Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-pwrkn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-07T01:19:39.326Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2011

Stefan Hedlund
Affiliation:
Uppsala Universitet, Sweden
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Invisible Hands, Russian Experience, and Social Science
Approaches to Understanding Systemic Failure
, pp. 281 - 300
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Appleby, Joyce (2010), The Relentless Revolution: A History of Capitalism, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Aquinas, Thomas Saint (1981), Summa Theologica: Complete English Edition in Five Volumes, London: Sheed & Ward.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1973), Information and Economic Behavior, Stockholm: Federation of Swedish Industries.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1990), “Kenneth Arrow,” in Swedberg, Richard (ed.), Economics and Sociology. Redefining Their Boundaries: Conversations with Economists and Sociologists, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 133–51.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1994), “Methodological Individualism and Social Knowledge,”American Economic Review, vol. 84, no. 2, pp. 1–9.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (2004), “Path Dependence and Competitive Equilibrium,” in Sundstrom, W., Guinnane, T., and Whatley, W. (eds.), History Matters: Essays on Economic Growth, Technology, and Demographic Change, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 23–35.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth and Debreu, Gérard (1954), “The Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy,”Econometrica, vol. 22, no. 3, pp. 265–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian (1988), “Self-Reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics,” in Anderson, Philip W., Arrow, Kenneth J., and Pines, David (eds.), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, pp. 9–27.Google Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian (1989), “Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical Events,”Economic Journal, vol. 99, March, pp. 116–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banfield, Edward C. (1958), The Moral Basis of a Backward Society, Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Baran, Paul A. and Sweezy, Paul M. (1966), Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic and Social Order, New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Barber, Bernard (1995), “All Economies Are ‘Embedded’: The Career of a Concept, and Beyond,”Social Research, vol. 62, no. 2, pp. 387–413.Google Scholar
Barkai, Haim (1977), Growth Patterns of the Kibbutz Economy, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Barone, Enrico (1908), “Il Ministro della Produzione nello Stato Collettivista,”Giornale degli Economisti, September/October, 2, pp. 267–293, translated as Barone, Enrico (1935), “The Ministry of Production in the Collectivist State,” in Friedrich A. Hayek (ed.), Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, London: G. Routledge, pp. 245–90.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Figueiredo Jr, Rui J.P.., and Weingast, Barry R. (1998), “The Politics of Interpretation: Rationality, Culture, and Transition,”Politics & Society, vol. 26, no. 2, pp. 221–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H. et al. (1998), Analytic Narratives, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Beccaria, Cesare, Marchese di (2006), An Essay on Crimes and Punishments, Clark, NJ: Lawbook Exchange. (Original published in 1764.)Google Scholar
Bergson, Abram (1967), “Market Socialism Revisited,”Journal of Political Economy, vol. 75, no. 5, pp. 655–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, Lloyd E. and Crummey, Robert O. (eds.) (1968), Rude and Barbarous Kingdom: Russia in the Accounts of Sixteenth-Century English Voyagers, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.
Billington, James H. (1970), The Icon and the Axe: An Interpretive History of Russian Culture, New York: Vintage.Google Scholar
Birnbaum, Henrik (1996), Novgorod in Focus: Selected Essays by Henrik Birnbaum, Columbus, Oh: Slavica.Google Scholar
Blum, Jerome (1964), Lord and Peasant in Russia: From the Ninth to the Nineteenth Century, New York: Atheneum.Google Scholar
Brabant, Jozef M. (1998), The Political Economy of Transition: Coming to Grips with History and Methodology, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Braudel, Fernand (1976), The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II, Vol. 2, New York: Harper Colophon Books. (First published in 1949.)Google Scholar
Braudel, Fernand (1992), Civilization and Capitalism: 15th – 18th Century, Vol. 2, The Wheels of Commerce, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Brinton, Mary C. and Nee, Victor (eds.) (1998), The New Institutionalism in Sociology, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Brown, A. H. [Archie] (1975), “Adam Smith's First Russian Followers,” in Skinner, Andrew S. and Wilson, Thomas (eds.), Essays on Adam Smith, Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 247–73.Google Scholar
Brown, Archie (2006), “Cultural Change and Continuity in the Transition from Communism,” in: Harrison, Lawrence E. and Berger, Peter L. (eds.), Developing Cultures: Case Studies, New York: Routledge, pp. 387–405.Google Scholar
Brown, Archie (2007), Seven Years that Changed the World: Perestroika in Perspective, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Brown, Archie (2009), The Rise and Fall of Communism, London: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. (1975), The Limits of Liberty – Between Anarchy and Leviathan, Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. (1979), “An Economist's Approach to ‘Scientific Politics,’” in Buchanan, (ed.), What Should Economists Do?, Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Press, pp. 143–59.Google Scholar
Cairnes, John (1873), “M. Comte and Political Economy,” in Cairnes, Essays in Political Economy: Theoretical and Applied, London: Macmillan, pp. 265–311.Google Scholar
Cardoso, Fernando Henrique and Faletto, Enzo (1979), Dependency and Development in Latin America, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Carlyle, Thomas (1837), The French Revolution: A History, Vols. 1–3, London: Chapman and Hall.Google Scholar
Carlyle, Thomas (1853), Occasional Discourse on the Nigger Question, London: Bosworth.Google Scholar
Clark, Gregory (2007), A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Colson, Elizabeth (1974), Tradition and Contract: The Problem of Order, Chicago: Adeline.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1937), “The Nature of the Firm,”Economica, vol. 4, no. 16, pp. 386–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1984), “The New Institutional Economics,”Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol. 140, no. 1, pp. 229–31.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1992), “The Institutional Structure of Production,”American Economic Review, vol. 82, no. 4, pp. 713–19.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. (1990), Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, James (1994), “A Rational Choice Perspective on Economic Sociology,” in Smelser, Neil J. and Swedberg, Richard (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 166–80.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul (2008), The Bottom Billion: Why the Poorest Countries Are Failing and What Can Be Done About It, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Collins, Randall (1980), “Weber's Last Theory of Capitalism: A Systematization,”American Sociological Review, vol. 45, no. 6, pp. 925–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, Randall (1994), Four Sociological Traditions, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. (1924), Legal Foundations of Capitalism, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. (1931), “Institutional Economics,”American Economic Review, vol. 21, no. 4, pp. 648–57.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. (1934a), Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. (1934b), Myself, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Comte, Auguste (1830–42), Cours de philosophie positive, Vols. 1–6, Paris: Bachelier.Google Scholar
Comte, Auguste (1869), Cours de philosophie positive, 3d ed., Vol. 4, Paris: Ballière.Google Scholar
Comte, Auguste (1883), Opuscules de Philosophie Sociale, 1819–1828, Paris: E. Leroux.Google Scholar
Conquest, Robert (1968), The Great Terror: Stalin's Purge of the Thirties, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Conquest, Robert (1986), The Harvest of Sorrow: Soviet Collectivization and the Terror-famine, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Conquest, Robert (1990), The Great Terror: A Reassessment, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Conrad, Alfred H. and Meyer, John R. (1958), “The Economics of Slavery in the Ante-Bellum South,”Journal of Political Economy, vol. 66, no. 2, pp. 95–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, Julian M. (2006), “Can Russia Compete in the Global Economy?,”Eurasian Geography and Economics, vol. 47, no 4, pp. 407–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cross, Samuel H. (ed. and transl.) (1953), The Russian Primary Chronicle, Cambridge, MA.
Crummey, Robert O. (1983), Aristocrats and Servitors: The Boyar Elite in Russia, 1613–1689, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Custine, Astolphe, Marquis de (1989), Empire of the Czar: A Journey through Eternal Russia, New York: Doubleday. (Original published in 1843.)Google Scholar
David, Paul A. (1985), “Clio and the Economics of QWERTY,”American Economic Review, vol. 75, no. 2, pp. 332–37.Google Scholar
David, Paul A. (1993), “Historical Economics in the Long Run: Some Implications of Path Dependence,” in Snooks, Graeme D. (ed.), Historical Analysis in Economics, London: Routledge, pp. 29–40.Google Scholar
David, Paul A. (1994), “Why Are Institutions the ‘Carriers of History?’: Path Dependence and the Evolution of Conventions, Organizations and Institutions,”Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, vol. 5, no. 2, pp. 205–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
David, Paul A. (1997), “Path Dependence and the Quest for Historical Economics: One More Chorus of the Ballad of QWERTY,”Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History, no. 20, November, pp. 1–47, http://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/economics/history/paper20/david3.pdf, accessed on November 9, 2009.Google Scholar
David, Paul A. (2001), “Path Dependence, Its Critics and the Quest for ‘Historical Economics,’” in Garrouste, Pierre and Ioannides, Stavros (eds.), Evolution and Path Dependence in Economic Ideas: Past and Present, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 15–40.Google Scholar
Debreu, Gérard (1956), Theory of Value, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Long, J. Bradford and Shleifer, Andrei (1993), “Princes and Merchants: European City Growth before the Industrial Revolution,”Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 36, no. 2, pp. 671–702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desai, Raj M. and Goldberg, Itzhak (eds.) (2008), Can Russia Compete?, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.CrossRef
Dewey, Horace W. (1987), “Political Poruka in Muscovite Rus,”Russian Review, vol. 46, no. 2, pp. 117–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewey, Horace W. and Kleimola, Ann M. (1984), “Russian Collective Consciousness: The Kievan Roots,”Slavonic and East European Review, vol. 62, no. 2, pp. 180–91.Google Scholar
Diamond, Jared and Robinson, James A. (eds.) (2010), Natural Experiments of History, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Powell, Walter W. (1991), “Introduction,” in DiMaggio, Paul J. and Powell, Walter W. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: Chicago University Press, pp. 1–40.Google Scholar
Djankov, Simeon, Glaeser, Edward, Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei (2003), “The New Comparative Economics,”Journal of Comparative Economics, vol. 31, no. 4, pp. 595–619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobb, Maurice (1933), “Economic Theory and the Problem of a Socialist Economy,”Economic Journal, vol. 43, no. 172, pp. 588–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbin, Frank (1994), “Cultural Models of Organization: The Social Construction of Rational Organizing Principles,” in Crane, Diane (ed.), The Sociology of Culture, Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 117–53.Google Scholar
Durkheim, Émile (1888), “Cours de science sociale: Leçon d'ouverture,”Revue internationale d'enseignement, Vol. 15, pp. 23–48.Google Scholar
Durkheim, Émile (1909), “Sociologie et sciences sociales,” in Bouasse, H. et al., De la méthode dans les sciences, Paris: F. Alcan, pp. 259–85.Google Scholar
Durkheim, Émile (1978), On Institutional Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Eberstadt, Nicholas (2005), “Russia, The Sick Man of Europe,” The Public Interest, winter, http://www.nationalaffairs.com/public_interest/detail/russia-the-sick-man-of-europe, accessed on February 9, 2010.
Eggertsson, Thráinn (1990), Economic Behavior and Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn (1996), “No Experiments, Monumental Disasters: Why It Took a Thousand Years to Develop a Specialized Fishing Industry in Iceland,”Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, vol. 30, no. 1, pp. 1–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn (1997), “Rethinking the Theory of Economic Policy: Some Implications of the New Institutionalism,” in Nelson, Joan M., Tilly, Charles, and Walker, Lee (eds.), Transforming Post-Communist Economies, Washington, DC: National Academy Press, pp. 61–79.Google Scholar
Eklof, Ben, Bushnell, John, and Zakharova, Larissa (eds.) (1994), Russia's Great Reforms, 1855–1881, Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
Elster, Jon (1974), The Empiricists, Garden City, NY: Anchor Books, .Google Scholar
Elster, Jon (1983), Sour Grapes: Studies in the Subversion of Rationality, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon (ed.) (1986), Rational Choice, New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon (1989a), The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon (1989b), Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon (1989c), Solomonic Judgments, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ferguson, Adam (1996), An Essay on the History of Civil Society, New York: Cambridge University Press. (Original published in 1767.)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Findlay, Ronald (2005), “Kindleberger: Economics and History,”Atlantic Economic Journal, vol. 33, no. 1, pp. 19–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, A. G. (1998), ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Friedland, Roger and Robertson, A. F. (1990), “Beyond the Market Place,” in Friedland, and Robertson, (eds.), Beyond the Market Place: Rethinking Economy and Society, New York: Aldine de Gruyter, pp. 3–49.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis (1989), “The End of History?,”The National Interest, no. 16, summer, pp. 3–18.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis (1992), The End of History and the Last Man, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis (1995), Trust:The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Richter, Rudolf (eds.) (1991), The New Institutional Economics: A Collection of Articles from the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, College Station: Texas A & M University Press.
Fukuyama, Francis (1998), Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Gemici, Kurtulus (2007), “Karl Polanyi and the Antinomies of Embeddedness,”Socio-Economic Review, vol. 6, no. 1, pp. 5–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschenkron, Alexander (1962), Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Goldman, Emma (1923), My Disillusionment in Russia, Garden City, NY: Doubleday, Page.Google Scholar
Goldman, Marshall (1994), Lost Opportunity: What Has Made Economic Reform in Russia so Difficult?, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Goldman, Marshall (2003), The Piratization of Russia: Russian Reform Goes Awry, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gossen, H. H. (1854), Entwicklung der Gesetze des menschlichen Verkehrs und der daraus fließenden Regeln für menschliches Handeln, Braunschweig: Vieweg.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1985), “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,”American Journal of Sociology, vol. 91, no. 3, pp. 481–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1990), “The Old and the New Economic Sociology: A History and an Agenda,” in Friedland, Roger and Robertson, A. F. (eds.), Beyond the Market Place: Rethinking Economy and Society, New York: Aldine de Gruyter, pp. 89–112.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1992a), “Economic Institutions as Social Constructions: A Framework for Analysis,”Acta Sociologica, vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 3–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1992b), “Problems of Explanation in Economic Sociology”, in Nohria, Nitin and Eccles, Robert G. (eds.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form and Action, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, pp. 25–56.Google Scholar
Greenfield, Sidney M., Strickton, Arnold, and Aubey, Robert T. (eds.) (1979), Entrepreneurs in Cultural Context, Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.
Greenspan, Alan (1997), “Remarks by Chairman Alan Greenspan,” at http://www. federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/1997/19970610.htm, accessed on January 19, 2010.
Greenspan, Alan (2008), The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a New World, New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Gregory, Paul R. and Stuart, Robert C. (1974), Soviet Economic Structure and Performance, New York:Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner (1993), “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghrebi Traders' Coalition,”American Economic Review, vol. 83, no. 3, pp. 525–48.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner (1994a), “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies,”Journal of Political Economy, vol. 102, no. 5, pp. 912–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner (1994b), “On the Political Foundations of the Late Medieval Commercial Revolution: Genoa during the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries,”Journal of Economic History, vol. 54, no. 4, pp. 271–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner (1995), “Political Organizations, Social Structure, and Institutional Success: Reflections from Genoa and Venice during the Commercial Revolution,”Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol. 151, no. 4, pp. 734–40.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gregory (1963), “Notes for a Theory of the Command Economy,”Soviet Studies, vol. 15, no. 2, pp. 101–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guillén, Mauro F. et al. (eds.) (2002), The New Economic Sociology: Developments in an Emerging Field, New York: Russell Sage.
Gulati, Ranjay and Gargiulo, Martin (1999), “Where Do Interorganizational Networks Come From?,”American Journal of Sociology, vol. 104, no. 5, pp. 1439–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, Frank (1992), “Autobiographical Notes with Reflections,” in Szenberg, Michael (ed.), Eminent Economists: Their Life Philosophies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 160–66.Google Scholar
Haitani, Kanji (1986), Comparative Economic Systems: Organizational and Managerial Perspectives, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. and Taylor, Rosemary C. R. (1996), “Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms,”Political Studies, vol. 44, pp. 936–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter A. and Taylor, Rosemary C. R. (1998), “The Potential of Historical Institutionalism: A Response to Hay and Wincott,”Political Studies, vol. 46, pp. 958–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter A. and Soskice, David (2001), “An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism,” in Hall, and Soskice, (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 1–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haller, Markus (2004), “Mixing Economics and Ethics: Carl Menger vs Gustav von Schmoller,”Social Science Information, vol. 43, no. 5, pp. 5–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanson, Philip (2002), “Barriers to Long-Run Growth in Russia,”Economy and Society, vol. 31, no. 1, pp. 62–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanson, Philip (2003), The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Economy: An Economic History of the USSR from 1945, London: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Harrison, Lawrence E. (2000a), Underdevelopment Is a State of Mind: The Latin American Case, Lanham: Madison Books.Google Scholar
Harrison, Lawrence E. (2000b), “Why Culture Matters,” in Harrison, Lawrence E. and Huntington, Samuel P. (eds.), Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress, New York: Basic Books, pp. xvii–xxxiv.Google Scholar
Harrison, Lawrence E. and Berger, Peter L. (eds.) (2006), Developing Cultures: Case Studies, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hay, Colin and Wincott, Daniel (1998), “Structure, Agency and Historical Institutionalism,”Political Studies, vol. 46, pp. 951–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1935), Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, London: G. Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1944), The Road to Serfdom, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan (1984), Crisis in Soviet Agriculture, London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan (1989), Private Agriculture in the Soviet Union, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan (1999), Russia's “Market” Economy: A Bad Case of Predatory Capitalism, London: UCL Press.Google Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan (2001), “Russia and the IMF: A Sordid Tale of Moral Hazard,”Demokratizatsiya, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 104–36.Google Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan (2005), Russian Path Dependence, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan (2006), “Vladimir the Great, Grand Prince of Muscovy: Resurrecting the Russian Service State,”Europe-Asia Studies, vol. 58, no. 5, pp. 781–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan (2008), “Such a Beautiful Dream: How Russia Did Not Become a Market Economy,”Russian Review, vol. 67, no. 2, pp. 187–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hedlund, Stefan and Sundström, Niclas (1996), “Does Palermo Represent the Future for Moscow?”Journal of Public Policy, vol. 16, no. 2, pp. 113–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellie, Richard (1977), “The Structure of Modern Russian History: Toward a Dynamic Model,”Russian History, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 1–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellie, Richard (2005), “The Structure of Russian Imperial History,”History and Theory, Theme issue 44, December, pp. 88–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellman, Joel S. (1998), “Winners Take All: The Politics of Partial Reform in Postcommunist Transitions,”World Politics, vol. 50, no. 2, pp. 203–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helpman, Elhanan and Krugman, Paul (1985), Market Structure and Foreign Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Herman, Arthur (2001), The Scottish Enlightenment: How the Scots Invented the Modern World, London: Fourth Estate.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. (1977), The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before Its Triumph, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. (1982), “Rival Interpretations of Market Society: Civilizing, Destructive, or Feeble?,”Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 20, no. 4, pp. 1463–84.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. (1992), Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas (1968), Leviathan, Harmondsworth: Pelican. (Original published in 1651.)Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1999), Evolution and Institutions: On Evolutionary Economics and the Evolution of Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2001), How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2004), The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2006), “What Are Institutions?,”Journal of Economic Issues, vol. 40, no. 1, pp. 1–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, Paul (1981), Political Pilgrims: Travels of Western Intellectuals to the Soviet Union, China, and Cuba, 1928–1978, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hollander, Paul (1998), Political Pilgrims: Western Intellectuals in Search of the Good Society, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.Google Scholar
Hosking, Geoffrey (2001), Russia and the Russians: A History from Rus to the Russian Federation, Harmondsworth: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Hume, David (1969), A Treatise of Human Nature, edited with an introduction by Mossner, Ernest C., Harmondsworth: Penguin. (Original published in three volumes in 1739–40.)Google Scholar
Hunter, Holland and Szyrmer, Janusz M. (1992), Faulty Foundations: Soviet Economic Policies, 1928–1940, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. (1993), “The Clash of Civilizations,”Foreign Affairs, vol. 72, no. 3, pp. 22–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. (1996), The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order, New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Hutchison, Terence W. (1984), “Institutionalist Economics Old and New,”Journal of Institutional andTheoretical Economics, vol. 140, no. 1, pp. 20–29.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald (2000), “Culture and Democracy,” in Harrison, Lawrence E. and Huntington, Samuel P. (eds.), Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress, New York: Basic Books, pp. 80–97.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. Stanley (1866), “Brief Account of a General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy,”Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, vol. 29, June, pp. 282–87.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. Stanley (1871), Theory of Political Economy, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Johnson, Juliet Ellen (1994), “The Russian Banking System: Institutional Responses to the Market Transition,”Europe-Asia Studies, vol. 46, no. 6, pp. 971–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaiser, Daniel H. (ed. and transl.) (1992), The Laws of Rus – Tenth to Fifteenth Centuries, Salt Lake City, UT: Charles Schlacks Jr.Google Scholar
Katsenelinboigen, Aron (1977), “Colored Markets in the Soviet Union,”Soviet Studies, vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 62–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantorovich, Leonid (1968), The Best Use of Resources, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keegan, William (1993), The Specter of Capitalism: The Future of the World Economy after the Fall of Communism, London: Vintage.Google Scholar
Keenan, Edward (1986), “Muscovite Political Folkways,”Russian Review, vol. 45, no. 2, pp. 115–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennan, George F. [“X”] (1947), “The Sources of Soviet Conduct,”Foreign Affairs, vol. 25, no. 4, pp. 566–82.Google Scholar
Kennan, George F. (1971), The Marquis de Custine and His Russia in 1839, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Neville (1917), The Scope and Method of Political Economy, 4th ed., London: Macmillan. (First edition published in 1890.)Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P. (1978), Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P. (1990), Historical Economics: Art or Science?New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Kleimola, Ann M. (1972), “The Duty to Denounce in Muscovite Russia,”Slavic Review, vol. 31, no. 4, pp. 759–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kluchevsky, V. O. (1911), A History of Russia, Vol. 1, London: J. M. Dent & Sons.Google Scholar
Kluchevsky, V. O. (1912), A History of Russia, Vol. 2, London: J.M. Dent & Sons.Google Scholar
Kochan, Lionel and Abraham, Richard (1990), The Making of Modern Russia, Harmondsworth: Penguin.Google Scholar
Koopmans, Tjalling C. and Montias, Michael (1971), “On the Description and Comparison of Economic Systems,” in Eckstein, A. (ed.), Comparison of Economic Systems, Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 27–78.Google Scholar
Kornai, János (1992), The Socialist System: The Political Economy of Communism, Oxford: Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krippner, Greta R. (2001), “The Elusive Market: Embeddedness and the Paradigm of Economic Sociology,”Theory and Society, vol. 30, no. 6, pp. 775–810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul (1991a), “History and Industry Location: The Case of the Manufacturing Belt,”American Economic Review, vol. 81, no. 2, pp. 80–83.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul (1991b), “Increasing Returns and Economic Geography,”Journal of Political Economy, vol. 99, no. 3, pp. 483–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul (1994), “The Myth of Asia's Miracle,”Foreign Affairs, vol. 73, no. 6, pp. 62–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul (2003), The Great Unraveling: Losing Our Way in the New Century, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Kuczynski, MargueriteandMeek, Ronald L. (eds.) (1972), Quesnay's Tableau économique, London: Macmillan.CrossRef
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1962), The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert (1999), “The Quality of Government,”Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, vol. 15, no 1, pp. 222–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, David S. (1969), The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Landes, David S. (1990), “Why Are We So Rich and They So Poor?,”American Economic Review, vol. 80, no. 2, pp. 1–13.Google Scholar
Landes, David S. (1999), The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are so Rich and Some so Poor, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Lange, Oskar (1936), “On the Economic Theory of Socialism: Part One,”Review of Economic Studies, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 53–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, Oskar (1937), “On the Economic Theory of Socialism: Part Two,”Review of Economic Studies, vol. 4, no. 2, pp. 123–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layard, Richard and Parker, John (1996), The Coming Russian Boom: A Guide to New Markets and Politics, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Ledeneva, Alena V. (1998), Russia's Economy of Favors: Blat, Networking and Informal Exchange, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ledeneva, Alena V. (2006), How Russia Really Works: The Informal Practices that Shaped Post-Soviet Politics and Business, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, Axel (1973), “Life among the Econ,”Western Economic Journal, vol. 11, no. 3, pp. 327–37. (Reprinted in Joshua S. Gans (ed.) (2000), Publishing Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 3–13.)Google Scholar
Lenin, V.I. (1976), The State and Revolution, Peking: Foreign Languages Press.Google Scholar
Leonardi, Robert (1995), “Regional Development in Italy: Social Capital and the Mezzogiorno,”Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 2, no. 2, pp. 165–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Archibald R. (1951), Naval Power and Trade in the Mediterranean, A.D. 500–1100, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lie, John (1991), “Embedding Polanyi's Market Society,”Sociological Perspectives, vol. 34, no. 2, pp. 219–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1990), “The Fable of the Keys,”Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 33, no. 1, pp. 1–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1994), “Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy,”Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 8, no. 2, pp. 133–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995a), “Are Network Externalities a New Source of Market Failure?,”Research in Law and Economics, vol. 17, no. 0, pp. 1–22.Google Scholar
Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995b), “Path Dependence, Lock-in, and History,”Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, vol. 11, no. 1, pp. 205–26.Google Scholar
Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, Stephen E. (1995c), “Policy and Path Dependence: From QWERTY to Windows 95,”Regulation: The Cato Review of Business & Government, vol. 3. pp. 33–41.Google Scholar
Lippincott, Benjamin (ed.) (1938), On the Economic Theory of Socialism, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Locke, John (1821), Two Treatises on Government, London: R. Butler. (Original published in 1689.)Google Scholar
Locke, John (1975), An Essay concerning Human Understanding, Oxford: Clarendon Press. (Original published in 1690.)Google Scholar
Lotman, Yurii M. and Uspenskii, Boris A. (1984), “The Role of Dual Models in the Dynamics of Russian Culture (Up to the End of the Eighteenth Century),” in Shukman, A. (ed.), The Semiotics of Russian Culture, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, pp. 3–35.Google Scholar
Loury, Glenn C. (1977), “A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Differences,” in Wallace, Phyllis A. and Mond, Annette M. (eds.), Women, Minorities and Employment Discrimination, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, pp. 153–86.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. (1993), “Making a Miracle,”Econometrica, vol. 61, no. 2, pp. 251–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macfie, A. L. (1967), The Individual in Society: Papers on Adam Smith, London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus (1995), Monitoring the World Economy 1820–1992, Paris: OECD Development Centre.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus (2001), The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective, Paris: OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, James (2000), “Path Dependence in Historical Sociology,”Theory and Society, vol. 29, no. 4, pp. 507–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malia, Martin (1999), Russia under Western Eyes: From the Bronze Horseman to the Lenin Mausoleum, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Malthus, Thomas (1798), An Essay on the Principle of Population, as It Affects the Future Improvement of Society, London: J. Johnson.Google Scholar
Mandeville, Bernard (1988), The Fable of the Bees: or, Private Vices, Publick Benefits, Indianapolis: Liberty Classics. (The original was published in a first edition 1714 and in an expanded edition in 1723.)Google Scholar
March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P. (1984), “The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life,”American Political Science Review, vol. 78, no. 3, pp. 734–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P. (1989), Rediscovering Institutions: The Organizational Basis of Politics, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P. (2008), “Elaborating the ‘New Institutionalism,’” in Rhodes, R. A. W., Binder, Sarah A., and Rockman, Bert A. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 3–20.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred (1885), The Present Condition of Economics, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred (1890), Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, Gordon (1982), In Search of the Spirit of Capitalism: An Essay on Max Weber's Protestant Ethics Thesis, London: Hutchison.Google Scholar
Martin, David (1990), Tongues of Fire: The Explosion of Protestantism in Latin America, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Matthews, R. C. O. (1986), “The Economics of Institutions and the Sources of Growth,”Economic Journal, vol. 96, no. 384, pp. 903–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDaniel, Tim (1996), The Agony of the Russian Idea, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
McMillan, John (2002), Reinventing the Bazaar: A Natural History of Markets, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
McNeill, William H. (1963), The Rise of the West: A History of the Human Community, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ménard, Claude (ed.) (2000), Institutions, Contracts and Organizations: Perspectives from New Institutional Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef
Ménard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M. (eds.) (2005), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRef
Menger, Carl (1871), Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre, Wien: W. Braumüller.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl (1883), Untersuchungen über die Methode der Socialwissenschaften: und der politischen Ökonomieinsbesondere, Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl (1884), Die Irrthümer des Historismus in der deutschen Nationalökonomie, Wien: A. Hölder.Google Scholar
Mielants, Eric H. (2007), The Origins of Capitalism and the “Rise of the West,”Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press.Google Scholar
Milford, Karl (1995), “Roscher's Epistemological and Methodological Position: Its Importance for the Methodenstreit,”Journal of Economic Studies, vol. 22, nos. 3/4/5, pp. 26–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul R., North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R. (1990), “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,”Economics and Politics, vol. 2, no. 1, pp. 1–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, John Stuart (1844), Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy, London: J. W. Parker.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart (1865), Auguste Comte and Positivism, London: Trübner.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig (1920), “Die Wirtschaftsrechnung im sozialistischen Gemeinwesen,”Archiv für Sozialwissenschaften, vol. 47, pp. 86–121.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley (1935), “Commons on Institutional Economics,”American Economic Review, vol. 25, no. 4, pp. 635–52.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel (1990), The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Montchrestien, Antoine (1999), Traicté de l'oeconomie politique, Genève: Droz.Google Scholar
Montesquieu, Charles de Secondat, Baron (2002), The Spirit of Laws, Amherst, NY: Prometheus Books. (Original published in 1748.)Google Scholar
Montesquieu, Charles de Secondat, Baron (1900), The Spirit of Laws, London: Colonial Press. (Original published in 1748.)Google Scholar
Moore, Henry L. (1914), Economic Cycles: Their Law and Cause, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Nash, E. Gee (1929), The Hansa: Its History and Romance, New York: Dodd, Mead.Google Scholar
,NBER (1960), Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries: A Conference of the Universities-National Bureau Committee for Economic Research, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor (2001), “Sources of the New Institutionalism,” in Brinton, Mary C. and Nee, Victor (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Sociology, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 1–16.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor and Ingram, Paul (2001), “Embeddedness and Beyond: Institutions, Exchange, and Social Structure,” in Brinton, Mary C. and Nee, Victor (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Sociology, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 19–45.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1974), “Beyond the New Economic History,”Journal of Economic History, vol. 34, no. 1, pp. 1–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1977), “Markets and Other Allocation Systems in History: The Challenge of Karl Polanyi,”Journal of Economic History, vol. 6, winter, pp. 703–16.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1986), “The New Institutional Economics,”Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol. 142, no. 1, pp. 230–37.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1988), “Ideology and Political/Economic Institutions,”Cato Journal, vol. 8, no. 1, pp. 15–28.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1990a), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1990b), “A Transaction Cost Theory of Politics,”Journal of Theoretical Politics, vol. 2, no. 4, pp. 355–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1991), “Institutions,”Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 97–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1993a), “Institutions and Credible Commitment,”Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics,” vol. 149, no. 1, pp. 11–23.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1993b), “Toward a Theory of Institutional Change,” in Barnett, W. A., Hinich, M. J., and Scofield, N. J. (eds.), Political Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 61–69.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1994), “Economic Performance through Time,”American Economic Review, vol. 84, no. 3, pp. 359–68.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (2005), Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. and Denzau, Arthur T. (1994), “Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions,”Kyklos, vol. 47, no. 3, pp. 3–30.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. and Thomas, Robert Paul (1973), The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R. (1989), “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England,”Journal of Economic History, vol. 49, December, pp. 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nove, Alec (1977), The Soviet Economic System, Boston: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Nove, Alec (1982), An Economic History of the USSR, Harmondsworth: Pelican.Google Scholar
Nove, Alec (1983), The Economics of Feasible Socialism, London: George Allen & Unwin.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,OECD (2006), Economic Survey of the Russian Federation 2006, Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1995), “Why the Transition from Communism Is so Difficult,”Eastern Economic Journal, vol. 21, no. 4, pp. 437–61.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1996), “Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations Are Rich and Others Poor,”Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 10, no. 2, pp. 3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1997), “The New Institutional Economics: The Collective Choice Approach to Economic Development,” in Clague, Christopher (ed.), Growth and Governance in Less-Developed and Post-Socialist Countries, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 37–64.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (2000), Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Vincent (2004), “Great Experiments and the Welfare State: Basic Paradigmatic Changes,” in Sankhder, M. M. and Jain, Sahrda (eds.), Social Security, Welfare and Polity, New Delhi: Deep & Deep, pp. 46–83.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1896), Cours d'économie politique professé à l'Université de Lausanne, Lausanne: F. Rouge.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1916), Trattato di sociologia generale, Firenze: G. Barbèra.Google Scholar
Parsons, Talcott (1937), The Structure of Social Action: A Study in Social Theory with Special Reference to a Group of Recent European Writers, New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Parsons, Talcott and Smelser, Neil J. (1956), Economy and Society: A Study in the Integration of Economic and Social Theory, Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Peters, B. Guy (1999), Institutional Theory in Political Science: The “New Institutionalism,”London: Pinter.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul (2000), “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics,”American Political Science Review, vol. 94, no. 2, pp. 251–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul (2004), Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul and Skocpol, Theda (2002), “Historical Institutionalism in Contemporary Political Science,” in Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V. (eds.), Political Science: The State of the Discipline, New York: Norton, pp. 693–721.Google Scholar
Pipes, Richard (1974), Russia under the Old Regime, New York: Charles Scribner's Sons.Google Scholar
Pipes, Richard (1996), “Russia's Past, Russia's Future,”Commentary, June, pp. 30–38.Google Scholar
Pipes, Richard (1999), Property and Freedom, New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Pipes, Richard (2004), “Flight from Freedom: What Russians Think and Want,”Foreign Affairs, vol. 83, no. 3, pp. 9–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirenne, Henri (1969), Medieval Cities: Their Origins and the Revival of Trade, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. (Original published in 1929.)Google Scholar
Platteau, Jean-Philippe (1994), “Behind the Market Stage Where Real Societies Exist – Part II: The Role of Moral Norms,”Journal of Development Studies, vol. 30, no. 3, pp. 753–817.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poe, Marshall T. (2000), “A People Born to Slavery.” Russia in Early Modern European Ethnography, 1476–1748, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Poe, Marshall T. (2001), “Moscow the Third Rome: The Origins and Transformation of a ‘Pivotal Moment,’”Jahrbücher für Geschichte Osteuropas, vol. 49, no. 3, pp. 412–29.Google Scholar
Poe, Marshall T. (2003), The Russian Moment in World History, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl (1944), The Great Transformation, New York: Farrar & Rhinehart.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl (1947), “Our Obsolete Market Mentality,” Commentary, vol. 3, February, pp. 109–17. Reprinted in Dalton, George (ed.) (1968), Primitive, Archaic, and Modern Economies: Essays of Karl Polanyi, New York: Anchor Books, pp. 59–77.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl (1957), “The Economy as an Instituted Process,” in Polanyi, Karl, Arensberg, Conrad M., and Pearson, Harry W. (eds.), Trade and Markets in Early Empires: Economies in History and Theory, Glencoe, IL: Free Press, pp. 243–70.Google Scholar
Powell, Walter W.andDiMaggio, Paul J. (eds.) (1991), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Przeworski, Adam (1991), Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Puffert, Douglas J. (2003), “Path Dependence, Network Form, and Technological Change,” in Sundstrom, W., Guinnane, T., and Whatley, W. (eds.), History Matters: Essays on Economic Growth, Technology, and Demographic Change, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 63–95.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert (1993), Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Quesnay, Francois (1980), Tableau Économique, Tokyo: Bibliothèque de la Faculté des sciences économiques, Université Nihon. (Original published in 1759.)Google Scholar
Raeff, Marc (1976), “Imperial Russia: Peter I to Nicholas I,” in Auty, Robert and Obolensky, Dimitri (eds.), An Introduction to Russian History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 121–95.Google Scholar
Raphael, D. D. (1975), “The Impartial Spectator,” in Skinner, Andrew S. and Wilson, Thomas (eds.), Essays on Adam Smith, Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 83–99.Google Scholar
Reiss, H.S. (ed.) (1991), Kant: Political Writings, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ricardo, David (1817), On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel (1952), The Theory of Economic Policy in English Classical Political Economy, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Roland, Gérard (2000), Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Romer, Paul M. (1986), “Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,”Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, no. 5, pp. 1002–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roscher, Wilhelm G. F. (1843), Grundriss zu Vorlesungen über die Staatswirtschaft: nach geschichtlicher Methode, Göttingen: Dieterich.Google Scholar
Rose, Richard (1999), “Living in an Anti-Modern Society,”East European Constitutional Review, vol. 8, nos. 1–2, pp. 68–75.Google Scholar
Rose, Richard and McAllister, Ian (1996), “Is Money the Measure of Welfare in Russia?,”Review of Income and Wealth, vol. 42, no. 1, pp. 75–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosefielde, Steven (1998), Efficiency and Russia's Economic Recovery Potential to the Year 2000 and Beyond, Aldershot: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Rosefielde, Steven (2002), Comparative Economic Systems: Culture, Wealth, and Power in the 21st Century, Malden, MA: Blackwell.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosefielde, Steven (2009), Red Holocaust, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan (1964), “Neglected Dimensions in the Analysis of Economic Change,”Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, vol. 26, no. 1, pp. 59–77.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan and Birdzell, Jr. L. E. (1986), How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Rothschild, Emma (1994), “Adam Smith and the Invisible Hand,”American Economic Review, vol. 84, no. 2, pp. 319–22.Google Scholar
Rothschild, Emma (2001), Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques (1911), Émile, ou de l'éducation, Paris: E. Flammarion. (Original published in 1762.)Google Scholar
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques (1993), The Social Contract and the Discourses, New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul (1947), Foundations of Economic Analysis, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sanders, Elizabeth (2008), “Historical Institutionalism,” in Rhodes, R. A. W., Binder, Sarah A., and Rockman, Bert A. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 39–55.Google Scholar
Sait, Edward (1938), Political Institutions – A Preface, Boston: Appleton-Century-Crofts.Google Scholar
Schmoller, Gustav (1883), “Zur Methodologie der Staats- und Sozial-Wissenschaften,”Schmoller's Jahrbuch, vol. 7, no. 3, pp. 975–94.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1908), Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie, Leipzig, Duncker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1950), “The March into Socialism,”American Economic Review, vol. 40, no. 2, May, pp. 446–56.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1951), “Vilfredo Pareto, 1848–1923,” in Schumpeter, Ten Great Economists: From Marx to Keynes, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 110–42.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954), History of Economic Analysis, London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Schwoerer, Lois G. (1981), The Declaration of Rights, 1689, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Scruton, Roger (2002), The West and the Rest: Globalization and the Terrorist Threat, Wilmington, DE: ISI Books.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (2009), “Capitalism beyond the Crisis,”New York Review of Books, vol. 56, no. 5, p. 3, www.nybooks.com/articles/22490, accessed on May 14, 2009.Google Scholar
Senik-Leygonie, Claudia and Hughes, Gordon (1992), “Industrial Profitability and Trade among the Former Soviet Republics,”Economic Policy, vol. 7, no. 2, pp. 354–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. (1989), “Studying Institutions: Some Lessons from the Rational Choice Approach,”Journal of Theoretical Politics, vol. 1, no. 2, pp. 131–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. (1991), “Discretion, Institutions and the Problem of Government Commitment,” in Bourdieu, Pierre and Coleman, James (eds.), Social Theory for a Changing Society, Boulder, CO: Western Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. (2008), “Rational Choice Institutionalism,” in Rhodes, R. A. W., Binder, Sarah A., and Rockman, Bert A. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 23–38.Google Scholar
Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert (1998), The Grabbing Hand: Government Pathologies and Their Cures, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Simmel, Georg (1955), Conflict and the Web of Group Affiliations, Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1957), Models of Man, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1991), “Organizations and Markets,”Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 5, pp. 25–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skocpol, Theda (1979), States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia and China, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Small, Albion W. (1907), Adam Smith and Modern Sociology: A Study in the Methodology of the Social Sciences, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Smelser, Neil J. and Swedberg, Richard (1994), “The Sociological Perspective on the Economy,” in Smelser, and Swedberg, (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 3–26.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1976), The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Indianapolis: Liberty Classics. (The original was published in a first edition 1759 and in a sixth and last edition in 1790, only weeks before the author's death.)Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (2000), The Wealth of Nations, New York: Modern Library. (The original was published in 1776, under the somewhat more elaborate title An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.)Google Scholar
Snooks, Graeme D. (ed.) (1993a), Historical Analysis in Economics, London: Routledge.
Snooks, Graeme D. (1993b), “The Lost Dimension: Limitations of a Timeless Economics,” in Snooks, (ed.), Historical Analysis in Economics, London: Routledge, pp. 41–66.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert (1985), “Economic History and Economics,”American Economic Review, vol. 75, no. 2, pp. 328–31.Google Scholar
Soto, Hernando (2000), The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Steffens, Lincoln (1931), The Autobiography of Lincoln Steffens, New York: Literary Guild.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1999), “Whither Reform? Ten Years of the Transition,” http:// siteresources.worldbank.org/INTABCDEWASHINGTON1999/Resources/stiglitz.pdf, accessed on October 1, 2009.
Sutela, Pekka (1984), Socialism, Planning and Optimality: A Study in Soviet Economic Thought, Helsinki: Finnish Society of Sciences and Letters.Google Scholar
Swedberg, Richard (1987), “Economic Sociology: Past and Present,”Current Sociology, vol. 35, no. 1, pp. 1–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swedberg, Richard (1990), Economics and Sociology: Redefining Their Boundaries: Conversations with Economists and Sociologists, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Swedberg, Richard (1997), “New Economic Sociology: What Has Been Accomplished, What Is Ahead?,”Acta Sociologica, vol. 40, pp. 161–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szamuely, László (1974), First Models of the Socialist Economic Systems: Principles and Theories, Budapest: Akademiai Kiadó.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen and Steinmo, Sven (1992), “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics,” in Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen, and Longstreth, Frank (1992), Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–32.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen (1999), “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics,”Annual Review of Political Science, vol. 2, no. 1, pp. 369–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, William (1963), An Inquiry into the Principles of the Distribution of Wealth, Most Conducive to Human Happiness, New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, Jan (1961), “Do Communist and Free Economies Show a Converging Pattern?,”Soviet Studies, vol. 12, no. 4, pp. 333–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tiner, John H. (1975), Isaac Newton: The True Story of His Life as Inventor, Scientist and Teacher, Milford, MI: Mott Media.Google Scholar
Tocqueville, Alexis (1945), Democracy in America, New York: Alfred A. Knopf. (The French original was published in two volumes, in 1835 and 1840, under the title De la Démocracie en Amérique.)Google Scholar
Vallance, Edward (2006), The Glorious Revolution, 1688: Britain's Fight for Liberty, London: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Vasiliev, Sergei A. (1997), “Economic Reform in Russia: Social, Political and Institutional Aspects,” in Aslund, Anders (ed.), Russia's Economic Transformation in the 1990s, London: Pinter, pp. 25–37.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein (1898), “Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 12, no. 4, pp. 373–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study in the Evolution of Institutions, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein (1917), An Inquiry into the Nature of Peace and the Terms of its Perpetuation, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Volin, Lazar (1970), A Century of Russian Agriculture: From Alexander II to Khrushchev, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voltaire, (2000), Treatise on Tolerance, New York: Cambridge University Press. (Translated by Brian Masters; translated and edited by Simon Harvey. Original published in 1763.)Google Scholar
Voslensky, Michael (1984), Nomenklatura: The Soviet Ruling Class, Garden City, NY: Doubleday.Google Scholar
Waller, William T. Jr. (1982), “The Evolution of the Veblenian Dichotomy: Veblen, Hamilton, Ayres, and Foster,”Journal of Economic Issues, vol. 16, no. 3, pp. 757–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallis, John J. and North, Douglass C. (1986), “Measuring the Transaction Sector in the American Economy,” in Engerman, Stanley and Gallman, Robert E. (eds.), Long-Term Factors in American Growth, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 95–161.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon (1874), Éléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale, Lausanne: Imprimerie L. Corbaz & Cie.Google Scholar
Webb, Sidney and Beatrice, (1935), Soviet Communism: A New Civilisation?, London: Longmans, Green.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1904/05), “Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus,”Archiv für Sozialwissenschaften und Sozialpolitik, vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 1–54, vol. 21, no. 1, pp. 1–110.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1922), Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr (P. Siebeck).Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1946a), “The Social Psychology of the World Religions,” in Gerth, H. H. and Mills, C. Wright (trans. and eds.), From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 267–301.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1946b), “The Protestant Sects and the Spirit of Capitalism,” in Gerth, H. H. and Mills, C. Wright (trans. and eds.), From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 302–22.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1961), General Economic History, New York: Collier Books.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (2001), The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit ofCapitalism, London: Routledge. (Original published in 1904/05.)Google Scholar
Wedel, Janine R. (1998), Collision and Collusion: The Strange Case of Western Aid to Eastern Europe 1989–98, New York: St. Martin's.Google Scholar
Wedel, Janine R. (2000), “Tainted Transactions: Harvard, the Chubais Clan and Russia's Ruin,”The National Interest, no. 59, spring, pp. 23–34.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. (1993), “Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secure Markets,”Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol. 149, no. 1, pp. 286–311.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry (1996), “Political Institutions: Rational Choice Perspectives,” in Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 167–90.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry (2002), “Rational Choice Institutionalism,” in Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V. (eds.), Political Science: The State of the Discipline, New York: Norton, pp. 660–92.Google Scholar
Weitzman, Martin (1974), “Prices versus Quantities,”Review of Economic Studies, vol. 41, no. 4, pp. 477–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Harrison (1981), “Where Do Markets Come From?,”American Journal of Sociology, vol. 87, no. 3, pp. 517–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, John (ed.) (1990), Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened?Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
Williamson, John (1993), “Democracy and the ‘Washington Consensus,’”World Development, vol. 21, no. 8, pp. 1329–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985a), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985b), “Reflections on the New Institutional Economics,”Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol. 141, no. 1, pp. 187–95.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1994), “Transaction Cost Economics and Organization Theory,” in Smelser, and Swedberg, (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 77–107.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1995), “The Institutions and Governance of Economic Development,” Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994, Washington, DC: World Bank, pp. 171–97.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1996), The Mechanisms of Governance, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1998), “Transaction Cost Economics: How It Works; Where It Is Headed,”De Economist, vol. 146, no. 1, pp. 23–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (2000), “The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead,”Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 38, no. 3, pp. 595–613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winter, Ella (1933), Red Virtue: Human Relationships in the New Russia, New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Yakovlev, Alexander M. (1995), “The Rule-of-Law Ideal and Russian Reality,” in Frankowski, Stanislaw and Stephan, Paul B. III (eds.), Legal Reform in Post-Communist Europe: The View from Within, Dordrecht: Martinus Nijhoff, pp. 5–19.Google Scholar
Yanov, Alexander (1981), The Origins of Autocracy: Ivan the Terrible in Russian History, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Yanov, Alexander (1984), The Drama of the Soviet 1960s: A Lost Reform, Berkeley: CA: Institute of International Studies.Google Scholar
Yonay, Yuval P. (1998), The Struggle over the Soul of Economics: Institutionalist and Neoclassical Economists in America between the Wars, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zinoviev, Alexander (1979), The Yawning Heights, New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Zukin, Sharon and DiMaggio, Paul (1990), “Introduction,” in Zukin, and DiMaggio, (eds.), Structures of Capital: The Social Organization of the Economy, New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–36.Google Scholar
Zweynert, Joachim (2009), “Interests versus Culture in the Theory of Institutional Change,”Journal of Institutional Economics, vol. 5, no. 3, pp. 339–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Stefan Hedlund, Uppsala Universitet, Sweden
  • Book: Invisible Hands, Russian Experience, and Social Science
  • Online publication: 01 June 2011
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139003612.012
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Stefan Hedlund, Uppsala Universitet, Sweden
  • Book: Invisible Hands, Russian Experience, and Social Science
  • Online publication: 01 June 2011
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139003612.012
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Stefan Hedlund, Uppsala Universitet, Sweden
  • Book: Invisible Hands, Russian Experience, and Social Science
  • Online publication: 01 June 2011
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139003612.012
Available formats
×