Google Scholar
Beer, John, ‘Fragmentations and Ironies’, in Questioning Romanticism, ed. Beer, John, Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995Google Scholar
Begg, David, Fischer, Stanley and Dornbusch, Rudiger, Economics, 4th edn., McGraw-Hill, 1994Google Scholar
Behler, Ernst, ‘Early German Romanticism: Friedrich Schlegel and Novalis’, chapter 4 in A Companion to Continental Philosophy, ed. Critchley, Simon and Schroeder, William R., Blackwell, 1998Google Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy, An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation (originally published in 1789), W. Pickering, 1823Google Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy, The Rationale of Reward, Robert Heward, 1830Google Scholar
Berger, Suzanne, ‘Introduction’, in National Diversity and Global Capitalism, ed. Berger, Suzanne and Dore, Ronald, Cornell University Press, 1996Google Scholar
Berger, Suzanne, ‘Globalization and Politics’, Annual Review of Political Science, 3, 2000, p. 59; also available as MIT IPC Globalization Working Paper 00–005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berlin, Isaiah, The Crooked Timber of Humanity – Chapters in the History of Ideas, ed. Hardy, Henry, John Murray, 1990Google Scholar
Berlin, Isaiah, The Roots of Romanticism, ed. Hardy, Henry, Chatto & Windus, 1999Google Scholar
Blake, William, ‘Milton’ (composed 1803–8), extract reproduced in Romanticism – An Anthology, ed. Wu, Duncan, Blackwell, 1998, p. 120Google Scholar
Boardman, Anthony E., Greenberg, David H., Vining, Aidan R. and Weimer, David L., Cost-Benefit Analysis: Concepts and Practice, Prentice Hall, 1996Google Scholar
Bohm, David, On Creativity, Routledge, 1996Google Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E., The Image – Knowledge in Life and Society, Ann Arbor Paperbacks (University of Michigan Press), 1961Google Scholar
Bowie, Andrew, From Romanticism to Critical Theory – The Philosophy of German Literary Theory, Routledge, 1997Google Scholar
Bronk, Richard, Progress and the Invisible Hand – The Philosophy and Economics of Human Advance, Little Brown, 1998Google Scholar
Bronk, Richard, ‘Which Model of Capitalism?’, OECD Observer, 221/222, Summer 2000, pp. 12–15Google Scholar
Bronowski, J., The Ascent of Man, BBC Books, 1973Google Scholar
Brown, S., Doherty, A. M. and Clarke, B., Romancing the Market, Routledge, 1998Google Scholar
Brown, Vivienne, Adam Smith's Discourse – Canonicity, Commerce and Conscience, Routledge, 1994Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Vanberg, Viktor J., ‘The Market as a Creative Process’, Economics and Philosophy, 7 (1991); reproduced as chapter 18 in The Philosophy of Economics – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Hausman, Daniel M., Cambridge University Press, 1994CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burke, Edmund, Reflections on the Revolution in France (originally published in 1790), ed. Mitchell, L. G., Oxford University Press, 1993Google Scholar
Burke, Edmund, ‘Speech on Moving the Resolutions for Conciliation with the Colonies’ (1775), extract quoted in Whale, John, Imagination Under Pressure, 1789–1832, Cambridge University Press, 2000, p. 32Google Scholar
Butler, Marilyn, Romantics, Rebels and Reactionaries – English Literature and its Background (1760–1830), Oxford University Press, 1981Google Scholar
Byron, Lord George, Childe Harold's Pilgrimage, Canto III (originally published in 1816), reprinted in ‘The Oxford Authors’ Byron', ed. McGann, Jerome J., Oxford University Press, 1986Google Scholar
Byron, Lord George, Lara (originally published in 1814), extracts reprinted in ‘The Oxford Authors’ Byron', ed. McGann, Jerome J., Oxford University Press, 1986Google Scholar
Calmfors, Lars and Drifill, John, ‘Centralisation of Wage Bargaining and Macro-Economic Performance’, Economic Policy 6 (April 1988), pp. 13–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Colin, The Romantic Ethic and the Spirit of Modern Consumerism, Blackwell, 1987Google Scholar
Caporaso, James A. and Levine, David P., Theories of Political Economy, Cambridge University Press, 1992CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlin, Wendy and Soskice, David, Macroeconomics: Imperfections, Institutions and Policies, Oxford University Press, 2006Google Scholar
Carlsnaes, W.et al. (eds.), Handbook of International Relations, Sage, 2002
Carlyle, Thomas, Signs of the Times (originally published in 1829), reprinted in Critical and Miscellaneous Essays, vol. 2, James Fraser, 1840Google Scholar
Chang, Ha-Joon (ed.), The Rebel Within, Wimbledon Publishing Company, 2001
Checkel, Jeffrey T., ‘The Constructivist Turn in International Relations Theory’, Review Article, World Politics, 50(2), 1998, pp. 324–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., ‘The Nature of the Firm’ (1937); reproduced as chapter 2 in The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development, ed. Williamson, Oliver E. and Winter, Sidney G., Oxford University Press, 1991Google Scholar
Colander, David, The Lost Art of Economics – Essays on Economics and the Economics Profession, Edward Elgar, 2001Google Scholar
Coleman, William Oliver, Economics and its Enemies – Two Centuries of Anti-Economics, Palgrave Macmillan, 2002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, ‘Lay Sermon addressed to the Higher and Middle Classes’ (originally published in 1817), and ‘The Statesman's Manual’ (originally published in 1816), reprinted in Biographia Literaria and Two Lay Sermons, George Bell & Son, 1898Google Scholar
Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, Biographia Literaria (originally published in 1817), ed. Shawcross, J., vols. I and II, Oxford, 1907Google Scholar
Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, On the Constitution of the Church and State (originally published in 1830), ed. Barrell, John, J. M. Dent & Sons, 1972Google Scholar
Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, ‘Lecture on Romeo and Juliet’ (9 December 1811), and ‘Lecture on the Slave Trade’ (June 1795), extracts reprinted in Hill, John Spencer (ed.), Imagination in Coleridge, Macmillan, 1978, pp. 81f., 27f.Google Scholar
Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, Table Talk (originally published in 1835), extracts reprinted in ‘The Oxford Authors’ Samuel Taylor Coleridge', ed. Jackson, H. J., Oxford University Press, 1985, pp. 590–603Google Scholar
Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, ‘Dejection: An Ode’, ‘A Letter to Sara Hutchinson’, and ‘Kubla Khan’, in Selected Poems, ed. Holmes, Richard, Penguin, 1996Google Scholar
Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, Notebooks, extracts reprinted in Coleridge's Notebooks – A Selection, ed. Perry, Seamus, Oxford University Press, 2002Google Scholar
Connell, Philip, Romanticism, Economics and the Question of ‘Culture’, Oxford University Press, 2001Google Scholar
Coyle, Diane, The Soulful Science – What Economists Really Do and Why It Matters, Princeton University Press, 2007Google Scholar
,CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, Challenging Neighbours – Rethinking German and Dutch Economic Institutions, Springer-Verlag, 1997Google Scholar
Critchley, Simon and Schroeder, William R. (eds.), A Companion to Continental Philosophy, Blackwell, 1998
Crouch, Colin, Capitalist Diversity and Change – Recombinant Governance and Institutional Entrepreneurs, Oxford University Press, 2005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crouch, Colin and Streek, Wolfgang (eds.), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism – Mapping Convergence and Diversity, Sage, 1997
Dasgupta, Partha, ‘Modern Economics and its Critics’, chapter 3 in Fact and Fiction in Economics: Models, Realism and Social Construction, ed. Mäki, Uskali, Cambridge University Press, 2002Google Scholar
Day, Aidan, Romanticism, Routledge, 1996CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bono, Edward, article on ‘Lateral Thinking’, in The Oxford Companion to the Mind, ed. Gregory, Richard L., Oxford University Press, 1987, p. 428f.Google Scholar
Quincey, Thomas, The Logic of Political Economy (1844), in The Collected Writings of Thomas de Quincey, ed. Masson, David, vol. IX, Adam & Charles Black, 1890
Donald, Merlin, Origins of the Modern Mind: Three Stages in the Evolution of Culture and Cognition, Harvard University Press, 1991Google Scholar
Drolet, Michael, Tocqueville, Democracy and Social Reform, Palgrave Macmillan, 2003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drolet, Michael (ed.) The Postmodernism Reader – Foundational Texts, Routledge, 2004
Dunn, Stephen P., ‘Keynes and Transformation’, chapter 13 in The Philosophy of Keynes's Economics: Probability, Uncertainty and Convention, ed. Runde, Jochen and Mizuhara, Sohei, Routledge, 2003Google Scholar
Eliot, George, Middlemarch (originally published in 1871), Penguin, 1965Google Scholar
Esping-Anderson, Gøsta, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Polity Press, 1990Google Scholar
Ferguson, Niall, The Cash Nexus, Allen Lane, 2001Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving, Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices, Yale University Press, 1925Google Scholar
Fleischacker, Samuel, On Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations – A Philosophical Companion, Princeton University Press, 2004Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, ‘The Methodology of Positive Economics’, from Essays in Positive Economics, University of Chicago Press, 1953; reproduced as chapter 9 in The Philosophy of Economics – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Hausman, Daniel M., Cambridge University Press, 1994Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis, The End of History and the Last Man, Penguin, 1992Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis, Trust – The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity, Penguin, 1996Google Scholar
Gamble, Andrew, Hayek – The Iron Cage of Liberty, Polity Press, 1996Google Scholar
Gerrard, Bill, ‘Keynesian Uncertainty: What do we Know?’, chapter 19 in The Philosophy of Keynes's Economics: Probability, Uncertainty and Convention, ed. Runde, Jochen and Mizuhara, Sohei, Routledge, 2003Google Scholar
Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, Oxford University Press, 1998CrossRef
Gray, John, Enlightenment's Wake – Politics and Culture at the Close of the Modern Age, Routledge, 1995CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gray, John, Mill on Liberty – A Defence, 2nd edn., Routledge, 1996Google Scholar
Gray, John, False Dawn – The Delusions of Global Capitalism, Granta Books, 1998Google Scholar
Gray, John, Hayek on Liberty, 3rd edn., Routledge, 1998Google Scholar
Gray, John, Two Faces of Liberalism, Polity Press, 2000Google Scholar
Grayling, A. C., The Quarrel of the Age: The Life and Times of William Hazlitt, Phoenix Press, 2001Google Scholar
Grayling, A. C., Wittgenstein – A Very Short Introduction, Oxford University Press, 2001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, Donald P. and Shapiro, Ian, Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory – A Critique of Applications in Political Science, Yale University Press, 1994Google Scholar
Greenfeld, Liah, The Spirit of Capitalism – Nationalism and Economic Growth, Harvard University Press, 2001Google Scholar
Gregory, Richard L. (ed.), The Oxford Companion to the Mind, Oxford University Press, 1987
Hall, Peter A. and Soskice, David (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism – The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford University Press, 2001CrossRef
Hancké, Bob and Goyer, Michel, ‘Degrees of Freedom: Rethinking the Institutional Analysis of Economic Change’, chapter 3 in Changing Capitalisms? – Internationalisation, Institutional Change and Systems of Economic Organisation, ed. Morgan, G., Whitley, R. and Moen, E., Oxford University Press, 2005Google Scholar
Hancké, Bob, Rhodes, Martin and Thatcher, Mark (eds.), Beyond Varieties of Capitalism – Conflict, Contradiction, and Complementarities in the European Economy, Oxford University Press, 2007CrossRef
Hausman, Daniel M. (ed.), The Philosophy of Economics – An Anthology, 2nd edn., Cambridge University Press, 1994
Hausman, Daniel M. and McPherson, Michael S., Economic Analysis and Moral Philosophy, Cambridge University Press, 1996Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A., ‘Competition as a Discovery Procedure’, in New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas, by Hayek, F. A., University of Chicago Press, 1978CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hazlitt, William, ‘On Reason and Imagination’, Essay V in The Plain Speaker, in The Collected Works of William Hazlitt, ed. Waller, A. R. and Glover, A., vol. XII, J. M. Dent & Co., 1903Google Scholar
Hazlitt, William, An Essay on the Principles of Human Action (originally published in 1805), reprinted in The Selected Writings of William Hazlitt, ed. Wu, Duncan, vol. 1, Pickering & Chatto, 1998, pp. 3–82Google Scholar
Hazlitt, William, The Spirit of the Age, 2nd edn. (originally published in 1825), essays on ‘Jeremy Bentham’ and ‘Mr. Coleridge’, The Wordsworth Trust, 2004Google Scholar
Heap, S., Hollis, M., Lyons, B., Sugden, R. and Weale, A. (eds.), The Theory of Choice – A Critical Guide, Blackwell, 1992
Hedley, Douglas, Coleridge, Philosophy and Religion – Aids to Reflection and the Mirror of the Spirit, Cambridge University Press, 2000CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heinzelman, Kurt, The Economics of the Imagination, University of Massachusetts Press, 1980Google Scholar
Henderson, W. O., Friedrich List: Economist and Visionary 1789–1846, Frank Cass, 1983Google Scholar
Herder, J. G., Essay on the Origin of Language (originally published in 1772), extracts trans. Barnard, F. M., in J. G. Herder on Social and Political Culture, Cambridge University Press, 1969Google Scholar
Herder, J. G., Ideas for a Philosophy of the History of Mankind (originally published in 1791), extracts trans. Barnard, F. M., in J. G. Herder on Social and Political Culture, Cambridge University Press, 1969Google Scholar
Hill, John Spencer (ed.), Imagination in Coleridge, Macmillan, 1978CrossRef
Hodgkiss, Philip, The Making of the Modern Mind – The Surfacing of Consciousness in Social Thought, The Athlone Press, 2001Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M., Economics and Utopia – Why the Learning Economy is not the End of History, Routledge, 1999Google Scholar
Hollander, Samuel, The Economics of John Stuart Mill, vol. I, University of Toronto Press, 1985Google Scholar
Hollingdale, R. J. (trans. and ed.), A Nietzsche Reader, Penguin, 1977
Hollis, Martin, ‘Autonomy’, chapter 6 in The Theory of Choice – A Critical Guide, ed. Heap, S., Hollis, M., Lyons, B., Sugden, R. and Weale, A., Blackwell, 1992Google Scholar
Holmes, Richard, Coleridge – Darker Reflections, HarperCollins, 1998Google Scholar
Howell, Chris, ‘Varieties of Capitalism: And Then There Was One?’, Comparative Politics, 36(1) (October 2003), pp. 103–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howkins, John, The Creative Economy – How People Make Money from Ideas, Penguin, 2001Google Scholar
Hume, David, An Inquiry Concerning Human Understanding (1777), and extracts from A Treatise of Human Nature (1740), reprinted in David Hume on Human Nature and the Understanding, ed. Flew, Anthony, Macmillan, 1962Google Scholar
Innes, Abby, Czechoslovakia – The Short Goodbye, Yale University Press, 2001Google Scholar
Jackson, Robert, The Global Covenant: Human Conduct in a World of States, Oxford University Press, 2000Google Scholar
Jacobs, Michael, The Green Economy – Environment, Sustainable Development and the Politics of the Future, Pluto Press, 1991Google Scholar
Johnson, Björn, ‘Institutional Learning’, chapter 2 in National Systems of Innovation, ed. Lundvall, Bengt-Åke, Pinter, 1995Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos, ‘Choices, Values, and Frames’, American Psychologist, 39(4) (1984), reprinted as chapter 1 in Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, Cambridge University Press, 2000CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kay, John A., The Business of Economics, Oxford University Press, 1996CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keats, John, Lamia (originally published in 1819), reprinted in Romanticism – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Wu, Duncan, Blackwell, 1998, pp. 1064–79Google Scholar
Keats, John, ‘Letter to George and Tom Keats’, 21 December 1817, extract reprinted in Romanticism – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Wu, Duncan, Blackwell, 1998, p. 1019Google Scholar
Kemp, John, The Philosophy of Kant, Thoemmes Press, 1995Google Scholar
Kenny, Anthony (ed.), The Wittgenstein Reader, Blackwell, 1994
Kermode, Frank, Romantic Image, Routledge, 2002Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, ‘A Tract on Monetary Reform’ (1923), chapter 3 in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. IV, Macmillan, 1971Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, Essay on ‘Thomas Robert Malthus’, essay on ‘Alfred Marshall’ and essay on ‘Francis Ysidro Edgeworth’, chapters 12, 14, 16, in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. X, Macmillan, 1972Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (originally published in 1936), in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. VII, Macmillan, 1973Google Scholar
Keynes, John Neville, The Scope and Method of Political Economy, 3rd edn., Macmillan, 1904Google Scholar
Kitschelt, Herbert, Lange, Peter, Marks, Gary and Stephens, John D., ‘Convergence and Divergence in Advanced Capitalist Democracies’, chapter 15 in Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, ed. Kitschelt, Herbertet al., Cambridge University Press, 1999CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul, Development, Geography, and Economic Theory, MIT Press, 1997Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S., The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 3rd edn., University of Chicago Press, 1996CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layard, Richard, Happiness – Lessons from a New Science, Allen Lane, 2005Google Scholar
Leavis, F. R. (ed.), Mill on Bentham and Coleridge, Chatto & Windus, 1950Google Scholar
Levinson, Marjorie, The Romantic Fragment Poem – A Critique of a Form, University of North Carolina Press, 1986Google Scholar
List, Friedrich, Outlines of American Political Economy, 1827, extracts quoted in Henderson, W. O., Friedrich List: Economist and Visionary 1789–1846, Frank Cass, 1983, pp. 145–55Google Scholar
List, Friedrich, The National System of Political Economy, 1841, trans. Lloyd, S. S., Longmans, Green & Co., 1922, extracts quoted in Greenfeld, Liah, The Spirit of Capitalism – Nationalism and Economic Growth, Harvard University Press, 2001, pp. 201–6Google Scholar
Little, I. M. D., Ethics, Economics, and Politics – Principles of Public Policy, Oxford University Press, 2002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lockridge, Laurence S., The Ethics of Romanticism, Cambridge University Press, 1989CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lovejoy, A. O., ‘On the Discrimination of Romanticisms’, from Essays in the History of Ideas, Johns Hopkins University Press, 1948, reprinted in English Romantic Poets – Modern Essays in Criticism, ed. M. H. Abrams, Oxford University Press, 1975, pp. 3–24Google Scholar
Lovelock, James, The Revenge of Gaia, Penguin, 2006Google Scholar
Lundvall, Bengt-Åke, chapters 1, 3 in National Systems of Innovation – Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning, ed. Lundvall, Bengt-Åke, Pinter, 1995Google Scholar
Lyons, Bruce, ‘Risk, Ignorance and Imagination’, ‘Game Theory’ and ‘Organisations’, chapters 4, 7, 10 in The Theory of Choice – A Critical Guide, ed. Heap, S., Hollis, M., Lyons, B., Sugden, R. and Weale, A., Blackwell, 1992Google Scholar
MacIntyre, Alasdair, After Virtue – A Study in Moral Theory, Duckworth, 1981Google Scholar
Magee, Bryan, The Great Philosophers – An Introduction to Western Philosophy, BBC Books, 1987Google Scholar
Magee, Bryan, Confessions of a Philosopher – A Journey Through Western Philosophy, Phoenix, 1997Google Scholar
Mäki, Uskali (ed.), Fact and Fiction in Economics: Models, Realism and Social Construction, Cambridge University Press, 2002CrossRef
Malthus, Robert, An Essay on the Principle of Population (originally published in 1798), and A Summary View of the Principle of Population (originally published in 1830), ed. Flew, Anthony, Penguin, 1970Google Scholar
Malthus, Robert, Letter to David Ricardo, 26 January 1817; extract reprinted in Keynes, John Maynard, essay on ‘Thomas Robert Malthus’, in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. X, Macmillan, 1972, p. 97f.Google Scholar
March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P., Rediscovering Institutions: The Organisational Basis of Politics, Free Press, 1989Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred, Principles of Economics, Eighth Edition (including Preface to First Edition, 1890), Macmillan, 1927Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred, Inaugural Lecture, extract quoted in Keynes, John Maynard, essay on ‘Alfred Marshall’, in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. X, Macmillan, 1972, p. 196Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred, Letter to Arthur Lyon Bowley, 21 February 1901; Letter to Arthur Lyon Bowley, 3 March 1901; Letter to Arthur Lyon Bowley, 27 February 1906, Letters 634, 637, 840, in The Correspondence of Alfred Marshall, ed. Whitaker, J. K., vols. 2, 3, Cambridge University Press, 1996Google Scholar
Martin, Michael, ‘Taylor on Interpretation and the Sciences of Man’, chapter 17 in Readings in the Philosophy of Social Science, ed. Martin, Michael and McIntyre, Lee C., MIT Press, 1994Google Scholar
Martin, Michael and McIntyre, Lee, C. (eds.), Readings in the Philosophy of Social Science, MIT Press, 1994
Marx, Karl and Engels, Frederick, Manifesto of the Communist Party (originally published in 1848), Progress Publishers (Moscow), 1977Google Scholar
Mason, John Hope, The Value of Creativity – The Origins and Emergence of a Modern Belief, Ashgate, 2003Google Scholar
Mayall, James, Nationalism and International Society, Cambridge University Press, 1990CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCalman, Iain (ed.), An Oxford Companion to the Romantic Age – British Culture 1776–1832, Oxford University Press, 1999
McCloskey, D. N., The Rhetoric of Economics, 2nd edn., University of Wisconsin Press, 1998Google Scholar
McDonagh, Josephine, De Quincey's Disciplines, Oxford University Press, 1994CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFarland, Thomas, Originality and Imagination, Johns Hopkins University Press, 1985Google Scholar
Merquior, J. G., Foucault, Fontana Press, 1985Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart, ‘Essay on the Definition of Political Economy; and on the Method of Investigation Proper to it’ (originally published in 1830), as Essay V in Mill, J. S., Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy, 3rd edn., Longmans, Green & Co., 1877Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart, Essay on ‘Bentham’ (originally published in 1838), and essay on ‘Coleridge’ (originally published in 1840), in Mill on Bentham and Coleridge, ed. Leavis, F. R., Chatto & Windus, 1950Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart, Utilitarianism (originally published in 1861), ed. Warnock, Mary, William Collins & Sons, 1962Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart, Autobiography (originally published in 1873), Penguin, 1989Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart, On Liberty (originally published in 1859), in On Liberty and Other Essays, ed. Gray, John, Oxford University Press, 1991Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart, Principles of Political Economy (originally published in 1848), ed. Riley, Jonathan, Oxford University Press, 1994Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip, More Heat than Light – Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics, Cambridge University Press, 1989CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Gareth, Images of Organization, Sage, 2006Google Scholar
Morgan, G., Whitley, R. and Moen, E. (eds.), Changing Capitalisms? – Internationalisation, Institutional Change and Systems of Economic Organisation, Oxford University Press, 2005
Mueller, Dennis C., Public Choice II, Cambridge University Press, 1989Google Scholar
Murdoch, Iris, ‘The Darkness of Practical Reason’, Review article in Encounter, July 1966, reprinted in Murdoch, Iris, Existentialists and Mystics – Writings on Philosophy and Literature, ed. Conradi, Peter, Chatto & Windus, 1997, pp. 193–202Google Scholar
Murdoch, Iris, Sartre: Romantic Rationalist, Vintage, 1999Google Scholar
Nietzsche, Friedrich, The Twilight of the Idols (originally published in 1889), and Notes on ‘Thus Spake Zarathustra’, trans. Ludovici, Anthony M., George Allen & Unwin, 1911Google Scholar
Nietzsche, Friedrich, Extracts from Beyond Good and Evil (originally published in 1886), The Gay Science (originally published in 1882) and Thus Spake Zarathustra, part IV (originally published in 1892), in A Nietzsche Reader, sel. and trans. Hollingdale, R. J., Penguin, 1977Google Scholar
Norris, Christopher, Derrida, Fontana, 1987Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton University Press, 2005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offe, Claus, ‘Political Economy: Sociological Perspectives’, chapter 29 in A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Oxford University Press, 1998Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action, Harvard University Press, 1965Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur, The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities, Yale University Press, 1982Google Scholar
Ormorod, Paul, The Death of Economics, Faber & Faber, 1994Google Scholar
Ortony, Andrew, article on ‘Metaphor’, in The Oxford Companion to the Mind, ed. Gregory, Richard L., Oxford University Press, 1987, pp. 478–81Google Scholar
Paulin, Tom, The Day-Star of Liberty – William Hazlitt's Radical Style, Faber & Faber, 1998Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C., Alfred Marshall and Current Thought – Lecture on Mathematical Methods, Macmillan, 1953Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R., Conjectures and Refutations – The Growth of Scientific Knowledge, Routledge, 1963Google Scholar
Porter, Michael E., The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Macmillan, 1990CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, Matthew, ‘Psychology and Economics’, Journal of Economic Literature, XXXVI (March 1998), pp. 11–46Google Scholar
Raphael, D. D., Adam Smith, Oxford University Press, 1985Google Scholar
Ricardo, David, On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (originally published in 1817), reprinted in The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. Sraffa, Piero, vol. 1, Cambridge University Press, 1951Google Scholar
Ricardo, David, Letter to Robert Malthus, 24 January 1817, extract reprinted in Keynes, John Maynard, essay on ‘Thomas Robert Malthus’, in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. X, Macmillan, 1972, p. 97Google Scholar
Rifkin, Jeremy, The End of Work, G. P. Putnam & Sons, 1995Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel, An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, 2nd edn., Macmillan, 1935, extracts reprinted as chapter 3 in The Philosophy of Economics – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Hausman, Daniel M., Cambridge University Press, 1994Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel, A History of Economic Thought – The LSE Lectures, ed. Medema, Steven G. and Samuels, Warren J., Princeton University Press, 1998Google Scholar
Roll, Eric, A History of Economic Thought, 5th edn., Faber & Faber, 1992Google Scholar
Rothschild, Emma, Economic Sentiments – Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment, Harvard University Press, 2001Google Scholar
Rothstein, Bo, ‘Political Institutions: An Overview’, chapter 4 in A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Oxford University Press, 1998Google Scholar
Runde, Jochen and Mizuhara, Sohei (eds.), The Philosophy of Keynes's Economics: Probability, Uncertainty and Convention, Routledge, 2003CrossRef
Ruskin, John, Unto this Last (originally published in 1862), ed. Wilmer, Clive, Penguin, 1985Google Scholar
Russell, Bertrand, A History of Western Philosophy, George Allen & Unwin, 1946Google Scholar
Sabel, Charles F., ‘Intelligible Differences: On Deliberate Strategy and the Exploration of Possibility in Economic Life’, Rivista Italiana degli Economisti, I, 1996, pp. 55–80; also available at www2.law.columbia.edu/sabel/papersGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul Anthony, Foundations of Economic Analysis, Harvard University Press, 1947Google Scholar
Schlegel, Friedrich, Fragment 53 from Athenaeum Fragments (originally published in 1798), quoted in Beer, John, ‘Fragmentations and Ironies’, in Questioning Romanticism, ed. Beer, John, Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995, p. 251Google Scholar
Schlegel, Friedrich, Fragment 108 from Critical Fragments (originally published in 1797), and a fragment from Ideas (originally published in the last volume of the Athenaeum, 1800), quoted in ‘Friedrich Schlegel and Novalis’, by Behler, Ernst, in A Companion to Continental Philosophy, ed. Critchley, Simon and Schroeder, William R., Blackwell, 1998, p. 80f.Google Scholar
Schlegel, Friedrich, Athenaeum fragment 206, and extract from Studien des Klassichen Altertums, 98, quoted in Armstrong, Charles I., Romantic Organicism – From Idealist Origins to Ambivalent Afterlife, Palgrave Macmillan, 2003, p. 43f.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A., History of Economic Analysis, George Allen & Unwin, 1954Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A., Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (originally published in 1943), Routledge, 1994Google Scholar
Schwartz, Barry, The Paradox of Choice – Why More is Less, HarperCollins, 2004Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya, On Ethics and Economics, Blackwell, 1987Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya, ‘Rationality and Social Choice’, American Economic Review, 85 (1995); reproduced as chapter 16 in Readings in Political Economy, ed. Kaushik Basu, Blackwell, 2003Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S., Decision, Order and Time in Human Affairs, Cambridge University Press, 1961Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S., Imagination and the Nature of Choice, Edinburgh University Press, 1979Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S., Epistemics and Economics – A Critique of Economic Doctrines (originally published in 1972), Transaction Publishers, 1992Google Scholar
Shelley, Percy Bysshe, A Defence of Poetry (originally published in 1840), extracts reprinted in Romanticism – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Wu, Duncan, Blackwell, 1998, pp. 944–56Google Scholar
Skidelski, Robert, John Maynard Keynes, Volume Two – The Economist as Saviour, 1920–1937, Macmillan, 1992Google Scholar
Skorupski, John, The Cambridge Companion to Mill, Cambridge University Press, 1998CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (originally published in 1759), ed. Raphael, D. D. and Macfie, A. L., Oxford University Press, 1976Google Scholar
Smith, Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (originally published in 1776), ed. Sutherland, Kathryn, Oxford University Press, 1993Google Scholar
Smith, Adam, ‘History of Astronomy’, in Essays on Philosophical Subjects (originally published in 1795), ed. Wightman, W. P. D. and Bryce, J. C., Oxford University Press, 1980, extracts quoted in Fleischacker, Samuel, On Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations – A Philosophical Companion, Princeton University Press, 2004, pp. 21, 32Google Scholar
Snow, C. P., The Two Cultures and the Scientific Revolution, Cambridge University Press, 1959Google Scholar
Soros, George, The Crisis of Global Capitalism: Open Society Endangered, Little Brown, 1998Google Scholar
Soskice, David, ‘Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s’, chapter 4 in Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, ed. Kitschelt, Herbertet al., Cambridge University Press, 1999Google Scholar
Stafford, William, John Stuart Mill, Macmillan, 1998CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., Principles of Micro-Economics, 2nd edn., W. W. Norton, 1997Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., ‘Whither Reform? Ten Years of the Transition’, Keynote Address, Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, 1999; reproduced as chapter 4 in The Rebel Within, ed. Chang, Ha-Joon, Wimbledon Publishing Company, 2001Google Scholar
Sutton, John,Marshall's Tendencies – What Can Economists Know?MIT Press, 2000Google Scholar
Tabb, William K., Reconstructing Political Economy – The Great Divide in Economic Thought, Routledge, 1999Google Scholar
Tarnas, Richard, The Passion of the Western Mind – Understanding the Ideas that have Shaped our World View, Ballantine Books, 1993Google Scholar
Taylor, Charles, ‘Interpretation and the Sciences of Man’, Review of Metaphysics, 25 (1971); reproduced as chapter 13 in Readings in the Philosophy of Social Science, ed. Michael Martin and Lee C. McIntyre, MIT Press, 1994Google Scholar
Todaro, Michael P., Economic Development, 5th edn., Longman, 1994Google Scholar
,United Nations Development Program, Human Development Report 1996, Oxford University Press; for recent years, see http://hdr.undp.org/en
Veblen, Thorstein, ‘The Limitations of Marginal Utility’, Journal of Political Economy, 17 (1909); reproduced as chapter 6 in The Philosophy of Economics – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Daniel M. Hausman, Cambridge University Press, 1994CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldrop, M. Mitchell, Complexity – The Emerging Science at the Edge of Order and Chaos, Penguin, 1994Google Scholar
Warnock, Mary, Imagination, Faber & Faber, 1976Google Scholar
Waterman, A. M. C., Revolution, Economics and Religion: Christian Political Economy, 1798–1833, Cambridge University Press, 1991CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weale, Albert ‘Homo economicus, Homo sociologicus’, chapter 5 in The Theory of Choice – A Critical Guide, ed. Heap, S., Hollis, M., Lyons, B., Sugden, R. and Weale, A., Blackwell, 1992Google Scholar
Webb, Beatrice, My Apprenticeship (1883), extracts quoted in Leavis, F. R., ‘Introduction’, in Mill on Bentham and Coleridge, Chatto & Windus, 1950, pp. 18–29Google Scholar
Weber, Max, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (originally published in English in 1930), Routledge, 1992Google Scholar
Weimer, David L. and Vining, Aidan R., Policy Analysis: Concepts and Practice, 2nd edn., Prentice Hall, 1992Google Scholar
Whale, John, Imagination Under Pressure, 1789–1832 – Aesthetics, Politics and Utility, Cambridge University Press, 2000CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, Raymond, Culture and Society: 1780–1950, Chatto & Windus, 1958Google Scholar
Winch, Donald, ‘Political Economy’, chapter 33 in An Oxford Companion to the Romantic Age – British Culture 1776–1832, ed. McCalman, Iain, Oxford University Press, 1999Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, Ludwig, Philosophical Investigations, trans. Anscombe, G. E. M. (originally published in 1953), Blackwell, 2001Google Scholar
Wordsworth, William, The Prelude (1805), ed. Selincourt, E., Oxford University Press, 1960Google Scholar
Wordsworth, William, Preface to the Lyrical Ballads, 1800, and 1802 amendment, in Wordsworth, William and Coleridge, Samuel Taylor, Lyrical Ballads, ed. Brett, R. L. and Jones, A. R., Methuen, 1963, pp. 235–66Google Scholar
Wordsworth, William, ‘Fragment’, dated by E. de Selincourt as 1798–1800, reproduced in Warnock, Mary, Imagination, Faber & Faber, 1976, p. 125Google Scholar
Wordsworth, William, The Prelude (1850), ed. Wordsworth, J., Abrams, M. H. and Gill, S., W. W. Norton, 1979Google Scholar
Wordsworth, William, ‘Lines Written a Few Miles above Tintern Abbey’, and ‘The Tables Turned’ (from Lyrical Ballads, 1798), reprinted in Romanticism – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Duncan Wu, Blackwell, 1998, pp. 260f., 265–9
Wordsworth, William, Preface to Poems (1815), reprinted in Romanticism – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Wu, Duncan, Blackwell, 1998, pp. 411–14Google Scholar
Wordsworth, William, ‘The world is too much with us’ (from Poems in Two Volumes, 1807), reprinted in Romanticism – An Anthology, 2nd edn., ed. Wu, Duncan, Blackwell, 1998, p. 372Google Scholar
,World Bank, From Plan to Market, World Development Report, 1996, Oxford University Press, 1996Google Scholar
Wu, Duncan (ed.), Romanticism – An Anthology, 2nd edn., Blackwell, 1998

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Richard Bronk, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: The Romantic Economist
  • Online publication: 05 March 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139166805.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Richard Bronk, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: The Romantic Economist
  • Online publication: 05 March 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139166805.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Richard Bronk, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: The Romantic Economist
  • Online publication: 05 March 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139166805.014
Available formats
×