Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-xm8r8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-26T16:47:24.224Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2014

Arie Arnon
Affiliation:
Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Monetary Theory and Policy from Hume and Smith to Wicksell
Money, Credit, and the Economy
, pp. 401 - 418
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Attwood, T. (various years), Selected Economic Writings of Thomas Attwood, edited with an Introduction Fetter, F. W., London: LSE Series of Reprints # 18.
Bagehot, W. (1873), Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market, London: Kegan Paul, Trench, Trubner & Co. [1896].Google Scholar
Bagehot, W (1978), The Collected Works of Walter Bagehot, The Economic Essays (vols. 9–11), St John-Stevas, N. (ed.), London: The Economist.Google Scholar
[Bailey, S.] (1840), A Defense of Joint Stock Banks and Country Issues, London: James Ridgway.Google Scholar
Baring, F. (1797a), Observations on the Establishment of the Bank of England and on Paper Circulation of the Country, London: Minerva Press [1993].Google Scholar
Baring, F (1797b), Further Observations on the Establishment of the Bank of England and on Paper Circulation of the Country, London: Minerva Press [1993].Google Scholar
Baring, F (1801a), Observations on the Publication of Walter Boyd, London: Minerba Press.Google Scholar
Baring, F (1801b?), A Twelve-Penny Answer to a Three Shillings and Six-Penny Pamphlet, Intitled “A Letter on the Influence of the Stoppage of the Issue in Specie at the Bank of England, on the Prices of Provisions and other Commodities,”London: J. Stockdale.Google Scholar
Baring, F (1801c?), A Second Twelve-Penny Answer to a New (and Five Shillings) Edition of Three Shillings and Six-Penny Pamphlet, Intitled “A Letter on the Influence of the Stoppage of the Issue in Specie at the Bank of England, on the Prices of Provisions and other Commodities; with additional Notes and a Preface,”London: I. Walter and Son.Google Scholar
Boase, H. (1804), A Letter to the Right Hon. Lord King, in Defence of the conduct of the Directors of the Banks of England and Ireland, London: Bulmer.Google Scholar
Bosanquet, C. (1810), Practical Observations on the Report of the Bullion-Committee, 2nd edition, corrected with a supplement, London: Richardson.Google Scholar
Boyd, W. (1801a), A Letter to the Right Honourable William Pitt on the Influence of the Stoppage of Issues in Specie at the Bank of England on the Prices of Provisions and Other Commodities, London: Wright.Google Scholar
Boyd, W (1801b), A Letter to the Right Honourable William Pitt on the Influence of the Stoppage of Issues in Specie at the Bank of England on the Prices of Provisions and Other Commodities, (2nd edition, with additional Notes and a Preface containing remarks on the publication of Sir Francis Baring), London: Wright and Mawman.Google Scholar
Checkland, S. G. (1948), “The Birmingham Economists, 1815–1850”, The Economic History Review, (New Series), Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horner, F. (1957), The Economic Writings of Francis Horner in the Edinburgh Review 1802–1806, Edited and with an Introduction by F.W. Fetter, New York: Kelley & Millman.Google Scholar
Horner, F (1994), The Horner Papers: Selection from the Letters and Miscellaneous Writings of Francis Horner, M.P. 1795–1817, Edited by Bourne, K. and Taylor, W. B., Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. (1752), Political Discourses in Rotwein, E. (1955), David Hume Writings on Economics, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Huskisson, W. (1810), The Question Concerning the Depreciation of Our Currency Stated and Examined, third edition-corrected, London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Fullarton, J. (1844), On the Regulation of Currencies, London: John Murray, (2nd edition 1845).Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. (1875), Money and the Mechanism of Exchange, London: Kegan Paul [1899].Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S (1884), Investigations in Currency and Finance, Foxwell, H. S. (ed.), New York: A. M. Kelley [1964].Google Scholar
Joplin, T. (1823a), An Essay on the General Principles and Present Practice of Banking in England and Scotland, London: Baldwin, Cradock and Joy, reprinted together with Outline of a System of Political Economy (1823b), New York: Kelley 1970.Google Scholar
Joplin, T (1823b), Outline of a System of Political Economy, London: Baldwin, Cradock and Joy, reprinted New York: Kelley 1970.Google Scholar
Joplin, T (1832), An Analysis and History of the Currency Question, London: Ridgway.Google Scholar
Joplin, T (1840), On Our Monetary System &c. &c., with an explanation of the Causes by which the Pressures on the Money Market are Produced, and a Plan for their Remedy, which can be carried into immediate effect, without any derangement, and with the approbation of the banks, both private and public, by which the currency is issued, second edition, London: Ridgway.Google Scholar
Joplin, T (1844), An Examination of Sir Robert Peel’s Currency Bill of 1844, in a Letter to the Bankers of the United Kingdom, London: Richardson.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1923), A Tract on Monetary Reform, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M (1925), “Alfred Marshall, 1842–1924,” in Memorials of Alfred Marshall, Pigou, A.C. (ed.), pp. 1–65, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M (1930), A Treatise on Money, (two volumes) London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
King, P. [Lord] (1803), Thoughts on the Effects of the Bank Restrictions, (2nd edition, 1804), London: Taylor.Google Scholar
Loyd, S. J. [Lord Overstone] (1857), Tracts and other Publications on Metallic and Paper Currency, London: Harrison.Google Scholar
Loyd, S. J [Lord Overtone] and R. Torrens (1847), The Petition of the Merchants, Bankers and Traders of London Against the Charter Act; With Comments on Each Clause, in Loyd, S. J. (1857), Tracts and other Publications on Metallic and Paper Currency, London: Harrison.Google Scholar
Loyd, S. J [Lord Overstone] (1971), The Correspondence of Lord Overstone, (Three Volumes), Edited and Introduction by O’Brien, D. P., Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Loyd, S.J. (1832) Evidence in the 1832 Parliamentary Committee.
Malthus, T.R. (1811), “Review of the Controversy Respecting the High Price of Bullion”, Edinburgh Review, 18 pp. 448–470.Google Scholar
Malthus, T.R (1823), “[A Review of] Thoughts and Details on the High and Low Prices of the Last Thirty Years” [by Thomas Tooke], Quarterly Review, 29, pp. 214–239.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1867), “Money,” in The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall, Whitaker, J. (ed.), vol. 2 pp. 277–278, London: Macmillan (for the Royal Economic Society).Google Scholar
Marshall, A (1871?), “Essay on Money,” in The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall, Whitaker, J. (ed.), vol. 1 pp. 164–177, London: Macmillan (for the Royal Economic Society).Google Scholar
Marshall, A (1886), “Answers to Questions on the Subject of Currency and Prices Circulated by the Royal Commission on the Depression of Trade and Industry,” in Official Papers by Alfred Marshall, Keynes, J. M. (ed.), pp. 1–16, London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society [1926].Google Scholar
Marshall, A (1887a), “Remedies for Fluctuations of General Prices”, Contemporary Review (March), Reprinted in Memorials of Alfred Marshall, Pigou, A.C. (ed.), pp. 188–211, London: Macmillan [1925].Google Scholar
Marshall, A (1887b), “Memoranda and Evidence before the Gold and Silver Commission”, in Official Papers by Alfred Marshall, Keynes, J. M. (ed.), pp. 17–195, London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society [1926].Google Scholar
Marshall, A (1890), Principles of Economics, Eighth Edition, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A (1923), Money, Credit and Commerce, New York: A. M. Kelley [1965].Google Scholar
Marshall, AMarshall, A.. and Marshall, M. P. (1879), Economics of Industry, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marx, K. (1847), The Poverty of Philosophy, New York: International Publishers [1963].Google Scholar
Marx, K (1857), Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy (Rough Draft), Translated and Foreword by Nicolaus, M., Middlesex: Penguin edition [1973].Google Scholar
Marx, K (1859), A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, with an introduction by Dobb, M., Moscow: Progress Publishers [1970].Google Scholar
Marx, K (1867), Capital, Volume I, Chicago: C. H. Kerr [1907].Google Scholar
Marx, K (1885), Capital, Volume II, Chicago: C. H. Kerr [1907].Google Scholar
Marx, K (1894), Capital, Volume III, Chicago: C. H. Kerr [1909].Google Scholar
Marx, KMarx, K. and Engels, F.. (1934), Correspondence 1846–1895: A Selection, New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
Marx, K (1963), Marx-Engels Werke (M.E.W.), Vols. 27–29. Berlin: Dietz Verlag.Google Scholar
[McCulloch, J. R.] (1831), Historical Sketch of the Bank of England, London: Longmans.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1826), “Paper Currency and Commercial Distress”, in The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Robson, J. M. (ed.), vol. IV pp. 71–124, Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1844a), Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy, in The Collected Works of John StuartMill, J. M. Robson (ed.), vol. IV pp. 289–340, Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1844b), “The Currency Question” [Review of Tooke’s and Torrens’ Inquiries of 1844], The Westminster Review, Vol. 41 pp. 579–598; also in The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Robson, J. M. (ed.), vol. IV pp. 341–362, Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1848), Principles of Political Economy, seventh edition [1871], in The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Robson, J. M. (ed.), vol. II & III, Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mushet, R. (1811), An Inquiry into the Effects Produced on the National Currency and Rates of Exchange by the Bank Restriction Bill; Explaining the Cause of the High Price of Bullion; With Plans for Maintaining the National Coins in a State of Uniformity and Perfection, Third Edition, London: Robert Baldwin.Google Scholar
Norman, G. W. (1833), Remarks upon Some Prevalent Errors with Respect to Currency and Banking and Suggestions to the Legislature as to the Renewal of the Bank Charter, London: R. Hunter.Google Scholar
Norman, G. W (1838), Remarks upon Some Prevalent Errors with Respect to Currency and Banking and Suggestions to the Legislature and the Public as to the Improvements of the Monetary System, London: Pelham Richardson.Google Scholar
Palmer, J. H. (1837), The Causes and Consequences of the Pressure upon the Money-Market, London: Pelham Richardson.Google Scholar
Parliamentary Papers. (1793), Report from the Select Committee appointed to take into Consideration the Present State of Commercial Credit [Reprinted in P.P. 1826].
Parliamentary Papers (1797), Report from the Committee of Secrecy On the Outstanding Demands of the Bank of England, in British Parliamentary Papers, The Bank of England and Commercial Credit, Monetary Policy, General I, Irish University Press.Google Scholar
Parliamentary Papers (1804), Report from the Select Committee on the Circulating Paper, the Specie and Current Coin of Ireland [see also Fetter (1955)].
Parliamentary Papers (1810), Report from the Select Committee on the High Price of Bullion, [see also Cannan (1919)].
Parliamentary Papers (1819a), Report from the Secret Committee on the Expediency of the Bank Resuming Cash Payments, P.P. 1819, (202, 282), III.
Parliamentary Papers (1819b), Lords Committees Appointed a Secret Committee to enquire into the State of the Bank of England, with respect to the Expediency of the Resumption of Cash Payments, P.P. 1819 (291) III.
Parliamentary Papers (1832), Report from the Committee of Secrecy on the Expediency of renewing the Charter of the Bank of England, and on the system on which Banks of Issue in England and Wales are conducted, P.P. 1831–1832, (722) VI.
Parliamentary Papers (1836–1837), Report from the Select Committee on Joint Stock Banks, P. P. 1836 (591) IX and 1837 (531) XIV.
Parliamentary Papers (1840), Report from the Select Committee on Banks of Issue, P. P. 1840 (602) IV and 1841 (366) V.
Parliamentary Papers (1847–1848), Report from the Secret Committee on Commercial Distress, First and Second reports, P.P. 1848 (395, 584).
Parliamentary Papers (1848), Report from the Secret Committee of the House of Lords appointed to inquire into the causes of the distress which has for some time prevailed among the commercial classes and how far it has been affected by the laws for regulating the issue of banks notes payable on demand together with the Minutes of Evidence, P.P. 1848, (565) VIII, pt. iii.
Parliamentary Papers (1857–1858), Report from the Select Committee on Bank Acts, P. P. 1857 (220) X, and 1857–1858 (381) V.
Parnell, H. (1804), Observations upon the State of Currency in Ireland and upon the Course of Exchange between Dublin and London, third edition, Dublin: Mahon.Google Scholar
Parnell, H (1827), Observations on Paper Money, Banking and Overtrading, London: James Ridgeway.Google Scholar
Parnell, H (1832), A Plain Statement of the Power of the Bank of England, London: James Ridgeway.Google Scholar
Pennington, J. (1827), Memorandum [to Huskisson], Goldsmiths’ Library, University of London, Goldsmiths’-Kress Number 25312 Microfilm Numbers 2421.
Pennington, J (1829), Paper Communicated by Mr. Pennington [to T. Tooke] Appendix in Tooke, T., A Letter to Lord Grenville on the Effects Ascribed to the Resumption of Cash Payments on the Value of the Currency, London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D. (1951–1973), Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, edited by Sraffa, P., 11 volumes, Cambridge: The University Press.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D (1932), Minor Papers on the Currency Question, 1809–1823, Edited with an Introduction and Notes by Hollander, Jacob H., Baltimore: John Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Senior, W. N. (1829), Three Lectures on the Value of Money, London: B. Fellowes [1840].Google Scholar
Simon, H. C. (1936), “Rules versus Authorities in Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 44, pp. 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. (1776), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, edited by Cannan, E., Chicago: The University Press [1994].CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A (1762–1766), Lectures on Jurisprudence, the Glasgow Edition of the works and Correspondence of Smith, Adam, Vol. 5, Oxford University Press [1978].Google Scholar
Smith, M. (2001),“Endogenous Money, Interest and Prices: Tooke’s Monetary Theory Revisited”, Contributions to Political Economy, 20, pp. 31–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thornton, H (2003), “On Central Banking “Rules”: Tooke’s Critique of the Bank Charter Act of 1844, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 25, pp. 39–61.Google Scholar
Thornton, H. (1797), Evidence before the 1797 Parliamentary Committee, in Thornton, (1802\1939), New Jersey: A. M. Kelley [1978].Google Scholar
Thornton, H (1802), An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain, (with an introduction by Hayek, F.A. von, 1939), New Jersey: A. M. Kelley [1978].Google Scholar
Thornton, H (1804), Notes on King in Thornton, (1802\1939), New Jersey: A. M. Kelley [1978].Google Scholar
Thornton, H (1811), Speeches 1811 in Thornton, (1802\1939), New Jersey: A. M. Kelley [1978].Google Scholar
Tooke, T. (1823), Thoughts and Details on the High and Low Prices of the Last Thirty Years (2 vols), London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1824), Thoughts and Details on the High and Low Prices of the Last Thirty Years, (2nd edition, in one volume), London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1826), Considerations on the State of the Currency, (2nd edition), London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1829a), A Letter to Lord Grenville on the Effects Ascribed to the Resumption of Cash Payments on the Value of the Currency, London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1829b), On the Currency in Connection with the Corn Trade and on the Corn Laws, to which is added a Postscript on the Present Commercial Stagnation, (second letter to Lord Grenville), London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1838), A History of Prices and of the State of the Circulation from 1793 to 1837, (Volumes I and II), London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1840), A History of Prices and of the State of the Circulation from 1838, 1839, (Vol. III), London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1844), An Inquiry into the Currency Principle: The Connection of the Currency with Prices and the Expediency of a Separation of Issue from Banking, London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1848), A History of Prices and of the State of the Circulation from 1839 to 1847, (Vol. IV), London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T (1856), On the Bank Charter Act of 1844, its Principles and Operation, with suggestions for an improved administration of the Bank of England, London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T. and Newmarch, W. (1857), A History of Prices and of the State of the Circulation from 1848–1856, Vols. V, VI, London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. (1812), An Essay on Money and Paper Currency, London: Johnson.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. (1819), A Comparative Estimate of the Effects which a Continuance and a Removal of the Restriction upon Cash Payments are Respectively Calculated to Produce: with Strictures on Mr. Ricardo’s Proposal for Obtaining a Secure and Economical Currency, London: R. Hunter.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. (1837), A Letter to the Right Honourable Lord Viscount Melbourne on the Causes of the Recent Derangement in the Money Market and on Bank Reform, London: Longman, Rees, Orme, Brown & Green.Google Scholar
Torrens, R (1840), A Letter to Thomas Tooke Esq. In Reply to His Objections Against the Separation of the Business of the Bank into A Department of Iwssue and a Department of Deposit and Discount with a Plan of Bank Reform, London: Longman, Hurst, Orme and Brown.Google Scholar
Torrens, R (1844), An Inquiry into the Practical Working of the Proposed Arrangements for the Renewal of the Charter of the Bank of England and the Regulation of the Currency with a Refutation of the Fallacies Advanced by Mr. Tooke, second edition, London: Smith, Elder & Cornhill.Google Scholar
Torrens, R (1848), The Principles and Practical Operation of Sir Robert Peel’s Act of 1844 Explained and Defended Against the Objections of Tooke, Fullarton and Wilson, London: Longman, Brown, Green and Longmans.Google Scholar
Torrens, R (1857), The Principles and Practical Operation of Sir Robert Peel’s Act of 1844 Explained and Defended, (second edition) London: Longman, Brown, Green, Longmans and Roberts.Google Scholar
Wheatley, J. (1803), Remarks on Currency and Commerce, London: Burton.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. (1889?/2001), “Bank Rate of Interest as the Regulator of Prices”, Edited and translated by M. Boianovsky and H. M. Trautwein, History of Political Economy, vol. 33, pp. 509–516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, K (1893), Value, Capital and Rent, New York: A. M. Kelley, [1954/19??].Google Scholar
Wicksell, K (1898), Interest and Prices: A Study of the Causes Regulating the Value of Money, [Translated by Kahn, R. F.; Introduction by Ohlin, B.] New York: A. M. Kelley, [1936/1965].Google Scholar
Wicksell, K (1906), Lectures on Political economy Vol. II [Edited with an Introduction Robbins, L.], New York: A. M. Kelley, [1935/1978].Google Scholar
Wicksell, K (1907), “The Influence of the Rate of Interest on Prices,” Economic Journal 17, pp. 213–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, K (1925), “The Monetary Problem of the Scandinavian Countries,” in Interest and Prices, Appendix pp. 199–219
Wicksell, K (1958), Selected Papers on Economic Theory, Lindahl, E. (ed.), with an Introduction, New York: A. M. Kelley [1969].Google Scholar
Wicksell, K (1999), Selected Essays in Economics, Sandlin, B. (ed.), volume two, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Wilson, J. (1839), Influences of the Corn Laws as affecting all Classes of the Community and Particularly the Landed Interests, London: Longman, Orme, Brown, Green and Longmans.Google Scholar
Wilson, J (1840), Fluctuations of Currency, Commerce and Manufactures; referable to the Corn Laws, London: Longman, Orme, Brown, Green and Longmans.Google Scholar
Wilson, J (1947), Capital, Currency, and Commerce, London: The Economist.Google Scholar
[Wright, T. B. and Harlow, J.] (1844), The Gemini Letters, London: Simpkin, Marshall.Google Scholar
Angell, J. W. (1926/1965), The Theory of International Prices: History, Criticism, and Restatement, New York: A. M. Kelley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnon, A. (1984), “The Transformation in Thomas Tooke’s Monetary Theory Reconsidered,” History of Political Economy, 16, pp. 311–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnon, A (1984), “Marx’s Theory of Money – The Formative Years,” History of Political Economy 16, 555–575. Also in Wood, J.C. (Ed.), Karl Marx’s Economics: Critical Assessments, Croom Helm, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnon, A (1987), “Banking Between the Invisible and Visible Hands: A Reinterpretation of Ricardo’s Place within the Classical School,” Oxford Economic Papers, 39, pp. 268–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnon, A (1989), “The Early Tooke and Ricardo: A Political Alliance and First Signs of Theoretical Disagreements,” History of Political Economy, 21, pp. 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnon, A (1991), Thomas Tooke: Pioneer of Monetary Theory, Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnon, A (1993), “Discussion” of Laidler, D., “Was Wicksell a Quantity Theorist?”, in Barkai, H., Fischer, S., and Liviatan, N., (Eds.) Monetary Theory and Thought: Essays in Honour of Don Patinkin, Ch 8 pp. 178–181, London: MacMillan Press.Google Scholar
Arnon, A (1997), “Thomas Tooke, The Currency Principle and The 1844 Bank Act”, Introductory Essay to Tooke’s “An Inquiry into the Currency Principle”, re-issued in ‘Klassiker der Nationalokonomie’ series, B. Schefold, (Ed), Dusseldorf, Germany: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen.
Arnon, A (1999), “Free and Not So Free Banking Theories Among the Classicals or Classical Forerunners of Free Banking and Why They Have Been Neglected,” History of Political Economy, Volume 31, pp. 79–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnon, A (2009), “Reexamination of Thornton’s Innovative Monetary Analysis: The Bullion Debate during the Restriction Once Again,” History of Political Economy, Vol. 41, pp. 545–574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashton, T. S. and Sayers, R. S. (eds.) (1953), Papers in English Monetary History, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Atack, J. and Neal, L. (2009), The Origins and Development of Financial Markets and Institutions: from the Seventeenth Century to the Present, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atack, J. (2009), “Financial Innovations and Crises: The View Backwards from Northern Rock”, in Atack, J and Neal, L. (eds.), The Origins and Development of Financial Markets and Institutions: from the Seventeenth Century to the Present, Ch. 1 pp. 1–31, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barkai, H. Fischer, S. and Liviatan, N. (1993), Monetary Theory and Thought: Essays in Honour of Don Patinkin, Hampshire: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaugrand, P. (1982), “Henry Thornton: a mise au pointHistory of Political Economy, vol. 14, pp. 101–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berdell, J. F. (1995), “The Present Relevance of Hume’s Open-Economy Monetary Dynamics”, The Economic Journal, vol. 105, pp. 1205–1217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, F. (1970), “Banking and Interest Rates in a World without Money: The Effects of Uncontrolled Banking,” Journal of Bank Research vol. 1, pp. 9–20.Google Scholar
Blaug, M. (1958), Ricardian Economics: A Historical Study, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Blaug, M. Eltis, W. O’Brien, D. Patinkin, D. Skidelsky, R. and Wood, G. E. (1995), The Quantity Theory of Money from Locke to Keynes and Friedman, Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Boianovsky, M. (1995), “Wicksell’s Business Cycle”, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 2 pp. 375–411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boianovsky, M (1998), “Wicksell, Ramsey and the Theory of Interest,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 5 pp. 140–168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boianovsky, M. and Trautwein, H. M. (2001), “An Early Manuscript by Knut Wicksell on the Bank Rate of InterestHistory of Political Economy, vol. 33, pp. 486–507 [the manuscript Wicksell (1889/2001)].CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonar, J. (1923), “Ricardo’s Ingot Plan,” Economic Journal, 33, pp. 281–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boot, H. M. (1983), “James Wilson and the Commercial Crisis of 1847”, History of Political Economy, vol. 15, pp 567–583.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bridel, P. (1987), Cambridge monetary thought: the development of saving-investment analysis from Marshall to Keynes, London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunhoff, S. de (1973), Marx on Money, New York: Urizen Books [1976].Google Scholar
Buchan, A. (1959), The Spare Chancellor: The life of Walter Bagehot, London: Chatto and Windus.Google Scholar
Caffentzis, C. G. (2008), “Fiction or Counterfeit? David Hume’s Interpretations of Paper and Metallic Money,” Chapter 8 in Wennerlind, C. and Schabas, M. (eds.), David Hume’s Political Economy, Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Campbell, R. H. and Skinner, A. S. (1982), The Origins and Nature of the Scottish Enlightenment, Edinburgh: John Donald.Google Scholar
Cameron, R. E. (1967), Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization: A Study in Comparative Economic History, with the collaboration of Crisp, O.Patrick, H. T. and Tilly, R., New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Cannan, E. (1919), The Paper Pound of 1797–1821, London: P.S. King [with The Bullion Report – 1810].Google Scholar
Capie, F. and Wood, G. E. (eds.) (1986), Financial Crises and the World Banking System, London: Macmillan.CrossRef
Capie, F. and Wood, G. E. (eds.) (1991), Unregulated Banking: Chaos or Order?New York: St. Martin’s Press.CrossRef
Capie, F. (ed.) (1993), History of Banking: 1650–1850, (ten volumes of selected readings), London: William Pickering.
Capie, F. and Wood, G. E. (eds.) (2007), The Lender of Last Resort, London & New York: Routledge.
Cassidy, M. (1998), “The Development of John Fullarton’s Monetary Theory,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 5, pp. 509–535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cesarano, F. (1998), “Hume’s Specie-Flow mechanism and Classical Monetary Theory: An Alternative Interpretation,” Journal of International Economics, vol. 45, pp. 173–186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Checkland, S. G. (1944)
Checkland, S. G. (1975), Scottish Banking: A History 1695–1973, Glasgow: Collins.Google Scholar
Chiodi, G. (1991), Wicksell’s Monetary Theory, New York: St. Martin’s Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clapham, J. H. (1944), The Bank of England: H History, (2 volumes: I 1694–1797; II 1797–1914), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, D. C. (ed.) (1969), Revisions in Mercantilism, London: Methuen.
Collins, M. (1988), Money and Banking in the UK: A History, London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Collins, M. and Baker, M. (2003), Commercial Banks and the Industrial Finance in England and Wales, 1860–1913, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Corry, B. A. (1962), Money, Saving and Investment in English Economics 1800–1850. New York: St Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Cowen, T. and Kroszner, R. (1989), “Scottish Banking Before 1845: A Model of Laissez Faire?Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 21 pp. 221–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daugherty, M. R. (1942), “The Currency-Banking Controversy: Part I,” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 9 (2), pp. 140–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daugherty, M. R (1943), “The Currency-Banking Controversy: Part II,” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 9 (3), pp. 241–251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, T. (2005), Ricardo’s Macroeconomics: Money, Trade Cycles, and Growth, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
de Boyer, des Roches, J. (2007), “Cause and Effect in the Gold Points Mechanism: A Criticism of Ricardo’s criticism of Thornton,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 14, pp. 25–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diatkine, S. and de Boyer, J. (2008), “British Monetary Orthodoxy in the 1870s: A Victory for the Currency PrincipleEuropean Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 15, pp. 181–209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorn, J. A. and Schwartz, A. J. (eds.) (1987), The Search for Stable Money: Essays on Monetary Reform, University of Chicago Press.
Dow, S. C. and Smithin, J. (1992), “Free Banking in Scotland, 1685–1845,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 30, pp. 374–390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dow, S. C. (2002), “Interpretation: The Case of David HumeHistory of Political Economy, vol. 34, pp. 399–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duke, M. I. (1979), “David Hume and Monetary Adjustment,” History of Political Economy, vol. 11, pp. 572–587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eagly, R. V. (1970), “Adam Smith and the Specie-Flow Doctrine,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, pp. 61–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E. F. (1980), “Banking in a Theory of Finance,” Journal of Monetary Economics vol. 6, pp. 39–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feavearyear, A. E. (1931), The Pound Sterling: A History of English Money, second edition revised by Morgan, E. V., Oxford: Clarendon Press [1963].Google Scholar
Fetter, F. W. (1955), The Irish Pound, Evanston: Northwestern University Press.Google Scholar
Fetter, F. W. (1959), “The Politics of the Bullion Report,” Economica, New Series, Vol. 26, pp. 99–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fetter, F. W. (1965), Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, 1797–1875, Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Fetter, F.W (1965), “The Influence of Economists in Parliament on British Legislation from Ricardo to John Stuart Mill,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 83 pp. 1051–1064.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, I. (1911), The theory of interest, New York: Kelley & Millman, 1954.Google Scholar
Foley, D. K. (1983), “On Marx’s Theory of Money,” Social Concept 1, pp. 5–19.Google Scholar
Foley, D. K. (2005), “Marx’s Theory of Money in Historical Perspective” in Marx’s Theory of Money: Modern Appraisals, Moseley, F. (ed.), New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Frenkel, J. A. and Johnson, H. G. (1976), The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments, Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. J. (1986), “Has Government Any Role in Money?Journal of Monetary Economics 17, pp. 37–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardlund, T. (1958), The Life of Knut Wicksell, Translated by Adler, N. from the Swedish, Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell.Google Scholar
Gardlund, T (1978), “The Life of Knut Wicksell and Some Characteristics of His Work,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, pp. 129–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gayer, A. D., Rostow, W. W. and Schwartz, A. J. (1953), The Growth and Fluctuations of the British Economy, 1790–1850, (two volumes), Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Gherity, J. A. (1994), “The Evolution of Adam Smith’s Theory of Banking,” History of Political Economy, vol. 26, pp. 423–441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glasner, D. (1985), “A Reinterpretation of Classical Monetary Theory”, Southern Economic Journal, vol. 52, pp. 46–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glasner, D (1989), “On Some Classical Monetary ControversiesHistory of Political Economy, vol. 21, pp. 201–229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glasner, D (1992), “The Real-Bills Doctrine in the Light of the Law of Reflux”, History of Political Economy, vol. 24, pp. 867–894.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glasner, D (2000), “Classical Monetary Theory and the Quantity TheoryHistory of Political Economy, vol. 32, pp. 39–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, R. (1992), Classical Theories of Money, Output and Inflation, London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenfield, R. L. and Yeager, L. B. (1983), “A Laissez-Faire Approach to Monetary Stability,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 15, pp. 302–315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, T. E. (1928), An Introduction to Tooke and Newmarch’s A History of Prices and the State of the Circulation from 1792–1856, London: L.S.E. Series of Reprints of Scarce Works on Political Economy Mo. 16.
Gregory, T. (1929), Select Statutes Documents & Reports Relating to British Banking 1832–1928 (two volumes), New York: Kelley [1964].Google Scholar
Grubel, H. G. (1961), “Ricardo and Thornton on the Transfer Mechanism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 75, pp. 292–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurley, J. G. and Shaw, E. S. (1960), Money in a Theory of Finance, Palo Alto: Brooking Institution.Google Scholar
Haavelmo, T. (1978), “Wicksell on the Currency Theory vs. The Banking Principle,” in The Theoretical Contributions of Knut Wicksell, Storm, S. and Thalberg, B. (eds.), pp. 81–87, London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Harris, L. (1997), “Corporate Finance and Capital Accumulation” in Arestis, P., Palma, G. and Sawyer, M. (eds) Markets, Unemployment and Economic Policy: Essays in Honor of Geoff Harcourt, Vol. II, Chapter 10 pp. 107–120.
Hayek, F. A. (1929a/1991), “The Period of Restriction, 1797–1821, and The Bullion Debate in England,” in Bartley, W.W. and Kresge, S. (eds.), The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek, volume 3, Ch. 11, pp. 177–215, Chicago: The University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F.A (1929b/1991), “The Dispute Between the Currency School and the Banking School, 1821–1848,” in Bartley, W.W. and Kresge, S. (eds.), The Collected Works of F. A. Hayek, volume 3, Ch. 12, pp. 216–244.
Hayek, F.A (1939), Introduction to the republication of Thornton, H. (1802/1939) Paper Credit, New Jersey: A. M. Kelley [1978].Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. von (1976), The Denationalization of Money, London: Institute of Economic Affairs, second edition, 1978.Google Scholar
Heertje, A. (2004), “The Dutch and Portuguese-Jewish Background of David Ricardo,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 11, pp. 281–294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hetzel, R. L. (1987), “Henry Thornton: Seminal Monetary Theorist and Father of the Modern Central Bank,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, 73 (4), pp. 3–16.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. (1967), Critical Essays in Monetary Theory, Oxford: The Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J (1982), “The Foundations of Monetary Theory,” in Collected Papers in Economic Theory, Volume II, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hicks, J (1989), “LF and LP” in Tsiang, S.C. Finance Constraints and the Theory of Money, edited by Kohn, M., with contributions by J. Hicks, D. Laidler and A. Stocktman, London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J (1989), A Market Theory of Money, Oxford: The Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, F. (1977), “The Bagehot Problem”, The Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies, vol. 45, pp. 241–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, J. H. (1911), “The Developments of the Theory of Money from Adam Smith to David Ricardo,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 25, pp. 426–470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, S. (1973). The Economics of Adam Smith, Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Hollander, S. (1979), The Economics of David Ricardo, Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Hollander, S (1985), The Economics of John Stuart Mill, Volume I Theory and Method, Volume II: Political Economy, Toronto and Buffalo: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Hollander, S (1987), Classical Economics, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hont, I. and Ignatieff, M. (1983), Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsefield, J. K. (1944), “The Origins of the Bank Charter Act, 1844,” Economica, vol. 11 pp. 180–189; also in Ashton, T.S. & Sayers, R.S. (eds.) (1953), Papers in English Monetary History, pp. 109–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsefield, J. K. (1949a), “The Opinions of Horsley Palmer: Governor of the Bank of England, 1830–33,” Economica, New Series, Vol. 16, pp. 143–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsefield, J. K (1949b), “The Cash Ratio in English Banks before 1800,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 57, pp. 70–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsefield, J. K (1952), “British Banking Practices,” Economica, New Series, Vol. 19, pp. 308–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphrey, T. M. (1981), “Adam Smith and the Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments”, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, 67 pp. 3–10.Google Scholar
Humphrey, T. M (1982), “The Real Bills Doctrine”, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, 68(5) pp. 3–13.Google Scholar
Humphrey, T. M (1989), “Lender of Last Resort: The Concept in History,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, 75(2) pp. 8–16.Google Scholar
Humphrey, T. M (1990), “Ricardo versus Thornton on the Appropriate Monetary Response to Supply Shocks,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, 76(6) pp. 18–24.Google Scholar
Humphrey, T. M (1999), “Mercantilists and Classicals: Insights from Doctrinal History”, Economic Quarterly Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, 85(2) pp. 55–82.Google Scholar
Humphrey, T. M (2003), “Knut Wicksell and Gustav Cassel on the Cumulative Process and the Price-Stabilizing Policy Rule,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 25 pp. 199–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphrey, T. M (2004), “Alfred Marshall and the Quantity Theory of Money,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Working Paper 10–04.
Hutchison, T. W. (1988), Before Adam Smith: The Emergence of Political Economy, 1662–1776, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Ingham, G. (2005), Concepts of Money: Interdisciplinary Perspectives from Economics, Sociology and Political Science, Elgar.Google Scholar
Kareken, J. H. and Wallace, N. (eds.) (1980), Models of Monetary Economics, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
Kindleberger, C. R. (1978), Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B. (1974), “The Competitive Supply of Money,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 6, pp. 423–453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, D. (1972), “Thomas Tooke on Monetary Reform” in Peston, M. and Corry, B., (eds), Essays in Honour of Lord Robbins, London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.Google Scholar
Laidler, D (1981), “Adam Smith as a Monetary Economist”, Canadian Journal of Economics, 14, pp. 185–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, D (1984) “Misconceptions about the Real-Bills Doctrine: A Comment on Sargent and WallaceJournal of Political Economy, vol. 92, pp.147–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, D (1990), “Alfred Marshall and the Development of Monetary Economics”, in Centenary Essays on Alfred Marshall, Whitaker, J. K. (ed.), pp. 44–78, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; also in Macroeconomics in Retrospect: The Selected Essays of David Laidler, Cheltenham: Elgar [2004].Google Scholar
Laidler, D (1991), The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory, Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, D (1993), “Was Wicksell a Quantity Theorist?” in Barkai, H., Fischer, S., and Liviatan, N., (Eds.), Monetary Theory and Thought: Essays in Honour of Don Patinkin, Ch. 8 pp. 178–181, London: MacMillan Press.Google Scholar
Laidler, D (2000), “Highlights of the Bullionist Controversy”, Research Report #13, Stockholm School of Economics, Institute for Research in Economic History.
Laidler, D (2002), “Rules, Discretion and Financial Crises in Classical and Neoclassical Monetary Economics,” Economic Issues, vol. 7 pp. 11–33; also in Macroeconomics in Retrospect: The Selected Essays of David Laidler, pp. 17–39, Cheltenham: Elgar [2004].Google Scholar
Laidler, D (2004), “Two Views of the Lender of Last Resort: Thornton and Bagehot,” in Macroeconomics in retrospect: The selected essays of David Laidler, pp. 40–56, Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Laidler, D (2006), “Woodford and Wicksell on Interest and Prices: The Place of the Pure Credit Economy in the Theory of Monetary Policy,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 28, pp. 151–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. (1981), “The Wicksell Connection: Variations on Theme” in Information and Coordination: Essays in Macroeconomic Theory, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lindahl, E. (1958), “Wicksell’s Life and Work,” Introduction to Wicksell, K. (1958), Selected Papers on Economic Theory, New York: A. M. Kelley [1969].Google Scholar
Link, R. C. (1959), English Theories of Economic Fluctuations 1815–1848, New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Magnusson, L. (1994), Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCallum, B. T. (1985), “Bank Deregulation, Accounting Systems of Exchange, and the Unit of Account: A Critical Review,” in Carnegie-Rochester Conferences Series on Public Policy, 23, pp. 13–46.CrossRef
Mints, L. W. (1945), A History of Banking Theory, Chicago: The University Press.Google Scholar
Mises, von L. (1912), The Theory of Money and Credit, translated from the German by Batson, H. E., Introduction L. Robbins, New York: The Foundation for Economic Education [1971].Google Scholar
Mitchell, B. R. with the collaboration of P. Deane (1962), Abstract of British Historical Statistics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press [1971].Google Scholar
Mitchell, B. R (1988), British Historical Statistics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Monroe, A. E. (1923), Monetary Theory before Adam Smith, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, J. (ed.) (1985), The Economics of the Industrial Revolution, Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allan.
Mokyr, J. (1993), The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective, Boulder: Westview Press.
Morgan, E. V. and Thomas, W. A. (1962), The Stock Exchange: Its History and Functions, London: Elek Books.Google Scholar
Munn, C. W. (1981), The Scottish Provincial Banking Companies, 1747–1864, Edinburgh: John Donald Publishers.Google Scholar
Munn, C.W (1991), “Comment” [on White 1991a], in Capie, F. and Wood, G.E. (eds.) Unregulated Banking: Chaos or Order? pp. 63–67.
Murphy, A. E. (2003), “Paper Credit and the Multi-Personae Mr. Henry Thornton,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 10 pp. 429–453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, A. E (2005), “Rejoinder to Skaggs’s Treating Schizophrenia: a comment on Antoin Murphy’s diagnosis of Henry Thornton’s Theoretical Condition,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 12 pp. 329–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nakano, T. (2006), “‘Let Your Science be Human’: Hume’s Economic Methodology,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 30, pp. 687–700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neal, L. (1990), The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Neal, L (1998), “The Financial Crisis of 1825 and the Restructuring of the British Financial System,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 80 (3) pp. 53–76.Google Scholar
Nelson, A. (1999), Marx’s Concept of Money: The God of Commodities, London and New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niehans, J. (1978), The Theory of Money, The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
O’Brien, D. P. (1965), “The Transition in Torrens’ Monetary Thought,” Economica, vol. 32, pp. 269–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Brien, D.P (1971), “Introduction” in The Correspondence of Lord Overstone, (Three Volumes), vol. 1 pp. 12–144, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
O’Brien, D.P (1993), Thomas Joplin and Classical Macroeconomics: A Reappraisal of Classical Monetary Thought, Aldershot: Elgar.Google Scholar
O’Brien, D.P (1995), “Long-run Equilibrium and cyclical disturbances: the currency and banking controversy over monetary control,” in M. Blaug, et.al. also in O’Brien (2007) Ch. 5.
O’Brien, D.P (1997), “Monetary Base Control and the Bank Act of 1844”, History of Political Economy, vol. 29, pp. 593–633, also in O’Brien (2007) Ch. 6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Brien, D.P (2001), “Bagehot’s Lombard Street and Macroeconomic Stabilisation”, The Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 48, pp. 425–441, also in O’Brien (2007) Ch. 8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Brien, D.P (2003), “The Lender-of-Last-Resort Concept in Britain”, History of Political Economy, vol. 35, pp. 1–19, also in O’Brien (2007) Ch. 7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Brien, D.P (2004), The Classical Economists Revisited, second revised edition, Princeton: Princeton University Press [first edition 1975].Google Scholar
O’Brien, D.P (2007a), The Development of Monetary Economics: A Modern Perspective on Monetary Controversies, Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Ohlin, B. (1936), Introduction to Wicksell, K. Interest and Prices, Kelley [1965].Google Scholar
Paganelli, M. P. (2009), “David Hume on Monetary Policy: A Retrospective Approach,” The Journal of Scottish Philosophy, Vol. 7, pp. 65–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patinkin, D. (1952), “Wicksell’s Cumulative Process,” Economic Journal, vol. 62 pp. 835–847.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patinkin, D (1961), “Financial Intermediaries and the Logical Structure of Monetary Theory,” American Economic Review, pp. 95–116.Google Scholar
Patinkin, D (1965), Money, Interest and Prices (2nd Edition), New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Peach, T. (2004), “David Ricardo” in Oxford Dictionary of National Biography, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Peake, C. F. (1978), “Henry Thornton and the Development of Ricardo’s Economic Thought”, History of Political Economy, 10, pp. 193–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peake, C. F (1982), “Henry Thornton: An Accurate PerspectiveHistory of Political Economy, 14, pp. 115–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peake, C. F (1995), “Henry Thornton in the History of Economics: Confusions and Contributions,” Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 63, pp. 283–296.CrossRef
Perlman, M. (1986), “The Bullionist Controversy Revisited,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, pp. 745–762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perlman, M (1987), “Of a Controversial Passage in Hume,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 95, pp. 274–289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perlman, M (1989), “Adam Smith and the paternity of the Real Bills doctrine,” History of Political Economy, Vol. 21, pp. 77–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petrella, F. (1968), “Adam Smith Rejection of Hume’s Price-Specie-Flow Mechanism: A Minor Mystery Resolved,” Southern Economic Journal, vol. 34, pp. 365–374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1917), “The Value of Money,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 38–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. (1985), Virtue, Commerce and History: Essays on Political Thought and History, Chiefly in the Eighteenth Century, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poitras, G. (1998), “Robert Torrens and the Evolution of the Real Bills Doctrine,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Vol. 20 pp. 479–498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pressnell, L. S. (1956), Country Banking in the Industrial Revolution, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Quinn, S. and Roberds, W. (2009), “An Economic Explanation of the Early Bank of Amsterdam, Debasement, Bills of Exchange, and the Emergence of the First Central Bank” in Atack, J and Neal, L. (eds.) The Origins and Development of Financial Markets and Institutions: from the Seventeenth Century to the Present, Ch. 2, pp. 32–70, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Reed, M. (2004), “Loyd, Samuel Jones, Baron Overstone (1796–1883),” Oxford Dictionary of National Biography, Oxford University Press, Sept 2004; online edn, Jan 2008 [, accessed type=”text/javascript”document.write(printCitationDate());24 March 2008]Google Scholar
Reisman, D. A. (1971), “Henry Thornton and Classical Monetary Economics,” Oxford Economic Papers, 23, pp. 70–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
>Ricardo, D. (1951–1973),Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, edited by P. Sraffa, 11 volumes, Cambridge: The University Press.Google Scholar
Rist, C. (1940), History of Monetary and Credit Theory from John Law to the Present Day, New York: A. M. Kelly [1966].Google Scholar
Robbins, L. (1958), Robert Torrens and the Evolution of Classical Economics, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Roberts, R. and Kynaston, D. (eds.) (1995), The Bank of England: Money, Power and Influence, 1694–1994, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Rockoff, H. (1986), “Walter Bagehot and the Theory of Central Banking,” in Capie, F. and Wood, G. F., Financial Crises and the World Banking System, pp. 160–180, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Rosdolsky, R. (1968), The making of Marx’s Capital, London, Pluto Press [1977].Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. N. (1995), Classical Economics: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Vol. II, Aldershot, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. N (1997), The Logic of Action I: Method, Money and the Austrian School, Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Rotwein, E. (1955), Introduction to David Hume: Writings on Economics, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Salerno, J. T. (1980), The Doctrinal Antecedents of the Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments, Ph. D. Thesis, Rutgers University.Google Scholar
Santiago-Valiente, W. (1988), “Historical Background of the Classical Monetary Theory and the ‘Real Bills’ Banking Tradition,” History of Political Economy, vol. 20, pp. 43–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saville, R. (1996), The Bank of Scotland: A History 1695–1995, Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
Sayers, R. S. (1953), “Ricardo’s Views on Monetary Questions,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 67, pp. 30–49 also in T. S. Ashton and R.S. Sayers Papers in English Monetary History pp. 76–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sayers, R. S. (1963), “The Life and Work of James Pennington,” in Economic Writings of James Pennington, London, LSE.Google Scholar
Sayers, R. S. (1976), The Bank of England, 1891–1944, (three volumes) Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sayers, R. S. (1978), “Introductory Essay” in The Collected Works of Walter Bagehot, N. St John-Stevas (ed.), Vol. 9, pp. 27–43.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1954), History of Economic Analysis, London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Schwartz, A. J. (1987), “Banking School, Currency School, Free Banking School” in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, (eds.) Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P.London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Sechrest, L. J. (1991), “Free Banking in Scotland: A Dissenting View,” Cato Journal, vol. 10, pp. 799–808.Google Scholar
Selgin, G. A. and White, L. H. (1994), “How would the Invisible Hand Handle Money?Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 32, pp. 1718–1749.Google Scholar
Silberling, N. J. (1919), “British Financial Experience 1790–1830,” The Review of Economic Statistics, vol. 1 pp. 282–297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silberling, N. J (1924), “Financial and Monetary Policy of Great Britain During the Napoleonic Wars,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, parts I and II, Vol. 38, pp. 214–233 and 397–439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. C. (1936), “Rules versus Authorities in Monetary Policy,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 44, pp. 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siven, C. H. (2006), “Monetary Equilibrium,” History of Political Economy, 38, pp. 665–709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaggs, N. T. (1991), “John Fullarton’s Law of Reflux and Central Bank Policy”, History of Political Economy, 23, pp. 457–480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaggs, N.T (1994), “The Place of J. S. Mill in the Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, “ History of Political Economy, 26, pp. 539–567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaggs, N.T (1995), “Henry Thornton and the Development of Classical Monetary Economics”, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 28, pp. 1212–1227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaggs, N.T (1999), “Changing Views: Twentieth-Century Opinion on the Banking School – Currency School Controversy,” History of Political Economy, vol. 31, pp. 361–391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaggs, N.T (2003), “Thomas Tooke, Henry Thornton and the Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 25, pp. 177–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaggs, N.T (2005) “Treating Schizophrenia: a comment on Antoin Murphy’s diagnosis of Henry Thornton’s Theoretical Condition,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 12 pp. 321–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skaggs, N.T (2008), “An Inquiry into the Nature and Effects of Henry Thornton’s Christian Faith on the Existence and Contents of his Economic Writings”, History of Political Economy, vol. 40 (annual supplement), pp. 168–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, A. S. (1993), “David Hume: Principles of Political Economy” in Norton, D. F. (ed.), The Cambridge Companion to Hume, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Skinner, A. S. (1996), “David Hume: Economic Writings” in A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith (2nd edition), Oxford: Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skinner, A. S. and Wilson, T. (1975), Essays on Adam Smith, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Smith, B. D. (1988), “Legal Restrictions, ‘Sunspots,’ and Peel’s Bank Act: The Real Bills Doctrine versus the Quantity Theory Reconsidered,” Journal of Political Economy, 96, pp. 3–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. C. (1936), The Rationale of Central Banking, London: P.S. King.Google Scholar
Sylla, R. (2009), “Comparing the UK and US financial Systems, 1790–1830,” “ in Atack, J. and Neal, L. (eds.) The Origins and Development of Financial Markets and Institutions: from the Seventeenth Century to the Present, Ch. 7 pp. 209–234, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, W. L. (1965), Francis Hutcheson and David Hume as Predecessors of Adam Smith, Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Thornton, M. (2007), “Cantillon, Hume, and the Rise of Antimercantilism,” History of Political Economy, 39(3), pp. 453–480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsiang, S.C. (1989) “The Monetary Theoretic Foundations of the Modern Monetary approach to the Balance of Payments” in Finance Constraints and the Theory of Money, edited by Kohn, M., with contributions by Hicks, J., Laidler, D., and Stocktman, A., London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Uhr, C. G. (1960), Economic Doctrines of Knut Wicksell, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Vickers, D. (1959), Studies in the Theory of Money, 1690–1776, London: Peter Owen.Google Scholar
Vickers, D (1976), “Adam Smith and the Status of the Theory of Money,” in Skinner, A.S. & Wilson, T., Essays on Adam Smith, pp. 428–503, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Viner, J. (1924), Canada’s Balance of International Indebtedness, 1990–1913, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Viner, J (1937), Studies in the Theory of International Trade, New York: A. M. Kelley [1975].Google Scholar
Wennerlind, C. (2000), “The Humean Paternity to Adam Smith’s Theory of Money”, History of Economic Ideas, Vol. 8, pp. 77–97.Google Scholar
Wennerlind, C (2001), “The Link between David Hume’s Treatise of Human Nature and His Fiduciary Theory of Money”, History of Political Economy, vol. 33 pp. 139–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wennerlind, C (2005), “David Hume’s Monetary Theory Revisited: Was He Really a Quantity Theorist and an Inflationist?”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 113 pp. 223–237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wennerlind, C (2008), “An Artificial Virtue and the Oil of Commerce: A Synthetic View of Hume’s Theory of Money” in Wennerlind, C. and Schabas, M. (eds.) (2008), David Hume’s Political Economy, Chapter 6, pp. 103–126, Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Wennerlind, C. and Schabas, M. (eds.) (2008), David Hume’s Political Economy, Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Whitaker, J. K. (ed.) (1975), The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall, 1867–1890, two volumes, London: Macmillan (for the Royal Economic Society).
White, L. H. (1984), Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience and Debates, 1800–1845, Cambridge: The University Press.Google Scholar
White, L.H (1989), Competition and Currency: Essays on Free Banking and Money, New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
White, L.H (1991a), “Banking without a Central Bank: Scotland Before 1884 as a Free Banking System,” in Unregulated Banking Chaos or Order, edited by Forrest, C. and Woods, G. E., New York: St. Martin’s Press, pp. 37–62.Google Scholar
White, L.H (1991b), “Free Banking in Scotland: Reply to a Dissenting View,” Cato Journal, vol. 11, pp. 809–810.Google Scholar
Wood, E. (1939), English Theories of Central Banking Control: 1819–1858, Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, J. H. (2005), A History of Central Banking in Great Britain and the United States, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Arie Arnon, Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel
  • Book: Monetary Theory and Policy from Hume and Smith to Wicksell
  • Online publication: 05 July 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511921384.027
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Arie Arnon, Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel
  • Book: Monetary Theory and Policy from Hume and Smith to Wicksell
  • Online publication: 05 July 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511921384.027
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Arie Arnon, Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel
  • Book: Monetary Theory and Policy from Hume and Smith to Wicksell
  • Online publication: 05 July 2014
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511921384.027
Available formats
×