Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-5nwft Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T23:47:13.006Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false
This chapter is part of a book that is no longer available to purchase from Cambridge Core

References

Richard B. McKenzie
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
Dwight R. Lee
Affiliation:
University of Georgia
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Microeconomics for MBAs
The Economic Way of Thinking for Managers
, pp. 492 - 512
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abowd, John M., 1990. Does performance-based managerial compensation affect corporate performance?Industrial and Labor Relations Review 43: 52S–53SCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adam, Scott, 1995. Manager's journal: the Dilbert principle, Wall Street Journal, May 22: A14Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A., 1970. The market for lemons: qualitative uncertainty and the market mechanism, Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 488–500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold, 1973. The property rights paradigm, Journal of Economic History 33: 17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexis, M., 1974. The political economy of labor market discrimination: synthesis and exploration, in Horowitz, A. and Furstenberg, G. (eds.), Patterns of Discrimination, Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath/Lexington BooksGoogle Scholar
Alonzo-Zaldivar, Ricardo, 2005. Insurance option has workers pay more, Los Angeles Times, May 23: A1.Google Scholar
Alpert, William T., 1986. The Minimum Wage in the Restaurant Industry, New York: PraegerGoogle Scholar
Amihud, Y. and Lev, B., 1981. Risk aversion as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers, Bell Journal of Economics 12: 605–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Terry L. and Jenson Hill, Peter, 2004. The Not So Wild, Wild West: Property Rights on the Frontier, Stanford, CA: Stanford University PressGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ariely, Dan, 2008. Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces that Shape Our Decisions, New York: HarperCollins PublishersGoogle Scholar
Aristotle, , Ethics, vol. 8, no. 9
Armentano, Dominick T., 1990. Antitrust and Monopoly: Anatomy of a Policy Failure, Oakland, CA: Independent InstituteGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth, 1963. Social Choice and Individual Values, New York: WileyGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. B., 1996. Increasing returns and the new world of business, Harvard Business Review 74(4): 100–9Google Scholar
,Associated Press, 2005a. Store says two others selling gas too cheap, Winston-Salem Journal, May 5: B5Google Scholar
,Associated Press, 2005b. North Carolina fails to make cut for U.S. airbus factory, Winston-Salem Journal, May 6, available on May 9, 2005 at www.journalnow.com/servlet/Satellite?pagename=WSJ/MGArticle/WSJ_BasicArticle&c=MGArticle&cid=1031782569685Google Scholar
,Associated Press, 2005c. Senate looks at raising minimum wage, Wall Street Journal, March 6: A17Google Scholar
Atlanta Journal – Constitution, 1995. Long-term risk (editorial), April 15: A10
Axelrod, Robert and Hamilton, W. D., 1987. The evolution of cooperation, Science 211: 1390–6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacevich, Andrew, 2008. The Limits of Power: The End of American Exceptionalism, New York: Metropolitan BooksGoogle Scholar
Baker, George, 2000. The use of performance in incentive contracting, American Economic Review 90(2): 415–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, George, Gibbon, Robert, and Murphy, Kevin, 1994. Subjective performance measures in optimal incentive contracts, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109: 1125–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balaker, Ted and Moore, Adrian T., 2005. Offshoring and Public Fear: Assessing the Real Threat to Jobs, Santa Monica, CA: Reason Foundation, Policy Study 33, available on May 19, 2005 at www.rppi.org/ps333.pdfGoogle Scholar
Banks, Howard, 1994. A sixties industry in a nineties economy, Forbes, May 9: 107–12Google Scholar
Barham, Catherine and Begum, Nasima, 2005. Sickness absence from work in the UK, in Labour Market Trends, London: Office for National Statistics, Labour Market Division, AprilGoogle Scholar
Barker, Colin, 2009. Dell's Ireland plant to shed 1,900 jobs, CNET News, January 8, accessed February 5, 2009 from http://news.cnet.com/8301–1001_3-10136439-92.html
Barkham, Patrick, 1999. The banana wars explained, Guardian, March 5, accessed on March 9, 2009 from www.guardian.co.uk/world/1999/mar/05/eu.wto3
Bartlett, C. A. and O'Connell, J., 1998. Lincoln Electric: venturing abroad, Boston: Harvard University Graduate School of Business, Case 3–398–095
Bastiat, Frédéric, 1996. Economic Sophisms, Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: The Foundation for Economic Education, Inc., trans. and ed. Arthur Goddard, Library of Economics and Liberty, available on January 4, 2004 at www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basSoph3.html>
Baumol, William J., 1982. Contestable markets: an uprising in the theory of industry structure, American Economic Review 72: 1–15Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1971. Economic Theory, New York: Alfred A. KnopfGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S., 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. and Murphy, Kevin M., 1988. A theory of rational addiction, Journal of Political Economy 96(4): 675–700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, W., Ronen, J., and Sorter, G. H., 1974. Opportunity costs – an experimental approach, Journal of Accounting Research, Autumn: 317–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendavid, Naftali, Williamson, Elizabeth, and Reddy, Sudeep, 2009. Stimulus package unveiled, Wall Street Journal, January 16: A1Google Scholar
Bennett, James T. and Johnson, Manuel H., 1983. Better Government at Half the Price, Ottawa, IL: Carolina HouseGoogle Scholar
Bentley, Arthur, 1967. The Process of Government, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, Harvard University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berlau, John, 2007. The subprime FHA, Wall Street Journal, October 15, accessed January 14, 2009 from http://online.wsj.com/article/SB119241016826258768.html
Bernanke, Ben, 2009. Comments before the Federal Open Market Committee, December 9, 2003, as reprinted in Ben Bernanke vs. the journal on inflation, Wall Street Journal, June 23: A15Google Scholar
Bethel, Tom, 1998. The Noblest Triumph: Property and Prosperity through the Ages, New York: St. Martin's PressGoogle Scholar
Beverage Digest, 2008. Elasticity: big price increases cause Coke volume to plummet, November 21: 3–4
Bhagat, Sanjai, Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert W., 1990. Hostile takeovers in the 1980s: the return to corporate specialization, in Bailey, Martin N. and Winston, Clifford (eds.), Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Washington, DC: Brookings InstitutionGoogle Scholar
Bhide, Amar, 1990. Reversing corporate diversification, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 3: 70–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, William K., Calavita, Kitty, and Pontell, Henry N., 1995. The savings and loan debacle of the 1980s: white-collar crime or risky business?Law & Policy 17(1): 23–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blalock, Garrick, Kadiyali, Vrinda, and Simon, Daniel H., 2005a. The impact of post 9/11 airport security measures on the demand for air travel, Ithaca, NY: Economics Department, Cornell University, Working Paper, February 23 version
Blalock, Garrick, Kadiyali, Vrinda, and Simon, Daniel H., 2005b. The impact of 9/11 on road fatalities: the other lives lost to terrorism, Ithaca, NY: Economics Department, Cornell University, Working Paper, February 2 version
Blinder, Alan, 1987. Hard Heads, Soft Hearts, Reading, MA: Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Boehm, Christopher, 1993. Egalitarian behavior and reverse dominance hierarchy, Current Anthropology 14: 227–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E., 1970. Economics as a Science, New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert, 2001. The evolution of strong reciprocity, Amherst, MA, Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts, Working Paper
Brandenburger, Adam M. and Nalebuff, Barry J., 1996. Co-Opetition, New York: Currency/DoubledayGoogle Scholar
Breit, William and Elzinga, Kenneth G., 1985. Private antitrust enforcement: the new learning, Journal of Law and Economics 28(2): 405–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breyer, Stephen, 1982. Regulation and Its Reform, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Brickley, James A., Bhagat, Sanjai, and Lease, Ronald C., 1985. The impact of long-range managerial compensation plans on shareholder wealth, Journal of Accounting and Economics 7: 115–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, James A. and Dark, Frederick H., 1987. The choice of organizational forms: the case of franchising, Journal of Financial Economics 18: 401–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brody, Jane E. 2005. As Americans get bigger, the world does, too, New York Times, April 19: D1Google Scholar
Brown, Charles, Gilroy, Curtis, and Kohen, Andrew, 1982. The effect of the minimum wage on employment and unemployment, Journal of Economic Literature 20: 487–528Google Scholar
Brownell, Kelly D. and Frieden, Thomas R., 2009. Ounces of prevention – the public policy case for taxes on sugared beverages, New England Journal of Medicine 360 (18, April 30): 1805–8CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Browning, Edgar, 1974. Why the social insurance budget is too large in a democracy, Economic Inquiry 13: 373–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Yoon, Yong J., 2000. Symmetric tragedies: commons and anticommons, Journal of Law and Economics 43(1): 1–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulow, Jeremy and Summers, Lawrence, 1986. A theory of dual labor markets with applications to industrial policy, discrimination and Keynesian unemployment, Journal of Labor Economics 4(3): 376–414CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2004. The Effect of Outsourcing and Offshoring on BLS Productivity Measures, March 26, available on August 20, 2004 at www.bls.gov/lpc/lproffshoring.pdf
Burgelman, Robert, 2002. Strategy Is Destiny: How Strategy-Making Shapes a Company's Future, New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Bush, Winston C., 1972. Individual welfare in anarchy, in Tullock, Gordon (ed.), Explorations in the Theory of Anarchy, Blacksburg, VA: University Publications, Inc.Google Scholar
Buurma, Christine, 2009. Energy consumption by the numbers, Wall Street Journal, January 9: R2Google Scholar
Byrne, John A., 1996. Has outsourcing gone too far?Business Week, April 1: 27Google Scholar
Cable, John and Wilson, Nicolas, 1989. Profit-sharing and productivity: an analysis of UK engineering firms, Economic Journal 99: 366–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cain, G. G., 1986. The economic analysis of labor market discrimination: a survey, in Aschenfelter, O. and Layard, R. (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, London: Elsevier Science PublishersGoogle Scholar
Cannon, Michael F., 2003. Three avenues to patient power, Brief Analysis, Dallas, TX: National Center for Policy Analysis, 430, January 30, available on August 17, 2004 at www.ncpa.org/iss/hea/2003/pd013003a.htmlGoogle Scholar
Card, David and Krueger, Alan B., 1995. Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Carmichael, H. L., 1988. Incentives in academics: why is there tenure?Journal of Political Economy 96(2): 453–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartwright, Dorwin, 1968. The nature of group cohesiveness, in Cartwright, Dorwin and Zander, Alvin (eds.), Group Dynamics: Research and Theory, 3rd edn, New York: Harper and RowGoogle Scholar
Chernova, Yuliya and Krieger, Sari, 2009. How to go green in hard times, Wall Street Journal, January 9: R1Google Scholar
Cherrie, Victoria, 2005. Dell requests rezoning for new access road in agricultural area, Winston-Salem Journal, April 30: B1Google Scholar
Christensen, Clayton M., 1997. The Innovator's Dilemma: When New Technologies Cause Great Firms to Fail, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School PressGoogle Scholar
Chung, Juliet, 2009. Looming tariffs whet appetite for delicacies, Wall Street Journal, March 31: A3.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., 1937. The nature of the firm, Economica 4(16): 386–405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., 1972. Durability and monopoly, Journal of Law and Economics 15: 143–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law, Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 33–55 (reprinted from Ronald H. Coase, The nature of the firm, Economica 4 (1937): 386–405)Google Scholar
Cobb, William E., 1973. Theft and the two hypotheses, in Rottenberg, Simon (ed.), The Economics of Crime and Punishment, Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy ResearchGoogle Scholar
Coleman, Major D., Lacour-Little, Michael, and Vandell, Kerry D., 2008. Subprime lending and the housing bubble: tail wags the dog? Social Science Research Network, September 2, accessed January 14, 2009 from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1262365
,Congressional Budget Office, 2009. The Estimated Costs to Households from the Cap-and-Trade Provisions of H.R. 2454, June 19, as accessed on June 25, 2009 from http://cbo.gov/ftpdocs/103xx/doc10327/06–19-CapTradeCosts.htm
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas, 1988. Law and Economics, Glenview, IL: Scott ForesmanGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John, 1992. Cognitive adaptation for social exchange, in Barkow, Jerome H., Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John (eds.), The Adapted Mind, New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Craig, Lynn, 2003. The time cost of children: a cross-national comparison of the interaction between time use and fertility rate, University of New South Wales, Sydney, paper presented at the IATUR Conference on Time Use Research, September 15–17, available on August 17, 2004 at www.sprc.unsw.edu.au/people/Craig/Time%20Cost%20of%20Children%20Time%20use%20and%20Fertility.pdf
Crain, W. Mark and Hopkins, Thomas D., 2001. The Impact of Regulatory Costs on Small Firms: A Report for the Office of Advocacy, Washington, DC: U.S. Small Business Administration, RFP No. SBAHW-00-R-0027, available on March 31, 2005 at www.sba.gov/advo/research/rs207.pdfGoogle Scholar
Crandall, Robert, 1985. Assessing the impact of the automobile export restraints upon U.S. automobile prices, Brookings Institution, December, mimeo
Crucini, Mario J. and Kahn, James, 1996. Tariffs and aggregate economic activity: lessons from the Great Depression, Journal of Monetary Economics 38(3): 427–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Jonathan, 1994. Many bypass the new rules of the road, Wall Street Journal, September 29: B1Google Scholar
Daniels, Mitch, 2009. Indiana says “no thanks” to cap and trade, Wall Street Journal, May 15: A11Google Scholar
David, Paul A., 1985. Clio and the economics of QWERTY, American Economic Review 75(2): 332–7Google Scholar
Davidow, William and Malone, Michael, 1992. The Virtual Corporation, New York: HarperCollinsGoogle Scholar
Davis, Bob, 2009. World economies plummet, Wall Street Journal, May 21: A1Google Scholar
Davis, Laura J., 2005. Privatization brings big savings to Michigan's state universities, Chicago: Heartland Institute, April, available on May 13, 2005 at www.heartland.org/Article.cfm?artId=16769
Dawkins, Richard, 1976. The Selfish Gene, Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Demick, Barbara, 2009. China links birth defects to pollution, Los Angeles Times, February 2: A6Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold, 1967. Toward a theory of property rights, American Economic Review 57: 347–59Google Scholar
Deneckere, Raymond J. and Preston McAfee, R., 1996. Damaged goods, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 5(2): 149–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dennen, Rodgers Taylor, 1975. From common to private property: the enclosure of the open range, PhD dissertation, Economics Department, University of Washington
Dennis, Debra K. and McConnell, John J., 1986. Corporate mergers and security returns, Journal of Financial Economics 16: 143–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeLorenzo, Thomas J., 1985. The origins of antitrust: an interest group perspective, International Review of Law and Economics 5: 73–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dore, Ronald P., 1987. Taking Japan Seriously, Stanford, CA: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Dornbush, Rudiger and Krugman, Paul, 1976. Flexible exchange rates in the short run, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, March: 537–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drucker, Peter, 2001. Management Challenges for the 21st Century, New York: HarperBusinessGoogle Scholar
Dunbar, Robin, 1998. The social brain hypothesis, Evolutionary Anthropology 6: 178–903.0.CO;2-8>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunlap, Al and Andelman, Bob, 1996. Mean Business: How I Save Bad Companies and Make Good Companies Great, New York: Times BooksGoogle Scholar
Dunn, L. F., 1985. Nonpecuniary job preferences and welfare losses among migrant agriculture workers, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67(2): 257–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyer, Geoff and Braithwaite, Tom, 2009. U.S. tyre duties spark China clash, FT.com, accessed on September 15, 2009 from www.ft.com/cms/s/0/f67c6fe6-a024–11de-b9ef-00144feabdc0.html
Earley, P. Christopher, 1989. Social loafing and collectivism: a comparison of the United States and the People's Republic of China, Administrative Science Quarterly 34(4): 565–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The Economist, 1999. Lessons from Microsoft, March 6: 21
Earley, P. Christopher, 2004a. Dead firms walking, September 23, available on June 21, 2005 at www.economist.com/business/displayStory.cfm?story_id=3219857
Earley, P. Christopher, 2004b. Low-cost airlines, July 8, available on June 21, 2005 at www.economist.com/displaystory.cfm?story_id=S%27%298L%25Q%21%2F%21%20P%23L%0A
Earley, P. Christopher, 2004c. Turbulent skies, July 8, available on August 21, 2005 at www.economist.com/business/displaystory.cfm?story_id=2897525
Editors, . Wall Street Journal, 2009. Obama's global tax raid, May 6: A14Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry, 1989. The political economy of the Smoot-Hawley tariff, Research in Economic History 12: 1–43Google Scholar
,Energy Information Administration, 2007. Emissions of Greenhouse Gases in the United States, 2006, tables 5–9 (November), as accessed on May 24, 2009 from http://usasearch.gov/search?affiliate=eia.doe.gov&v%3Aproject=firstgov&query=emissions+GDP and www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/1605/archive/gg02rpt/gasfig1.html
Esty, Daniel C. and Winston, Andrew, 2009. Green to Gold: How Smart Companies Use Environmental Strategy to Innovate, Create Value, and Build Competitive Advantage, New York: WileyGoogle Scholar
Evans, David S., Nichols, Albert, and Reddy, Bernard, 1999. The Rise and Fall of Leaders in Personal Computer Software, Cambridge, MA: National Economic Research Associates, January 7Google Scholar
Farrell, J. and Klemperer, P., 2007. Coordination and lock-in: competition with switching costs and network effects, in Armstrong, M. and Porter, R. H. (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Amsterdam: ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Fast, N. and Berg, N., 1971. The Lincoln Electric Company, Harvard Business School Case, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School PressGoogle Scholar
Feenstra, Robert C., 1992. How costly is protectionism?Journal of Economic Perspective 6(3): 159–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Schmidt, Klaus M., 2002. Theories of fairness and reciprocity – evidence and economic application, in Dewatripont, M., Hansen, L., and Turnovsky, S. J. (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics, 8th World Congress, Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Feldstein, Martin, 2009. Tax increases could kill the recovery, Wall Street Journal, May 13, 2009: A19Google Scholar
Ferrell, Greg, 2000. Online time at office soars, USA Today, February 18: 1AGoogle Scholar
Fishback, Price V., 1992. Soft Coal, Hard Choices: The Economic Welfare of Bituminous Coal Miners, 1890–1930, New York: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Franklin M., 1998. Direct testimony, U.S. v. Microsoft Corporation, Civil Action No. 98–1233 (TPJ), filed October 14, available on August 16, 2004 at www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f2000/2057.pdf
Fisher, Richard W., 2005. Protect us from protectionists, Wall Street Journal, April 25: A14Google Scholar
FitzRoy, Felix R. and Kraft, Kornelius, 1986. Profitability and profit-sharing, Journal of Industrial Economics 35(2): 113–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fitzroy, Felix R., and Kraft, Kornelius, 1987. Cooperation, productivity and profit sharing, Quarterly Journal of Economics 103: 23–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleisher, Belton M., 1981. Minimum Wage Regulation in Retail Trade, Washington, DC: American Enterprise InstituteGoogle Scholar
Flint, Joe, 2005. Blockbuster faces state suit over no late fees, Wall Street Journal, February 22: D2Google Scholar
Forelle, Charles and Wingfield, Nick, 2009. EU hits Microsoft with new antitrust charges, Wall Street Journal, January 17–18: B5Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H., 1988. Passions within Reason: The Strategic of the Emotions, New York: W. W. NortonGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H., Gilgorich, Thomas, and Regan, Dennis T., 1996. Do economists make bad citizens?Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 GJ: 187–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Steven A. 2009. Evolutionary foundations of cooperation and group cohesion, in Levin, Simon A.. (ed.), Games, Groups, and the Global Good, Heidelberg: SpringerGoogle Scholar
Frauenheim, Ed, 2005. Getting tough with China? CNET News.com: Tech News First, May 20, available on May 23, 2005 at http://news.com.com/Getting±tough±with±China/2100–1022–5714390.html?part=dtx&tag=ntop&tag=nl.e703
Plaza, Fresh, 2008. EU, Latin America look to WTO talks for banana deal, December 8, accessed March 9, 2009 from www.freshplaza.com/news_detail.asp?id=34605
Friedman, David, 1996. Hidden Order: The Economics of Everyday Life, New York: HarperBusinessGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton, 1962. Capitalism and Freedom, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 40th anniversary edition, republished in 2002Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Rose Friedman, , 1998. Two Lucky People, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Savage, L. J., 1948. The utility analysis of choices involving risk, Journal of Political Economy 56: 279–304CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furnham, A., 1993. Wasting time in the board room, Financial Times, March 10: 11Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth, 1967. The New Industrial State, Boston: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Gelbach, Jonah B., Klick, Jonathan, and Stratmann, Tyhomas, 2007. Cheap donuts and expensive broccoli: the effect of relative prices on obesity, Tallahassee, FL: College of Law, Florida State University, Research Law Paper no. 261, March 21, accessed August 27, 2009 from the Social Science Research Network, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=976484Google Scholar
Ghosn, Carlos, 2005. Shift: Inside Nissan's Historic Revival, New York: Doubleday, U.S. ednGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert and Murphy, Kevin J., 1992. Optimal incentive contracts in the presence of career concerns: theory and evidence, Journal of Political Economy 100(3): 468–506CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilder, George, 1989. Microcosm: The Quantum Revolution in Economics and Technology, New York: Simon and SchusterGoogle Scholar
Gintis, Herbert, 2000a. Game Theory Evolving, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Gintis, Herbert, 2000b. Strong reciprocity and human sociality, Journal of Theoretical Biology 211: 169–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Girion, Lisa, 2005. Obesity is costly to state, report says, Los Angeles Times, April 6: C1Google Scholar
Gladwell, Malcolm, 2000. The Tipping Point: How Little Things Can Make a Big Difference, Boston: Little, Brown & Co.Google Scholar
Gneezy, Uri and Rustichini, Aldo, 2000. A fine is a price, Journal of Legal Studies 29(1): 1–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Jonah, 2003. Bah Humbug: blame uninformed voters, Townhall.com, December 26, as available on October 5, 2004 at www.townhall.com/opinion/columns/jonahgoldberg/2003/12/26.1606/html
Goodman, John C. and Musgrave, Gerald L., 1992. Patient Power: Solving America's Health Care Crisis, Washington, DC: Cato InstituteGoogle Scholar
Goodman, John C., Musgrave, Gerald L., and Herrick, Devon M., 2004. Lives at Risk: Single-Payer Health Insurance around the World, Dallas: National Center for Policy Analysis, JulyGoogle Scholar
Gordon, H. Scott, 1954. The economic theory of a common property resource: the fishery, Journal of Political Economy 62(2): 124–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenhouse, Steven, 2005. Can't retail behemoth pay more?New York Times, May 4: C1Google Scholar
Greenspan, Alan. 2007. The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a New World, New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Greenville, Jared W. and MacAulay, T. G., 2004. Tariffs and steel: the U.S. safeguard actions, Sydney: Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Sydney, paper presented at the Annual Conference of the Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, Melbourne, February
Grinblatt, S. J. and Titman, S., 2002. Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy, Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill/IrwinGoogle Scholar
Gunderson, Morley, 1989. Male–female wage differentials and policy responses, Journal of Economic Literature 27(1): 46–72Google Scholar
Gurbaxani, Vijay and Whang, Seungjin, 1991. The impact of information systems on organizations and markets, Communication of the ACM 34(1): 59–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halberstam, David, 1986. The Reckoning, New York: Avon BooksGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Alexander, Jay, John and Madison, James, 1964. The Federalist: A Commentary on the Constitution of the United States, no. 51, New York: Random House, Modern Library ednGoogle Scholar
Hanke, Steve H. 2008. Testimony on rising food prices: budget challenges, before the Committee on the Budget, U.S. Congress, House of Representatives, July 30, as accessed on January 14, 2008, from http://web.jhu.edu/gcpa/government/federal/images/pdfs/Hanke_30–07-2008.pdf
Hansell, Saul, 2005. Wal-Mart ends online video rentals and promotes netflix, New York Times, May 20: C3Google Scholar
Hardin, Garrett, 1968. The tragedy of the commons, Science 62: 1243–54Google Scholar
Hare, A. Paul, 1952. A study of interaction and consensus in different-sized groups, American Sociological Review 17: 261–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hashimoto, Masanori, 1982. Minimum wage effects on training to the job, American Economic Review 70: 1070–87Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A., 1944. The Road to Serfdom, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A., 1945. The use of knowledge in society, American Economic Review 35(3): 519–30Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A., 1948. The meaning of competition, in Hayek, F., Individualism and Economic Order, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A., 1960. The Constitution of Liberty, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hayes, L., 1988. All eyes on DuPont's incentive program, Wall Street Journal, December 5: B1Google Scholar
Heller, Michael A., 1998. The tragedy of the anticommons: property in transition, Harvard Law Review 111: 621–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henderson, David R. 2009. A Nobel for practical economics, Wall Street Journal, October 13: A19Google Scholar
Henrich, Joseph, Boyd, Robert, Bowles, Samuel, Camerer, Colin, Fehr, Ernst, Gintis, Herbert, and McElreath, Richard, 2001. In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies, American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 91: 73–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herszenhorn, David M. 2009. Senate releases second portion of the bailout fund, New York Times, January 16: A1Google Scholar
Hesson, Robert, 1979. In Defense of the Corporation, Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution PressGoogle Scholar
Hewitt, Michael, 2004. Commissioners pass Dell plant incentives, Winston-Salem Journal, December 14, available on April 25, 2005 at www.journalnow.com/servlet/Satellite?pagename=WSJ%2FMGArticle%2FWSJ_BasicArticle&c=MGArticle&cid=1031779670184
Heyne, Paul, 1994. The Economic Way of Thinking, New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, Jerry, 2005. Is wholesale change in alcohol pricing on tap?Los Angeles Times, April 11: C1Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack, 1999. There are many pathways to cooperation, Journal of Bioeconomics 1: 73–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas, 1968. Leviathan, ed. Macpherson, C. B., Baltimore, MD: Penguin (first published in 1651)Google Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin A., and Smith, Vernon L., 1998. Behavioral foundations of reciprocity: experimental economics and evolutionary psychology, Economic Inquiry 36: 335–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt, 1979. Moral hazard and observability, Bell Journal of Economics 10: 74–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, Bengt and Kaplan, Stephen, 2001. Corporate governance and merger activity in the United States: making sense of the 1980s and 1990s, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(2): 121–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homans, George C., 1950. The Human Group, New York: Harcourt, Brace, Inc.Google Scholar
Horngren, C. T., 1999. Cost Accounting: A Managerial Emphasis, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Howard, Bion B. and Dietz, Peter O., 1969. A Study of the Financial Significance of Profit Sharing, Chicago: Council of Profit Sharing IndustriesGoogle Scholar
Hufbauer, Gary Clyde and Grieco, Paul L. E., 2005. The payoff from globalization, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, May, available on June 2, 2005 at www.iie.com/publications/papers/hufbauer0505.htm
Hufbauer, Gary Clydeet al., 1986. Trade Protection in the United States: 31 Case Studies, Washington, DC: Institute for International EconomicsGoogle Scholar
Husled, Mark, 1995. The impact of human resource management practices on turnover, productivity and corporate financial performance, Academy of Management Journal 38(2): 635–72Google Scholar
Ichniowski, Casey, Shaw, Kathryn, and Prennushi, Giovanna, 1996. The effects of human resource practices on productivity, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 5333Google Scholar
Ingrassia, Paul, 2005. Junk cars, Wall Street Journal, May 17: A12Google Scholar
James, John, 1951. A preliminary study of the size determinants in small-group interaction, American Sociological Review 16: 444–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarrell, Gregg A., James, A.Brickley, , and Jeffrey, M.Netter, , 1988. The market for corporate control: the empirical evidence since 1980, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2: 49–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarrell, Gregg A. and Annette, B. Paulsen, 1989. The returns to acquiring firms in tender offers: evidence from three decades, Financial Management 18: 12–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael, 1988. Takeovers: their causes and consequences, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(1): 21–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael, 1989. Eclipse of the public corporation, Harvard Business Review 67(5): 61–74Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael and Meckling, William H., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3: 325–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael and Meckling, William H., 1979. Property rights and production functions: an application of labor-managed firms and codetermination, Journal of Business 52: 469–506CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Michael and Ruback, Richard S., 1983. The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 11(5): 5–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, David L., 1974. An analysis of the costs and benefits for criminals in theft, St. Cloud, MN: Economics Department, St. Cloud State College, mimeo
Joskow, Paul, 1985. Vertical integration and long-term contracts: the case of coal-burning electric generating plants, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 1: 33–80Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Thaler, Richard H., and Knetsch, J., 1990. Experimental tests of the Endowment and the Coase Theorem, Journal of Political Economy 98(6): 1325–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalita, Mitra, 2009. Americans see 18% of their wealth vanish, Wall Street Journal, March 13: A1Google Scholar
Kant, Immauel, 1999 [1781]. Critique of Pure Reason, Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kanter, Rosebeth M., 1973. Commitment and Community: Communes and Utopias in Sociological Perspective, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, Karen, 2009. Calls to tax junk food gain ground. Los Angeles Times, August 23, accessed on September 15, 2009 from www.latimes.com/news/nationworld/nation/la-sci-junk-food-tax23–2009aug23,0,5244082.story
Karstensson, Lewis, 2003. The merchant and Mr. Reagan, American Journal of Economics and Sociology 62(3): 568–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keeling, R. F., Piper, S. C., Bollenbacher, A. F., and Walker, J. S., 2009. Atmospheric carbon dioxide record from Mauna Loa, La Jolla, CA: Carbon Dioxide Research Group, Scripps Institution of Oceanography, University of California, accessed February 9, 2009, from http://cdiac.ornl.gov/trends/co2/sio-mlo.html
Keller, John J., 1997. Best phone discounts go to hardest bargainers, Wall Street Journal, February 13: B1, B12Google Scholar
Kelly, Kevin, 1998. New Rules for the New Economy, New York: Viking/PenguinGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, New York: Harcourt Brace, republished in 1991Google Scholar
Kirzner, Israel, 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert, and Alchian, Armen, 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process, Journal of Law and Economics 21: 297–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin and Leffler, Keith B., 1981. The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance, Journal of Law and Economics 89(4): 615–41Google Scholar
Klein, Benjamin and Saft, Lester F., 1985. The law and economics of franchise tying contracts, Journal of Law and Economics 28: 345–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Joel I.et. al., 1998. Complaint, United States of America v. Microsoft Corporation, May 20, available on August 20, 2004 at www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases3/micros/1763.htm
Klein, Richard G., 2000. Archaeology and the evolution of human behavior, Evolutionary Anthropology 32: 391–428Google Scholar
Knauft, Bruce, 1991. Violence and and sociality in human evolution, Current Anthropology 32: 391–428CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Frank H., 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, republished in 1971Google Scholar
Koening, R., 1990. DuPont plan linking pay to fibers profit unravels, Wall Street Journal, October 25: B1Google Scholar
Kohn, Alfie, 1993a. Punished by Rewards, Boston, MA: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Kohn, Alfie, 1993b. Why incentive plans cannot work, Harvard Business Review, September–October: 54–63Google Scholar
Kosters, Marvin and Welch, Finis, 1972. The effects of minimum wages on the distribution of changes in aggregate employment, American Economic Review 62: 323–31Google Scholar
Krueger, Alan B., 2005. Economic scene: the farm-subsidy model of financing academia, New York Times, May 26: C2Google Scholar
Krueger, Ann O., 1974. The political economy of the rent-seeking society, American Economic Review 64: 291–303Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul, 2008. The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008, New York: W. W. NortonGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul, 2009. Out of the shadows, New York Times, June 19: A21Google Scholar
Laband, David N. and Lentz, Bernard F., 1990. Entrepreneurial success and occupational inheritance among proprietors, Canadian Journal of Economics 23(3): 101–17Google Scholar
Laband, David N. and Lentz, Bernard F., 1990. Strategic Pay: Aligning Organizational Strategies and Pay Systems, San Francisco: Jossey-BassGoogle Scholar
Labaton, Stephen, 2009. Tough enough: senior lawmakers have doubts on spreading the regulatory reach, New York Times, June 18: B1Google Scholar
Lawler, Edward E., 1968. Effects of hourly overpayment on productivity and work quality, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 10: 306–14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawler, Edward E., 1990. Strategic Pay: Aligning Organizational Strategies and Pay Systems, San Francisco: Jossey-BassGoogle Scholar
Lazear, Edward, 1979. Why is there mandatory retirement? Journal of Political Economy 87: 1261–84
Lawler, Edward E., 2000. Performance pay and productivity, American Economic Review 90: 1346–61Google Scholar
Lazear, Edward and Rosen, S., 1981. Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contract, Journal of Political Economy 89(3): 841–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lean, Geoffrey, 2007. Global warming “is three times faster than worst predictions,” The Independent, June 3, accessed on February 5, 2009 from www.independent.co.uk/environment/climate-change/global-warming-is-three-times-faster-than-worst-predictions-451529.html
Ledyard, John O., 1995. Public goods: a survey of experimental research, in Kager, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Lee, Dwight R., 1990. Why it pays to have tough profs, The Margin, September–October: 28–9Google Scholar
Lee, Dwight R. and Kreutzer, David, 1982. Lagged demand and a perverse response to threatened property rights, Economic Inquiry 20: 579–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Dwight R. and McKenzie, Richard B., 1998. How the client effect moderates price competition, Southern Economic Journal 64(3): 741–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Louis, 1996. Without a receipt you may get stuck with that ugly scarf, Wall Street Journal, November 18: A1Google Scholar
Lee, William G., 1994. The new corporate republics, Wall Street Journal, September 26: A12Google Scholar
Lehn, Kenneth and Annette, B.Paulsen, , 1987. Sources of value in leveraged buyouts, in Weidenbaum, Murray (ed.), Public Policy towards Corporate Takeovers, New Brunswick, NJ: TransactionGoogle Scholar
Leighton, Linda and Mincer, Jacob, 1981. Effects of minimum wages on human capital formation, in Rothenberg, Simon (ed.), The Economics of Legal Minimum Wages, Washington, DC: American Enterprise InstituteGoogle Scholar
Lessig, Lawrence, 2001. The Future of Ideas: The Fate of the Commons in a Connected World, New York: Random HouseGoogle Scholar
Levitt, Stephen D. and Stephen, J.Dubner, , 2005. Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything, New York: William Morrow, revised edition 2006Google Scholar
Lichter, Robert, Lichter, Linda, and Rothman, Stanley, 1990. Watching America, New York: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Liebowitz, Stan J. and Stephen, E.Margolis, , 1995. Path dependence, lock-in and history, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11(1): 205–26Google Scholar
Liebowitz, Stan J., and Stephen, E.Margolis, , 1999. Winners, Losers, and Microsoft: How Technology Markets Choose Products, Oakland, CA: Independent Institute (reprinted from Stan Liebowitz, J. and Stephen, E.Margolis, , The fable of the keys, Journal of Law and Economics 33 (1990): 1–25)Google Scholar
Lisser, Eleena, 1999. Windows shopping – one-click commerce: what people do now to goof off at work, Wall Street Journal, September 24: A1Google Scholar
Locke, John, 1690. The Second Treatise of Civil Government, as found on August 10, 2004 at http://oregonstate.edu/instruct/phl302/texts/locke/locke2/2nd-contents.html
,Los Angeles Times Wire Service, 2005. More goods from China face limits, Los Angeles Times, May 19: C3Google Scholar
Lott, Jr., John, R. and Russell, D. Roberts, , 1991. A guide to the pitfalls of identifying price discrimination, Economic Inquiry 29(1): 14–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ludwig, D. S., Peterson, K. E., and Gortmaker, S. L., 2001. Relation between consumption of sugar-sweetened drinks and childhood obesity: a prospective, observational analysis, Lancet 357: 505–8CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Luna, Nancy, 2005. Lack of late fee empties shelves, Orange County (CA) Register, February 18: business 1Google Scholar
Malatesta, Paul H. and Walkling, Ralph A., 1988. Poison pill securities: stockholder wealth, profitability, and ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics 20(1): 347–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mandelson, Peter, 2009. We need greater global governance, Wall Street Journal, June 19: A13Google Scholar
Mangum, G. L., 1962. Are wage incentives becoming obsolete?Industrial Relations 2: 73–96Google Scholar
Manne, Henry G., 1963. Mergers and the market for corporate control, Journal of Political Economy 73: 110–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marks, Mindy, 2004. Minimum wages and fringe benefits, Economics Department, St. Louis: Washington University, Working PaperGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Ray, 1974. Economics of racial discrimination, Journal of Economic Literature 12: 849–71Google Scholar
Marwell, Gerald and Ames, Ruth, 1981. Economists free ride, does anyone else?Journal of Public Economics 15: 295–310CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maslow, A. H., 1954. Motivation and Personality, New York: Harper and RowGoogle Scholar
Mathewson, G. Frank and Winter, Ralph A., 1985. The economics of franchise contracts, Journal of Law and Economics 28: 503–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, K. and Smith, V. L., 1999. A comparison of naive and sophisticated subject behavior with game theoretic predictions, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA 97: 3777–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McChesney, Fred S., 1997. Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction and Political Extortion, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
McConnell, John J. and Muscarella, Chris J., 1985. Capital expenditure decisions and market value of the firm, Journal of Financial Economics 14: 399–422CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCormack, Richard, 2008. U.S. container exports still dominated by junk – scrap paper, scrap metal and bulk commodities, Manufacturing and Technology News, July 31, 15(14), as accessed March 25, 2009 from www.manufacturingnews.com/news/08/0731/PIERS.html
McKenzie, Richard B., 1977. Political ignorance: an empirical assessment of educational remedies, in Gordon Tullock (ed.), Frontiers of Economics, Blacksburg, VA: University PublicationsGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B., 1987. The loss of textile and apparel jobs: the relative importance of imports and productivity, Cato Journal, winter: 731–46
McKenzie, Richard B., 1994. Times Change: The Minimum Wage and the New York Times, San Francisco: Pacific Research InstituteGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B., 1996. In defense of academic tenure, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 152(2): 325–41
McKenzie, Richard B., 1997. The Paradox of Progress, New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B., 2000. Trust on Trial: How the Microsoft Case Is Transforming the Rules of Competition, Boston, MA: PerseusGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B., 2008. Why Popcorn Costs So Much at the Movies, and Other Pricing Puzzles, Heidelberg: Springer/CopernicusGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B., 2010. Predictably Rational? In Search of Defenses of Rational Behavior in Economics, Heidelberg: SpringerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B. and Galar, Roman, 2004. The importance of deviance in intellectual development, American Journal of Economics and Sociology 63(1): 19–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B. and Dwight, R. Lee, 1991. Quicksilver Capital: How the Rapid Movement of Wealth Has Changed the World, New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B., and Lee, Dwight R., 1992. A reexamination of the relative efficiency of the draft and the all-volunteer army, Southern Economic Journal 58 (January): 644–54Google Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B., 2008. In Defense of Monopoly: How Market Power Fosters Creative Production, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B. and Sullivan, Thomas, 1987. The NCAA as a cartel: an economic and legal reinterpretation, Antitrust Bulletin 3: 373–99Google Scholar
McKenzie, Richard B. and Tullock, Gordon, 1994. The New World of Economics, New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John, 2002. Reinventing the Bazaar: The Natural History of Markets, New York: W. W. NortonGoogle Scholar
Metzger, Bertram L., 1975. Profit Sharing in 38 Large Companies, I & II, Evanston, IL: Profit Sharing Research FoundationGoogle Scholar
Meyer, Stephen, 1981. The Five-Dollar Day: Labor, Management, and Social Control in the Ford Motor Company, 1908–1921, Albany, NY: State University of New York PressGoogle Scholar
Micklethwait, John and Wooldridge, Adrian, 2003. The Company: A Short History of a Revolutionary Idea, New York: The Modern LibraryGoogle Scholar
Mikkelson, Wayne H. and Richard, S. Ruback, 1985. An empirical analysis of the interfirm equity investment process, Journal of Financial Economics 14: 523–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John, 1992. Economics, Organization and Management, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Miller, Gary J., 1992. Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy, New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Scott, 2005. WTO urges caution on textile limits, Wall Street Journal, April 25: A2Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig, 1962. The Ultimate Foundations of Economic Science: An Essay on Method, Princeton, NJ: D. Van NostrandGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, Mark L. and Lehn, Kenneth, 1990. Do bad bidders become good targets?Journal of Political Economy 98(2): 372–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, R., 1994. Managing by values, Business Week, August 1
Moore, Gordon E., 1994. The accidental entrepreneur, Engineering & Science 62(4): 23–30Google Scholar
Muñoz, Lorenza, 2005. Blockbuster settles state probes into late-fee ads, Los Angeles Times, March 30: C1
Murphy, Robert P., 2009. The economics of climate change, The Library of Liberty, July 6, 2009, as accessed July 6, 2009 from www.econlib.org/library/Columns/y2009/Murphyclimate.html#note_1
Nalbantian, Haig R. and Schotter, Andrew, 1997. Productivity under group incentives: an experimental study, American Economic Review 87(3): 314–41Google Scholar
Nasar, Sylvia, 1998. A Beautiful Mind, New York: Simon and SchusterGoogle Scholar
,National Center for Health Statistics, 2009. Health, United States, 2008, with Chart Cook on Trends in the Health of Americans, Hyattsville, MD: U.S. Government Printing Office, accessed August 6, 2009 from www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/hus/hus08.pdf
,National Center for Policy Analysis, 1994. Answering the critics of medical savings accounts, Brief Analysis, Dallas, TX: National Center for Policy Analysis, September 16Google Scholar
,National Heart, Lung, and Blood Institute, 1998. Clinical Guidelines on the Identification, Evaluation, and Treatment of Overweight and Obesity in Adults: The Evidence Report. Bethesda, MD: National Heart, Lung, and Blood InstituteGoogle Scholar
Navarro, Peter, 2008. The Coming China Wars: Where They Will Be Fought and How They Can Be Won, Revised and Expanded Edition, rev. edn, Upper Saddle River, NJ: FT PressGoogle Scholar
Neumann, W. R., 1986. The Paradox of Mass Politics, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Neumark, David and Wascher, William L., 2008. Minimum Wages, Cambridge, MA: MIT PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
New York Times, 2005. Lenovo of China completes purchase of IBM's PC unit, May 5: C5
Nishiguchi, Toshihiro, 1994. Strategic Industrial Sourcing: The Japanese Advantage, New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Nishiguchi, Toshihiro and Masayoshi, Ikeda, 1996. Suppliers' process innovation: understated aspects of Japanese industrial sourcing, in Nishiguchi, Toshihiro (ed.), Managing Product Development, New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Norberg, Johan, 2009. Financial Fiasco: How America's Infatuation with Home Ownership and Easy Money Created the Economic Crisis, Washington, DC: Cato InstituteGoogle Scholar
Obama, Barack, 2009. Barack Obama: 21st century regulatory reform, FT.com, as accessed on June 18, 2009 at www.ft.com/cms/s/0/12b0b48a-5b54–11de-be3f-00144feabdc0.html
Olson, Mancur, 1971. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor, 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor, 2000. Collective action and the evolution of social norms, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 137–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oyer, Paul, 1998. Fiscal year ends and nonlinear incentive contracts: the effect on business seasonality, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113: 149–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paletta, Damian, 2009. Historic overhaul of finance rules, Wall Street Journal, June 18: A1
Parsky, Gerald (commission chair), 2009. Commission on the 21st Century [California] Economy, Sacramento, CA: Governor's Office, State of California, September, accessed on September 30, 2009 from www.cotce.ca.gov/documents/reports/documents/Commission_on_the_21st_Century_Economy-Final_Report.pdf
Pearce, Jone L., 1987. Why merit pay doesn't work: implications for organization theory, in Balkin, D. B. and Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (eds.), New Perspectives in Compensation, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice HallGoogle Scholar
Peers, Martin, 2005. At Blockbuster, new strategies raise tensions over board seats, The Weekly Review (Wall Street Journal), April 18, as found on April 22, 2005 at http://online.wsj.com/article_print/0, SB111378718174309203,00.html
Peers, Martin and Zimmerman, Ann, 2005. Dissident Icahn wins board seats at Blockbuster, Wall Street Journal, May 12: A1Google Scholar
Pencavel, J. H., 1977. Work effort, on the job screening, and alternative methods of remuneration, Research in Labor Economics, 225–59Google Scholar
Peters, Mark, 2009. U.S. plays catch-up in efficiency credits, Wall Street Journal, April 13: C4Google Scholar
Peters, Thomas J., 1994. Tom Peters Seminar: Crazy Times Call for Crazy Organizations, New York: Vintage BooksGoogle Scholar
Petersen, Tron, 1991. Reward systems and the distribution of wages, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organizations 7 (special issue): 130–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, John M. and Stewart, Charles T., 1969. Employment Effects of Minimum Wage Rates, Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy ResearchGoogle Scholar
,Pew Research Center Survey, 2004. Roper Center, Accession no. 0448774, February 4–16
Poole, Robert, 2008. Stimulus shouldn't be an excuse for pork, Wall Street Journal, December 10: A18Google Scholar
Porter, Lyman W. and Lawyer, E. E., 1965. Properties of organization structure in relation to job attitudes and job behavior, Psychological Bulletin 77: 23–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A., 1974. Theories of economic regulation, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 5(2): 335–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A., 2009a. Capitalism in crisis, Wall Street Journal, May 7: A17Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A., 2009b. A Failure of Capitalism: The Crisis of '08 and the Descent into Depression, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Prestowitz, Jr., Clyde, V., 1988. Trading Places: How We Allowed Japan to Take the Lead, New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Price, Daniel M., 2009. Free trade, green trade, Wall Street Journal, May 6: A23Google Scholar
,Princeton Survey Research Associates, 2004. Roper Center, Accession no. 0454615, April 15
Radford, R. A., 1945. The economic organization of a POW camp, Economica 12: 189–201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radia, Ryan, 2009. European officials target Microsoft over Internet Explorer, Press Release, Washington, DC: Competitive Enterprise Institute, as accessed January 20, 2009 at http://cei.org/node/21524
Ragan, James F., 1977. Minimum wages and the youth labor market, Review of Economics and Statistics 59: 129–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raupach, Michael R., Gregg, Marland, Ciais, Philippe, Canadell, Corinne Le Quéré, Josep G., Klepper, Gernot, and Field, Christopher B., 2007. Global and regional drivers of accelerating CO2 emissions, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, accessed on February 5, 2009 from www.pnas.org/content/104/24/10288
Read, Leonard E., 1983. I, pencil, The Freeman, November (originally published in The Freeman in 1958), available on July 19, 2004 at www.fee.org/vnews.php?nid=1321
Reuters, 2009. Barack Obama, Greta Garbo and China's trade surplus, January 19, 2009, accessed on January 28, 2009, at www.reuters.com/article/reutersEdge/idUSTRE50I12O20090119
Richman, Sheldon, 1981. The rape of Poletown, Inquiry, August 3: 24
Rivoli, Pietra, 2006. The Travels of a T-Shirt in the Global Economy: An Economist Examines the Markets, Power, and Politics of World Trade, New York: WileyGoogle Scholar
Roberts, John, 2004. The Modern Firm: Organizational Design for Performance and Growth, New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Robins, James A., 1996. Why and when does agency theory matter? A critical approach to the role of agency theory in the analysis of organizational control, Irvine, CA: Graduate School of Management, University of California, Irvine, Working Paper
Rogers, John, 2008. Despite home upgrades, Gore still “hypocrite” on energy use, group says, The City (Nashville) Paper, June 18, accessed on February 6, 2009 from www.nashvillecitypaper.com/news.php?viewStory=60895
Rosenthal, Mathew, 2009. India rejects U.S. proposal of carbon limits, Wall Street Journal, July 20: A7Google Scholar
Rothbard, Murray, 1977. America's Great Depression. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises InstituteGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul H., 1978. The theory of the firm and the structure of the franchise contract, Journal of Law and Economics 21(1): 223–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul H., 1990. Managing Business Transactions: Controlling the Costs of Coordination, Communication, and Decision Making, New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Rubin, Paul H., 2002. Darwinian Politics: The Evolutionary Origin of Freedom, New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University PressGoogle Scholar
Rush, Rebecca, 2005. Chiquita's threat to the Caribbean Islands: the new banana wars, CounterPunch, March 26, accessed on March 9, 2009 from www.counterpunch.org/rush05262005.html
Ryngaert, Michael and Netter, Jeffry, 1988. Shareholder wealth effects of the Ohio antitakeover law, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4: 373–83Google Scholar
Schiller, Robert J., 2008 The Subprime Solution: How Today's Global Financial Crisis Happened and What to Do about It, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Scott, Anthony, 1955. The fishery: the objective of sole ownership, Journal of Political Economy 63: 116–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seiler, Eric, 1984. Piece-rate vs. time-rate: the effect of incentives on earnings, Review of Economics and Statistics 66(3): 363–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sethi, Rajiv and Somanathan, E., 1996. The evolution of social norms in common property resource use, American Economic Review 86: 766–88Google Scholar
Shapiro, Carl and Stiglitz, Joseph, 1984. Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device, American Economic Review 74(3): 433–44Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven, 1979. Risk sharing and incentives in the principal and agent relationship, Bell Journal of Economics 10(1): 55–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepherd, William G., 1984. Contestability vs. competition, American Economic Review 74: 572–87Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert J., 2005. Irrational Exuberance, 2nd edn, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert, 1951. A formal theory of employment relationship, Econometrica 19: 293–305CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Stephanie, 2009. More states considering tax breaks to woo jobs, Wall Street Journal, February 2: A1Google Scholar
Smith, Adam, 1937. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, New York: Modern LibraryGoogle Scholar
Smith, C. and Watts, R., 1982. Incentive and tax effects of executive compensation plans, Australian Journal of Management 7: 139–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L., 1962. An experimental study of competitive market behavior, Journal of Political Economy 70: 111–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soloman, Deborah and Paletta, Damian, 2009. U.S. seeks rest of the bailout cash, Wall Street Journal, January 13: A1.Google Scholar
Solomon, , Susan, Gian-Kasper Plattner, Knutti, Reto, and Friedlingstein, Pierre, 2009. Irreversible climate change due to carbon dioxide emissions, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 106 (6, February 10): 1704–9, accessed February 5, 2009 from www.pnas.org/content/early/2009/01/28/0812721106.full.pdf+html
Somin, Ilya, 2003. Voter knowledge and constitutional change: the new deal experience, William and Mary Law Review 45: 595–615Google Scholar
Sowell, Thomas, 2009. The Housing Boom and Bust, New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Spencer, Herbert, 1896. Principles of Sociology, London: Williams and NorgateGoogle Scholar
Stecklow, Steve, 1994. Evangelical schools reinvent themselves by stressing academics, Wall Street Journal, May 12: A1Google Scholar
Steiner, Mary C., Munro, Natalie D., Surovell, Todd A., Tchernov, Eitan, and Bar-Yosef, Ofer, 1998. Paleolithic population growth pulses evidenced by small animal exploitation, Science, September 25, available at www.science mag.org, accessed December 19, 2004
Stephenson, Frederick J. and Fox, Richard J., 1992. Corporate strategies for frequent-flier programs, Transportation Journal 32(1): 38–50Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., 1971. The theory of economic regulation, Bell Journal of Economics 2(1): 3–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., 2009. Obama's ersatz capitalism, New York Times, April 1: A25Google Scholar
Stokes, Donald E. and Miller, Warren E., 1962. Party government and the saliency of congress, Public Opinion Quarterly 26: 531–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stout, David, 2009. Senators skeptical of plan on financial regulation, New York Times, June 19: B1Google Scholar
Talley, Ian and Bartley, Thomas, 2009. Energy chief says U.S. open to carbon tariff, Wall Street Journal, March 18, accessed July 20, 2009 from http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123733297926563315.html
Taylor, Frederick W., 1895. A piece rate system, American Society of Mechanical Engineers Transactions 16: 856–93Google Scholar
Tellis, Gerald and Golder, Peter, 2002. Will and Vision: How Late Comers Grow To Dominate Markets, New York: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Thaler, Richard H., 1992. The Winner's Curse: Paradoxes and Anomalies of Economic Life, New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Thaler, Richard H., 2000. Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice, as reprinted in Quasi Rational Economics, New York: Russell Sage Foundation: 3–24Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. and Sunstein, Cass R., 2008. Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Thomas, Paulette, 1996. Work week: teams rule, Wall Street Journal, May 28: A1Google Scholar
Thompson, Donald N., 1971. Franchise Operations and Antitrust, Lexington, MA: D. C. HeathGoogle Scholar
Tichy, Noel M. and Sherman, Stratford, 1993. Jack Welch's lessons for success, Fortune, January 25: 86–93Google Scholar
Trivers, Robert L., 1971. The evolution of reciprocal altruism, Quarterly Review of Biology 46: 35–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tucker, William, 1997. How rent control drives out affordable housing, Policy Analysis 274 (May 21), Washington, DC: Cato Institute, available on August 17, 2004 at www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-274es.htmlGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, 1967. The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft, Western Economic Journal 5: 224–32Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, 1972. Toward a Mathematics of Politics, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Uchitelle, Louis and Andrews, Edmund L., 2009. Economy slides at fastest rate since late 1950s, New York Times, April 30: A1Google Scholar
,US Department of Labor, 1993. High Performance Work Practices and Firm Performance, Washington, DC: Bureau of National AffairsGoogle Scholar
,US Department of State, 2002. Projected Greenhouse Gases, Washington, DC: May, as accessed May 24, 2009 from www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/1605/archive/gg02rpt/gasfig1.html
Veblen, Thorstein, 1902. The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions, New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Wagner, John L., Rubin, Paul A., and Callahan, Thomas J., 1988. Incentive payment and non-managerial productivity: an interrupted time series analysis of magnitude and trend, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 42(1): 47–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Marcus, 2009. Record GDP drop sharpens pain across euro zone, Wall Street Journal, May 16: A5Google Scholar
Wall Street Journal, 1975. Less regulation of airline sector is urged by Ford, October 9: A3
Wall Street Journal, 2009. A California quake (editorial), September 30: A22
Wallison, Peter J., 2009. Too big to fail, or succeed, Wall Street Journal, June 18: A17Google Scholar
Warren-Bolton, Frederick R., n.d. Direct testimony, State of New York ex rel. Attorney-General Dennis C. Vacco, et al. v. Microsoft Corporation, Civil Action No. 98–1233 (TPJ), p. 21, available on August 20, 2004 at www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f2000/2079.htm
Washington Post, 2005. U.S. can consider textile-import limit, April 28: E2
Wauzzinski, Robert A., 2003. The Transforming Story of Dwelling House Savings and Loan: A Pittsburgh Bank's Fight against Urban Poverty, Lewiston, NY: Edwin MellenGoogle Scholar
Weisman, Martin L. and Kruse, Douglas L., 1990. Profit sharing and productivity, in Blinder, Alan S. (ed.), Paying for Productivity: A Look at the Evidence, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution: 95–140Google Scholar
Wessels, Walter J., 1987. Minimum wages: are workers really better off? Paper prepared for presentation at a conference on minimum wages, Washington, DC, National Chamber Foundation, July 29
White, Erin, 2005. To keep employees, Domino's decides it's not all about pay, Wall Street Journal, February 17: A1Google Scholar
White, Harrison C., 1991. Agency as control, in Pratt, John W. and Zeckhauser, Richard J. (eds.), Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press: 187–212Google Scholar
White, Lawrence J., 2002. International trade in services: more than meets the eye, New York: Stern School of Business, Working Paper, February 28, available on May 10, 2005 at www.stern.nyu.edu/eco/wkpapers/workingpapers02/02-13 White.pdfGoogle Scholar
White, Lawrence J., 2008. How Did We Get into This Financial Mess? Washington, DC: Cato Institute, no. 110, November 18, as accessed January 14, 2009 from www.cato.org/pubs/bp/bp110.pdf
Whitehouse, Mark, 2009. Imbalance in nation's savings clouds forecasts of recovery, Wall Street Journal, March 23: A2Google Scholar
Williams, Nicole, 2007. Al Gore's personal energy use is his own “Inconvenient Truth”: Gore's home uses more than 20 times the national average, Nashville, TN: Tennessee Center for Policy Research, accessed February 6, 2009 from www.tennesseepolicy.org/main/article.php?article_id=367
Williams, Walter, 2005. Minimum wage, maximum folly, Capitalism Magazine, March 23, as available on August 20, 2005 at www.capmag.com/article.asp? id4173
Williamson, Oliver E., 1967. Hierarchical control and optimum size firms, Journal of Political Economy 75(2): 123–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., 1990. Economic Organization, New York: New York University PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., 1998. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Wilson, James Q., 1993. The Moral Sense, New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Wingfield, Nick and Clarke, Don, 2009. Microsoft gambles on Windows 7 “Starter,”Wall Street Journal, April 20: B1Google Scholar
Wirthman, Lisa, 1997. Superior snooping: new software can catch workers goofing off, but some say such surveillance goes too far, Orange County (Calif.) Register, July 20: 1, 10Google Scholar
Withers, Lanita, 2008. Officials break ground for FedEx hub, Greensboro News and Record, November 21, accessed February 5 from www.news-record.com/content/2008/11/21/article/officials_break_ground_for_fedex_hub
,WorldNetDaly.com, 2007. Gore's “carbon offsets” paid to firm he owns: critics say justification for energy-rich lifestyle serves as way for former VP to profit, accessed February 6, 2009, from www.worldnetdaily.com/news/article.asp?ARTICLE_ID=54528
Wortham, Jenna, 2009. Doing good with unused gift cards, New York Times, August 24: B7Google Scholar
Wriston, Walter B., 1989. On track with the deficit, Wall Street Journal, January 6: A1Google Scholar
Young, Wesley, Graff, Laura, and Romoser, James, 2009. The price of Dell, Winston-Salem Journal, March 13: A1Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Richard B. McKenzie, University of California, Irvine, Dwight R. Lee, University of Georgia
  • Book: Microeconomics for MBAs
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511761140.018
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Richard B. McKenzie, University of California, Irvine, Dwight R. Lee, University of Georgia
  • Book: Microeconomics for MBAs
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511761140.018
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Richard B. McKenzie, University of California, Irvine, Dwight R. Lee, University of Georgia
  • Book: Microeconomics for MBAs
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511761140.018
Available formats
×