Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wg55d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-29T06:13:32.287Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Manuel Becerra
Affiliation:
Instituto de Empresa, Madrid
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Theory of the Firm for Strategic Management
Economic Value Analysis
, pp. 272 - 292
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adler, M. D., and Posner, E. A. (2001). Cost-benefit Analysis: Legal, Economic, and Philosophical Perspectives. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Agarwal, S., and Ramaswami, S. N. (1992). “Choice of Foreign Market Entry Mode: Impact of Ownership, Location and Internalization Factors.” Journal of International Business Studies, 23(1), 1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aguilera, R. V., Rupp, D. E., Williams, C. A., and Ganapathi, J. (2007). “Putting the S Back in Corporate Social Responsibility: a Multilevel Theory of Social Change in Organizations.” The Academy of Management Review, 32(3), 836–863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. (1970). “The Market for Lemons: Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, A., and Demsetz, H. (1972). “Production, Information and Economic Organization.” American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–795.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A. (1965). “The Basis of Some Recent Advances in the Theory of Management of the Firm.” The Journal of Industrial Economics, 14(1), 30–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aliber, R. Z. (1970). “A Theory of Foreign Direct Investment.” The International Corporation, 17–34.Google Scholar
Alvarez, S. A., and Busenitz, L. W. (2001). “The Entrepreneurship of Resource-Based Theory.” Journal of Management, 27(6), 755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amabile, T. M. (1983). The Social Psychology of Creativity. New York: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amihud, Y., and Lev, B. (1981). “Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers.” The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), 605–617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amit, R., and Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1993). “Strategic Assets and Organizational Rent.” Strategic Management Journal, 14(1), 33–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, C. R., and Zeithaml, C. P. (1984). “Stage of the Product Life Cycle, Business Strategy, and Business Performance.” The Academy of Management Journal, 27(1), 5–24.Google Scholar
Anderson, J. C., and Narus, J. A. (1998). “Understand What Customers Value.” Harvard Business Review, 53–65.Google ScholarPubMed
Andrews, K. R. (1987 [1971]). The Concept of Corporate Strategy. Homewood, Ill.: Dow Jones-Irwin.Google Scholar
Ansoff, H. I. (1965). Corporate Strategy. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1974). The Limits of Organization. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J., and Debreu, G. (1954). “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy.” Econometrica, 22(3), 265–290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984). The Evolution of Corporation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Baiman, S. (1982). “Agency Research in Managerial Accounting: A Survey.” Journal of Accounting Literature, 1(1), 154–210.Google Scholar
Bain, J. S. (1956). Barriers to New Competition. Boston: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bamford, J. D., Gomes-Casseres, B., and Robinson, M. S. (2003). Mastering Alliance Strategy. San Francisco, Calif.: Jossey-Bass.Google Scholar
Barnard, C. I. (1938). The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Barney, J. B. (1986). “Strategic Factor Markets.” Management Science, 32(10), 1231–1241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. B. (1990). “The Debate between Traditional Management Theory and Organizational Economics: Substantive Differences or Intergroup Conflict?The Academy of Management Review, 15(3), 382–393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. B. (1991). “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage.” Journal of Management, 17(1), 99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. B. (1997). Gaining and Sustaining Competitive Advantage. Harlow: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Barney, J. B. (2001). “Is the Resource-Based View a Useful Perspective for Strategic Management Research? Yes.” The Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 41–56.Google Scholar
Barney, J. B., and Arikan, A. M. (2001). “The Resource-Based View: Origins and Implications.” In Hitt, M. A., Freeman, R. E. and Harrison, J. S. (Eds.), Handbook of Strategic Management (124–188): Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Baron, D. P. (2006). Business and Its Environment. Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Pearson Education.Google Scholar
Baron, R. A., and Shane, S. A. (2008). Entrepreneurship: A Process Perspective. Mason, Ohio: South-Western.Google Scholar
Bartlett, C. A., and Ghoshal, S. (1989). Managing Across Borders. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J., Panzar, J. C., and Willig, R. D. (1982). Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure. London: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Beath, J., and Katsoulacos, Y. S. (1991). The Economic Theory of Product Differentiation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becerra, M., and Santalo, J. (2003). “An Empirical Analysis of the Corporate Effect: The Impact of the Multinational Corporation on the Performance of its Units Worldwide.” Management International Review, 43, 7–23.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1976). “Altruism, Egoism, and Genetic Fitness: Economics and Sociobiology.” Journal of Economic Literature, 14(3), 817–826.Google Scholar
Benito, G. R. G., and Gripsrud, G. (1992). “The Expansion of Foreign Direct Investments: Discrete Rational Location Choices or a Cultural Learning Process?Journal of International Business Studies, 23(3).Google Scholar
Berger, P. G., and Ofek, E. (1995). “Diversification's Effect on Firm Value.” Journal of Financial Economics, 37(1), 39–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berle, A., and Means, G. C. (1933). The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Besanko, D., Dranove, D., Shanley, M., and Schaefer, S. (2004). Economics of Strategy. Hoboken, N.J.: Wiley.Google Scholar
Bettis, R. A., and Hall, W. K. (1982). “Diversification Strategy, Accounting Determined Risk, and Accounting Determined Return.” The Academy of Management Journal, 25(2), 254–264.Google Scholar
Bower, J. L, Bartlett, C. A., Christensen, C. R., Pearson, A. E., and Andrews, K. R. (1991). Business Policy. (Seventh edition). Homewood, Ill.: Richard Irwin.Google Scholar
Bowman, C., and Ambrosini, V. (2000). “Value Creation versus Value Capture: Towards a Coherent Definition of Value in Strategy.” British Journal of Management, 11(1), 1–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowman, E. H., and Helfat, C. E. (2001). “Does Corporate Strategy Matter?Strategic Management Journal, 22(1), 1–23.3.0.CO;2-T>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandenburger, A., and Nalebuff, B. J. (1996). Co-Opetition. New York; London: Currency Doubleday.Google Scholar
Brandenburger, A., and Stuart, H. (1996). “Value-Based Business Strategy.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 5, 5–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brouthers, K. D., and Hennart, J. F. (2007). “Boundaries of the Firm: Insights from International Entry Mode Research.” Journal of Management, 33(3), 395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, S. L., and Eisenhardt, K. M. (1995). “Product Development: Past Research, Present Findings, and Future Directions.” The Academy of Management Review, 20(2), 343–378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckley, P. J., and Casson, M. (1976). The Future of the Multinational Enterprise. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burke, L., and Logsdon, J. M. (1996). “How Corporate Social Responsibility Pays Off.” Long Range Planning, 29(4), 495–502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, T. B., and Stalker, G. M. (1961). The Management of Innovation. London: Tavistock Publications.Google Scholar
Busenitz, L. W., and Barney, J. B. (1997). “Differences between Entrepreneurs and Managers in Large Organizations: Biases and Heuristics in Strategic Decision-Making.” Journal of Business Venturing, 12(1), 9–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calori, R., and Ardisson, J. M. (1988). “Differentiation Strategies in ‘Stalemate Industries'.” Strategic Management Journal, 9(3), 255–269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. (1991). “Does Strategy Research Need Game Theory?Strategic Management Journal, 12, 137–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campa, J. M., and Kedia, S. (2002). “Explaining the Diversification Discount.” The Journal of Finance, 57(4), 1731–1762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, A., Goold, M., and Alexander, M. (1995). “Corporate Strategy: The Quest for Parenting Advantage.” Harvard Business Review, 73(2), 123.Google Scholar
Campbell-Hunt, C. (2000). “What have we Learned about Generic Competitive Strategy? A Meta-Analysis.” Strategic Management Journal, 21(2), 127–154.3.0.CO;2-1>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, A. B. (1979). “A Three-dimensional Conceptual Model of Corporate Performance.” The Academy of Management Review, 4(4), 497–505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, G. R. (1993). “A Sociological View on Why Firms Differ.” Strategic Management Journal, 14(4), 237–249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caves, R. E. (1974). International Trade, International Investment, and Imperfect Markets. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Caves, R. E. (1982). Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Caves, R. E., and Porter, M. E. (1977). “From Entry Barriers to Mobility Barriers: Conjectural Decisions and Contrived Deterrence to New Competition.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91(2), 241–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caves, R. E., and Williamson, P. J. (1985). “What Is Product Differentiation, Really?The Journal of Industrial Economics, 34(2), 113–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamberlin, E. (1933). The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chandler, A. D. (1962). Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Chatterjee, S. (1986). “Types of Synergy and Economic Value: the Impact of Acquisitions on Merging and Rival Firms.” Strategic Management Journal, 7(2), 119–139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chatterjee, S., and Wernerfelt, B. (1991). “The Link between Resources and Type of Diversification: Theory and Evidence.” Strategic Management Journal, 12(1), 33–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, M. J., and Miller, D. (1994). “Competitive Attack, Retaliation and Performance: an Expectancy–Valence Framework.” Strategic Management Journal, 15(2), 85–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheung, S. N. S. (1998). “Presidential Address.” Economic Inquiry, 36, 514–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Child, J. (1972). “Organizational Structure, Environment and Performance: The Role of Strategic Choice.”Sociology, 6(1), 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiles, T. H., and McMackin, J. F. (1996). “Integrating Variable Risk Preferences, Trust, and Transaction Cost Economics.” The Academy of Management Review, 21(1), 73–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen, C. R., Andrews, K. R., Bower, J. L., and Learned, E. P. (1978). Business Policy: Text and Cases. Homewood, Ill.: R. D. Irwin.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937). “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica, 4(New series) 386–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960). “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1).Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1988). “The Nature of the Firm: Origin, Meaning, Influence.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4(1), 3–47.Google Scholar
Coff, R. W. (1999). “When Competitive Advantage Doesn't Lead to Performance: the Resource-Based View and Stakeholder Bargaining Power.” Organization Science, 10(2), 119–133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, W. M., and Levinthal, D. A. (1990). “Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1).Google Scholar
Collis, D. J. (1994). “Research Note: How Valuable are Organizational Capabilities?Strategic Management Journal, 15, 143–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collis, D. J., and Montgomery, C. A. (1998). Corporate Strategy: A Resource-Based Approach. Boston, Mass.: Irwin.Google Scholar
Conner, K., and Prahalad, C. K. (1996). “A Resource Based View of the Firm: Knowledge Versus Opportunism.” Organization Science, 7(5), 407–501.Google Scholar
Conner, K. (1991). “A Historical Comparison of Resource-Based Theory and Five Schools of Thought within Industrial Organization Economics: Do we Have a New Theory of the Firm?Journal of Management, 17(1), 121.Google Scholar
Copeland, T. E., Koller, T., and Murrin, J. (1990). Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Cottrell, T., and Nault, B. R. (2004). “Product Variety and Firm Survival in the Microcomputer Software Industry.” Strategic Management Journal, 25(10), 1005–1025.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cubbin, J., and Geroski, P. (1987). “The Convergence of Profits in the Long Run: Inter-firm and Inter-industry Comparisons.” The Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 427–442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cyert, R. M., and March, J. G. (1992 [1963]). Behavioral Theory of the Firm (Second edition). Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
d'Aspremont, C., Gabszewicz, J. J., and Thisse, J. F. (1979). “On Hotelling's Stability in Competition.” Econometrica, 47(5), 1145–1150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damanpour, F. (1991). “Organizational Innovation: a Meta-Analysis of Effects of Determinants and Moderators.” The Academy of Management Journal, 34(3), 555–590.Google Scholar
Das, T. K., and Teng, B. S. (2000). “A Resource-Based Theory of Strategic Alliances.” Journal of Management, 26(1), 31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Datta, D. K., Pinches, G. E., and Narayanan, V. K. (1992). “Factors Influencing Wealth Creation from Mergers and Acquisitions: a Meta-Analysis.” Strategic Management Journal, 13(1), 67–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, G. S., Shocker, A. D., and Srivastava, R. K. (1979). “Customer-oriented Approaches to Identifying Product–Markets.” Journal of Marketing, 43(4), 8–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vasconcellos, J. A. S., and Hambrick, D. C. (1989). “Key Success Factors: Test of a General Theory in the Mature Industrial–Product Sector.” Strategic Management Journal, 10(4), 367–382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deephouse, D. L. (1999). “To be Different, or to be the Same? It's a Question (and Theory) of Strategic Balance.” Strategic Management Journal, 20(2), 147–166.3.0.CO;2-Q>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, H. (1967). “Toward a Theory of Property Rights.” The American Economic Review, 57(2), 347–359.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. (1982). “Barriers to Entry.” American Economic Review, 72(1), 47–57.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. (1988). “The Theory of the Firm Revisited.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 4, 141–161.Google Scholar
DeSarbo, W. S., Jedidi, K., and Sinha, I. (2001). “Customer Value Analysis in a Heterogeneous Market.” Strategic Management Journal, 22(9), 845–857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dess, G. G., and Davis, P. S. (1984). “Porter's (1980) Generic Strategies as Determinants of Strategic Group Membership and Organizational Performance.” The Academy of Management Journal, 27(3), 467–488.Google Scholar
Dickson, P. R., and Ginter, J. L. (1987). “Market Segmentation, Product Differentiation, and Marketing Strategy.” Journal of Marketing, 51(2), 1–10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dierickx, I., and Cool, K. (1989). “Asset Stock Accumulation and Sustainability of Competitive Advantage.” Management Science, 35(12), 1504–1513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, P., and Powell, W. (1983). “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Cost Explanation.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 4, 305–336.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. K., and Nalebuff, B. J. (1991). Thinking Strategically. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. K., and Stiglitz, J. E. (1977). “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity.” The American Economic Review, 67(3), 297–308.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. (1973). Theories of Value and Distribution since Adam Smith: Ideology and Economic Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donaldson, L. (1990). “The Ethereal Hand: Organizational Economics and Management Theory.” The Academy of Management Review, 15(3), 369–381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drucker, P. F. (1954). Practice of Management. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Drucker, P. F. (1985). Innovation and Entrepreneurship. London: Heinemann.Google Scholar
Dunning, J. H. (1981). The Eclectic Theory of the MNC. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Dunning, J. H. (1993). Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Wokingham: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). “Agency Theory: an Assessment and Review.” The Academy of Management Review, 14(1), 57–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisenhardt, K. M., and Zbaracki, M. J. (1992). “Strategic Decision Making.” Strategic Management Journal, 13(8), 17–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E. F. (1980). “Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Political Economy, 88, 288–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferrier, W. J., Smith, K. G., and Grimm, C. M. (1999). “The Role of Competitive Action in Market Share Erosion and Industry Dethronement: a Study of Industry Leaders and Challengers.” The Academy of Management Journal, 42(4), 372–388.Google Scholar
Fisher, F. M. (1989). “Games Economists Play: a Noncooperative View.” The RAND Journal of Economics, 20(1), 113–124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, I. (1930). The Theory of Interest. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. (2005). Strategy, Economic Organization, and the Knowledge Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R. H. (1988). Passion within Reason. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Freeman, R. E. (1984). Strategic Management: a Stakeholder Approach. Boston: Pitman.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. (1970). “The Social Responsibility of a Business Is to Increase Its Profits.” The New York Times Magazine, 13 September.Google Scholar
Frondizi, R. (1971). What is Value? An Introduction to Axiology. La Salee. Ill.: Open Court.Google Scholar
Frost, T. S., Birkinshaw, J. M., and Ensign, P. C. (2002). “Centers of Excellence in Multinational Corporations.” Strategic Management Journal, 23(11), 997–1018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fulmer, W., and Goodwin, J. (1988). “Differentiation: Begin with the Customer.” Business Horizons, 31(5), 159–166.Google Scholar
Galbraith, J. R. (1977). Organization Design. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Gale, B. T., and Wood, R. C. (1994). Managing Customer Value. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Gander, J. P. (1991). “Managerial Intensity, Firm Size and Growth.” Managerial and Decision Economics, 12(3), 261–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geroski, P. A., Gilbert, R. J., and Jacquemin, A. (1990). Barriers to Entry and Strategic Competition. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ghoshal, S. (1987). “Global Strategy: an Organization Framework.” Strategic Management Journal, 8, 425–440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghoshal, S., Bartlett, C., and Moran, P. (2000). “Value Creation.” Executive Excellence, 17(11), 10–36.Google Scholar
Ghoshal, S., and Moran, P. (1996). “Bad for Practice: a Critique of the Transaction Cost Approach.” The Academy of Management Review, 21, 13–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gimeno, J., and Woo, C. Y. (1999). “Multimarket Contact, Economies of Scope, and Firm Performance.” The Academy of Management Journal, 42(3), 239–259.Google Scholar
Goold, M., and Campbell, A. (1998). “Desperately Seeking Synergy.” Harvard Business Review, 76(5), 131–143.Google Scholar
Goold, M., Campbell, A., and Alexander, M. (1994). Corporate-level Strategy: Creating Value in the Multibusiness Company. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Goold, M., and Luchs, K. (1993). “Why Diversify? Four Decades of Management Thinking.” Academy of Management Executive, 7(3).Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1985). “Economic Action and Social Structure: a Theory of Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 481–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, R. M. (1996). “Toward a Knowledge-based Theory of the Firm.” Strategic Management Journal, 17(10), 109–122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, R. M. (2005). Contemporary Strategy Analysis. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Grant, R. M., Jammine, A. P., and Thomas, H. (1988). “Diversity, Diversification, and Profitability among British Manufacturing Companies, 1972–84.” The Academy of Management Journal, 31(4), 771–801.Google Scholar
Grimm, C. M., Lee, H., and Smith, K. G. (2006). Strategy as Action. New York; Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, S., and Hart, O. (1986). “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership. A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691–719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gulati, R. (1995). “Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in Alliances.” The Academy of Management Journal, 38(1), 85–112.Google Scholar
Gulati, R., and Singh, H. (1998). “The Architecture of Cooperation: Managing Coordination Costs and Appropriation Concerns in Strategic Alliances.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 43(4), 781–784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, A. K., and Govindarajan, V. (2001). “Converting Global Presence into Global Competitive Advantage.” Academy of Management Executive, 15, 45–58.Google Scholar
Gupta, A. K., Govindarajan, V., and Wang, H. (2008). The Quest for Global Dominance. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Hambrick, D. C., and Fredrickson, J. W. (2005). “Are you Sure you Have a Strategy?The Academy of Management Executive, 19(4), 51–62.Google Scholar
Hamel, G. (1991). “Competition for Competence and Inter-partner Learning within International Strategic Alliances.” Strategic Management Journal, 12(4), 83–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrigan, K. R. (1980). Strategies for Declining Businesses. Lexington: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Harris, M., and Raviv, A. (1979). “Optimal Incentive Contracts with Imperfect Information.” Journal of Economic Theory, 20(2), 231–259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1985). “Monopolistic Competition in the Spirit of Chamberlin: a General Model.” The Review of Economic Studies, 52(4), 529–546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1995). Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haspeslagh, P. C., and Jemison, D. B. (1991). Managing Acquisitions: Creating Value through Corporate Renewal. London: Free Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945). “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” The American Economic Review, 35, 519–530.Google Scholar
Hennart, J. F. (1982). A Theory of Multinational Enterprise. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Hennart, J. F. (1988). “A Transaction Costs Theory of Equity Joint Ventures.” Strategic Management Journal, 9(4), 361–374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hennart, J. F. (2001). “Theories of the Multinational Entreprise.” In Rugman, A. M. and Brewer, T. (Eds.), Handbook of International Business. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hennart, J. F., and Reddy, S. (1997). “The Choice between Mergers/Acquisitions and Joint Ventures: the Case of Japanese Investors in the United States.” Strategic Management Journal, 18(1), 1–12.3.0.CO;2-R>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, C. W. L., and Hansen, G. S. (1991). “A Longitudinal Study of the Cause and Consequences of Changes in Diversification in the US Pharmaceutical Industry 1977–86.” Strategic Management Journal, 12(3), 187–199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hitt, M. A., Freeman, R. E., and Harrison, J. S. (2001). The Blackwell Handbook of Strategic Management. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hitt, M. A., Harrison, J. S., and Ireland, R. D. (2001). Mergers and Acquisitions: a Guide to Creating Value for Stakeholders. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Holbrook, M. B. (1999). Consumer Value: A Framework for Analysis and Research. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, B. (1979). “Moral Hazard and Observability.” The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 74–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, B., and Roberts, J. (1998). “The Boundaries of the Firm Revisited.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(4), 73–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Wan, W. P., and Yiu, D. (1999). “Theory and Research in Strategic Management: Swings of a Pendulum.” Journal of Management, 25(3), 417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotelling, H. (1929). “Stability in Economic Competition.” Economic Journal, 39(153), 41–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, G. P. (1991). “Organizational Learning: the Contributing Processes and the Literatures.” Organization Science, 2(1), 88–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Husted, B. W., and Salazar, J. (2006). “Taking Friedman Seriously: Maximizing Profits and Social Performance.” Journal of Management Studies, 43(1), 75–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hymer, S. (1976). The International Operations of National Firms. Cambridge, Mass.; London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Inkpen, A. C. (2001). “Strategic Alliances.” The Blackwell Handbook of Strategic Management, 409–432.Google Scholar
Inkpen, A. C., and Dinur, A. (1998). “Knowledge Management Processes and International Joint Ventures.” Organization Science, 9(4), 454–468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobsen, R. (1988). “The Persistence of Abnormal Returns.” Strategic Management Journal, 9(5), 415–430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarrell, G. A., Brickley, J. A., and Netter, J. M. (1988). “The Market for Corporate Control: the Empirical Evidence since 1980.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(1), 49–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C. (1988). “Takeovers: Their Causes and Consequences.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(1), 21–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C., and Meckling, W. (1976). “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Capital Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C., and Ruback, R. S. (1983). “The Market for Corporate Control: the Scientific Evidence.” Journal of Financial Economics, 11(1–4), 5–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johanson, J., and Vahlne, J. E. (1977). “The Internationalization Process of the Firm: a Model of Knowledge Development and Increasing Foreign Market Commitments.” Journal of International Business Studies, 8(1), 23–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
John, C. H. S., and Harrison, J. S. (1999). “Manufacturing-based Relatedness, Synergy, and Coordination.” Strategic Management Journal, 20(2), 129–145.3.0.CO;2-F>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, G. R., and Hill, C. W. L. (1988). “Transaction Cost Analysis of Strategy–Structure Choice.” Strategic Management Journal, 9(2), 159–172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, P. L. (1987). “Contract Duration and Relationship-specific Investments: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets.” The American Economic Review, 77(1), 168–185.Google Scholar
Kant, I. (2008). On the Metaphysics of Morals and Ethics. Radford, Va.: Wilder Publications.Google Scholar
Katz, M. L., and Shapiro, C. (1985). “Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility.” The American Economic Review, 75(3), 424–440.Google Scholar
Kekre, S., and Srinivasan, K. (1990). “Broader Product Line: a Necessity to Achieve Success?Management Science, 36(10), 1216–1231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, K. L. (1993). “Conceptualizing, Measuring, and Managing Customer-based Brand Equity.” Journal of Marketing, 57(1), 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keller, K. L. (2007). Strategic Brand Management: Building, Measuring, and Managing Brand Equity. Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Khanna, T., Gulati, R., and Nohria, N. (1998). “The Dynamics of Learning Alliances: Competition, Cooperation, and Relative Scope.” Strategic Management Journal, 19(3), 193–210.3.0.CO;2-C>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, D. J., and Kogut, B. (1996). “Technological Platforms and Diversification.” Organization Science, 7(3), 283–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, W. C., and Mauborgne, R. (1997). “Value Innovation: the Strategic Logic of High Growth.” Harvard Business Review (Jan–Feb), 103–112.Google ScholarPubMed
Kindleberger, C. P. (1969). American Business Abroad. Six Lectures on Direct Investment: New Haven and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. (1979). Perception, Opportunity and Profit: Studies in the Theory of Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. (1997). “Entrepreneurial Discovery and the Competitive Market Process: an Austrian Approach.” Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1), 60–85.Google Scholar
Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., and Alchian, A. A. (1978). “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process.” Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knickerbocker, F. T. (1973). Oligopolistic Reaction and Multinational Enterprise. Boston, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. New York: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Kobrin, S. J. (1991). “An Empirical Analysis of the Determinants of Global Integration.” Strategic Management Journal, 12, 17–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B. (1988). “Joint Ventures: Theoretical and Empirical Prospects.” Strategic Management Journal, 9, 319–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B. (1991). “Country Capabilities and the Permeability of Borders.” Strategic Management Journal, 12(1), 33–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B., and Zander, U. (1993). “Knowledge of the Firm and the Evolutionary Theory of the Multinational Enterprise.” Journal of International Business Studies, 24(4), 625–645.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B., and Zander, U. (1996). “What Firms Do? Coordination, Identity, and Learning.” Organization Science, 7(5), 502–518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B., and Zander, U. (2003). “Knowledge of the Firm and the Evolutionary Theory of the Multinational Corporation.” Journal of International Business Studies, 34(6), 516–529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kotha, S., and Vadlamani, B. L. (1995). “Assessing Generic Strategies: an Empirical Investigation of Two Competing Typologies in Discrete Manufacturing Industries.” Strategic Management Journal, 16(1), 75–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kotler, P., and Armstrong, G. (1993). Marketing: an Introduction. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Kotler, P., and Zaltman, G. (1971). “Social Marketing: an Approach to Planned Social Change.” Journal of Marketing, 35(3), 3–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M. (1990). Game Theory and Economic Modelling. Oxford: Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M., and Wilson, R. (1982). “Reputation and Imperfect Information.” Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2), 253–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lancaster, K. (1990). “The Economics of Product Variety: a Survey.” Marketing Science, 9(3), 189–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, P. R., and Lorsch, J. W. (1967). Organization and Environment. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Leong, S. M., and Tan, C. T. (1993). “Managing across Borders: an Empirical Test of the Bartlett and Ghoshal [1989] Organizational Typology.” Journal of International Business Studies, 24(3), 449–464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lepak, D. P., Smith, K. G., and Taylor, M. S. (2007). “Value Creation and Value Capture: a Multilevel Perspective.” The Academy of Management Review, 32(1), 180–194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinthal, D. (1988). “A Survey of Agency Costs of Organizations.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 9, 153–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitt, T. (1983). “The Gobalization of Markets.” Harvard Business Review, 61(3).Google Scholar
Levitt, T. (1986). The Marketing Imagination. London: Collier Macmillan.Google Scholar
Libecap, G. D. (1989). Contracting for Property Rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lieberman, M. B., and Montgomery, D. B. (1988). “First-mover Advantages.” Strategic Management Journal, 9, 41–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebeskind, J. P. (1996). “Knowledge, Strategy, and the Theory of the Firm.” Strategic Management Journal, 17, 93–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lippman, S. A., and Rumelt, R. P. (1982). “Uncertain Imitability: an Analysis of Interfirm Differences in Efficiency under Competition.” The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 418–438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, J. W., and Beamish, P. W. (2004). “International Diversification and Firm Performance: the S-curve Hypothesis.” Academy of Management Journal, 47(4), 598–609.Google Scholar
MacCrimmon, K. R. (1993). “Do Firm Strategies Exist?Strategic Management Journal, 14, 113–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machlup, F. (1967). “Theories of the Firm: Marginalist, Behavioral, Managerial.” The American Economic Review, 57(1), 1–33.Google Scholar
MacIntyre, A. C. (1998). A Short History of Ethics. Notre Dame, Ind.: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Mackey, A., Mackey, T. B., and Barney, J. B. (2007). “Corporate Social Responsibility and Firm Performance: Investor Preferences and Corporate Strategies.” The Academy of Management Review, 32(3), 817–835.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madhok, A. (2002). “Reassessing the Fundamentals and Beyond: Ronald Coase, the Transaction Cost and Resource-based Theories of the Firm and the Institutional Structure of Production.” Strategic Management Journal, 23(6), 535–550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magenheim, E. B., and Mueller, D. C. (1988). “Are Acquiring-firm Shareholders Better Off after an Acquisition?” in Coffee, J. C., Lowenstein, L., and Rose-Ackerman, S. (Eds.) Knights, Raiders, and Targets the Impact of the Hostile Takeover. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mahoney, J. T. (1992). “The Choice of Organizational Form: Vertical Financial Ownership versus Other Methods of Vertical Integration.” Strategic Management Journal, 13(8), 559–584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, J. T. (2005). Economic Foundations of Strategy. Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage.Google Scholar
Mahoney, J. T., and Pandian, J. R. (1992). “The Resource-based View within the Conversation of Strategic Management.” Strategic Management Journal, 13(5), 363–380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maister, D. H. (1997). Managing the Professional Service Firm. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Majumdar, S. K., and Ramaswamy, V. (1994). “Explaining Downstream Integration.” Managerial and Decision Economics, 15(2), 119–129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Makadok, R., and Barney, J. B. (2001). “Strategic Factor Market Intelligence: an Application of Information Economics to Strategy Formulation and Competitor Intelligence.” Management Science, 47(12), 1621–1638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Makadok, R., and Coff, R. (2002). “The Theory of Value and the Value of Theory: Breaking New Ground versus Reinventing the Wheel.” Academy of Management Review, 27(1), 10–13.Google Scholar
March, J. G., and Simon, H. A. (1967 [1958]). Organizations. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Mason, E. S. (1939). “Price and Production Policies of Large-scale Enterprise.” The American Economic Review, 29(1), 61–74.Google Scholar
Mayo, E. (1945). The Social Problems of an Industrial Civilisation. Boston: Harvard University.Google Scholar
McGahan, A. M., and Porter, M. E. (1997). “How Much does Industry Matter, Really?Strategic Management Journal, 18, 15–30.3.3.CO;2-T>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGregor, D. (1960). The Human Side of Enterprise. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
McWilliams, A., and Siegel, D. (2001). “Corporate Social Responsibility: a Theory of the Firm Perspective.” The Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 117–127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miles, R. E., and Snow, C. C. (1978). Organizational Strategy, Structure, and Process. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. R., and Roberts, J. F. (1992). Economics, Organization and Management. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (2001). Utilitarianism. Edited by Sher, E.. Indianapolis, Ind.: Hackett Publishing.Google Scholar
Miller, D. (1986). “Configurations of Strategy and Structure: Towards a Synthesis.” Strategic Management Journal, 7(3), 233–249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, D. (1992). “The Generic Strategy Trap.” Journal of Business Strategy, 13(1), 37–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mintzberg, H. (1978). “Patterns in Strategy Formation.” Management Science, 24(9), 934–948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mintzberg, H. (1988). “Generic Strategies: Toward a Comprehensive Framework.” Advances in Strategic Management, 5(New series 1), 67.Google Scholar
Mintzberg, H., Ahlstrand, B. W., and Lampel, J. (1998). Strategy Safari. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Montgomery, C. A., and Hariharan, S. (1991). “Diversified Expansion by Large Established Firms.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 15(1), 71–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morck, R., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1990). “Do Managerial Motives Drive Bad Acquisitions.” Journal of Finance, 45(1), 31–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, G. (2006). Images of Organization. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Mueller, D. C. (1986). Profits in the Long Run. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, P. E., and Enis, B. M. (1986). “Classifying Products Strategically.” Journal of Marketing, 50(3), 24–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nadler, D. A., Tushman, M. L., and Nadler, M. B. (1997). Competing by Design. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Narver, J. C., and Slater, S. F. (1990). “The Effect of a Market Orientation on Business Profitability.” Journal of Marketing, 54(4), 20–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nayyar, P. R. (1993). “On the Measurement of Competitive Strategy: Evidence from a Large Multiproduct US Firm.” The Academy of Management Journal, 36(6), 1652–1669.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R., and Winter, S. G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nutt, P. C. (1998). “How Decision Makers Evaluate Alternatives and the Influence of Complexity.” Management Science, 44(8), 1148–1166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obrinsky, M. (1983). Profit Theory and Capitalism. Oxford: Robertson.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orlitzky, M., Schmidt, F. L., and Rynes, S. (2003). “Corporate Social and Financial Performance: a Meta-analysis.” Organization Studies, 24(3), 403.Google Scholar
Palich, L. E., Cardinal, L. B., and Miller, C. C. (2000). “Curvilinearity in the Diversification–Performance Linkage: an Examination of over Three Decades of Research.” Strategic Management Journal, 21(2), 155–174.3.0.CO;2-2>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, C. (2003). “Research Notes and Commentaries: Prior Peformance Characteristics of Related and Unrelated Acquirers.” Strategic Management Journal, 24, 471–480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, A., and Holt, S. (2001). “Diagnosing Customer Value: Integrating the Value Process and Relationship Marketing.” British Journal of Management, 12(2), 159–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Penrose, E. T. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Perloff, J. M., and Salop, S. C. (1985). “Equilibrium with Product Differentiation.” The Review of Economic Studies, 52(1), 107–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perrow, C. (1986). Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay (third edition). New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Peteraf, M. A. (1993). “The Conerstones of Competitive Advantage: a Resource-based View.” Strategic Management Journal, 14(3), 179–191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, W., and Waterman, R. (1982). In Search of Excellence. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1932). The Economics of Welfare. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pisano, G. P. (1990). “The R&D Boundaries of the Firm: an Empirical Analysis.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1), 153–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Porter, M. E. (1985). Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Porter, M. E. (1987). “From Competitive Advantage to Corporate Strategy.” Harvard Business Review, 65(3), 43–59.Google Scholar
Porter, M. E. (1990). The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York: Free Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, M. E. (1991). “Towards a Dynamic Theory of Strategy.” Strategic Management Journal, 12, 95–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, M. E. (1996). “What's Strategy?” Harvard Business Review, 74(6), 61–78.Google Scholar
Porter, M. E., and Kramer, M. R. (1999). “Philanthropy's New Agenda: Creating Value.” Harvard Business Review, 77(6), 121–130.Google Scholar
Porter, M. E., and Kramer, M. R. (2002). “The Competitive Advantage of Corporate Philanthropy.” Harvard Business Review, 80(12), 56–68.Google Scholar
Porter, M. E., and Kramer, M. R. (2006). “Strategy and Society: the Link between Competitive Advantage and Corporate Social Responsibility.” Harvard Business Review, 84(12), 78–92.Google Scholar
Powell, T. C. (2001). “Competitive Advantage: Logical and Philosophical Considerations.” Strategic Management Journal, 22(9), 875–888.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prahalad, C. K. (2006). The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid. Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Wharton School.Google Scholar
Prahalad, C. K., and Bettis, R. A. (1986). “The Dominant Logic: a New Linkage between Diversity and Performance.” Strategic Management Journal, 7(6), 485–501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prahalad, C. K., and Doz, Y. L. (1987). The Multinational Mission. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Prahalad, C. K., and Hamel, G. (1990). “The Core Competencies of the Corporation.” Harvard Business Review, 68(3), 79–91.Google Scholar
Prahalad, C. K., and Ramaswamy, V. (2004). “Co-creating Unique Value with Customers.” Strategy and Leadership, 32(3), 4–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pratt, J. W., and Zeckhauser, R. J. (1985). Principals and Agents: the Structure of Business. Boston, Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Preston, L. E., and Post, J. E. (1975). Private Management and Public Policy. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Priem, R. L., and Butler, J. E. (2001). “Is the Resource-based View a Useful Perspective for Strategic Management Research?The Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 22–40.Google Scholar
Putterman, L. G., and Kroszner, R. (1996). The Economic Nature of the Firm: A Reader. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Radner, R. (1980). “Collusive Behavior in Noncooperative Epsilon-equilibria of Oligopolies with Long but Finite Lives.” Journal of Economic Theory, 22(2), 289–303.Google Scholar
Ramirez, R. (1999). “Value Co-production: Intellectual Origins and Implications for Practice and Research.” Strategic Management Journal, 20(1), 49–65.3.0.CO;2-2>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rappaport, A. (1986). Creating Shareholder Value. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Rasmusen, E. (2007). Games and Information. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Ravenscraft, D. J., and Scherer, F. M. (1987). Mergers, Sell-Offs, and Economic Efficiency. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1999). A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Raymond, V. (1966). “International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(2), 190–207.Google Scholar
Reed, R., and DeFillippi, R. J. (1990). “Causal Ambiguity, Barriers to Imitation, and Sustainable Competitive Advantage.” The Academy of Management Review, 15(1), 88–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richardson, G. B. (1972). “The Organisation of Industry.” Economic Journal, 82(327), 883–896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rindova, V. P., Williamson, I., Petkova, A. P., and Sever, J. (2005). “Being Good or Being Known: an Empirical Examination of the Dimensions, Antecedents, and Consequences of Organizational Reputation.” The Academy of Management Journal, 48(6), 1033–1049.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, J. (1933). The Economics of Imperfect Competition. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robock, S. H., and Simmonds, K. (1989). International Business and Multinational Enterprises: Homewood, Ill.: Richard Irwin.Google Scholar
Rosen, S. (1974). “Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition.” The Journal of Political Economy, 82(1), 34–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, S. A. (1973). “The Economic Theory of Agency.” The American Economic Review, 63(May), 134–139.Google Scholar
Rugman, A. M. (1982). New Theories of the Multinational Enterprise. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Rumelt, R. P. (1974). Strategy, Structure, and Economic Performance. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Rumelt, R. P. (1982). “Diversification Strategy and Profitability.” Strategic Management Journal, 3(4), 359–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rumelt, R. P. (1984). “Towards a Strategy Theory of the Firm.” Competitive Strategic Management, 556–570.Google Scholar
Rumelt, R. P. (1986). Strategy, Structure, and Economic Performance. Boston, Mass..: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Rumelt, R. P. (1991). “How Much Does Industry Matter?Strategic Management Journal, 12(3), 167–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rumelt, R. P. (1997). “The Evaluation of Business Strategy.” In Mintzberg, H. and Quinn, J. B. (Eds.), The Strategy Process. Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Rumelt, R. P., Schendel, D., and Teece, D. J. (1994). Fundamental Issues in Strategy: a Research Agenda. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Saloner, G. (1991). “Modeling, Game Theory, and Strategic Management.” Strategic Management Journal, 12, 119–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salop, S. C. (1979). “Monopolistic Competition with Outside Goods.” The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 141–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Santalo, J., and Becerra, M. (2008). “Competition from Specialized Firms and the Diversification–Performance Linkage.” The Journal of Finance, 63(2), 851–883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schendel, D., and Hofer, C. W. (1979). Strategic Management: a New View of Business Policy and Planning. Boston, N.J.: Little Brown.Google Scholar
Scherer, F. M. (1979). “The Welfare Economics of Product Variety: an Application to the Ready-to-eat Cereals Industry.” The Journal of Industrial Economics, 28(2), 113–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scherer, F. M. (1988). “Corporate Takeovers: the Efficiency Arguments.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(1), 69–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scherer, F. M., and Ross, D. M. (1990). Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1982). The Theory of Economic Development. Edison, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Scott, W. R. (1992). Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open Systems. London: Prentice Hall International.Google Scholar
Selznick, P. (1957). Leadership in Administration: a Sociological Interpretation. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Senge, P. M. (1990). The Fifth Discipline. New York: Currency Doubleday.Google Scholar
Seth, A., and Thomas, H. (1994). “Theories of the Firm: Implications for Strategy Research.” Journal of Management Studies, 31(2), 165–191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shane, S., and Venkataraman, S. (2000). “The Promise of Enterpreneurship as a Field of Research.” The Academy of Management Review, 25(1), 217–226.Google Scholar
Shapiro, C. (1989). “The Theory of Business Strategy.” The RAND Journal of Economics, 20(1), 125–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, C., and Varian, H. R. (1999). Information Rules. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Shelanski, H. A., and Klein, P. G. (1995). “Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Analysis: a Review and Assessment.” Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11, 335–361.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1957). Administrative Behavior. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1982). Models of Bounded Rationality. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1991). “Bounded Rationality and Organizational Learning.” Organization Science, 2(1), 125–134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, H., and Montgomery, C. A. (1987). “Corporate Acquisition Strategies and Economic Performance.” Strategic Management Journal, 8(4), 377–386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slater, S. F., and Narver, J. C. (1994). “Market Orientation, Customer Value, and Superior Performance.” Business Horizons, 37(2), 22–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: W. Strahan and T. Cadell.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, K. G., Carroll, S. J., and Ashford, S. J. (1995). “Intra- and Inter-organizational Cooperation: Toward a Research Agenda.” The Academy of Management Journal, 38(1), 7–23.Google Scholar
Smith, K. G., Ferrier, W. J., and Ndofor, H. (2001). “Competitive Dynamics Research: Critique and Future Directions.” Handbook of Strategic Management, 315–361.Google Scholar
Smith, K. G., Grimm, C. M., and Gannon, M. J. (1992). Dynamics of Competitive Strategy. Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Sorenson, O. (2000). “Letting the Market Work for You: an Evolutionary Perspective on Product Strategy.” Strategic Management Journal, 21(5), 577–592.3.0.CO;2-C>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, M. (1976). “Product Differentiation and Welfare.” The American Economic Review, 66(2), 407–414.Google Scholar
Spender, J. C. (1989). Industry Recipes. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Stabell, C. B., and Fjeldstad, O. D. (1998). “Configuring Value for Competitive Advantage: on Chains, Shops, and Networks.” Strategic Management Journal, 19(5), 413–437.3.0.CO;2-C>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, J. (2003). “Agency, Information and Corporate Investment.” In Stein, J., Constantinides, G., Harris, M., and Stulz, R. (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
Stein, J. (1950). “The Development of Utility Theory: Part I and Part II.” Journal of Political Economy, 58, 307–327.Google Scholar
Stein, J. (1958). “Ricardo and the 93% Labor Theory of Value.” The American Economic Review, 48(3), 357–367.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1961). “The Economics of Information.” Journal of Political Economy, 69, 213–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1968). “Price and Non-price Competition.” The Journal of Political Economy, 76(1), 149–154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, D. J. (1980). “The Economics of Scope and Scale of the Enterprise.” Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation, 1(3), 223–247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, D. J. (1982a). “An Economic Theory of Multiproduct Firms.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, 39–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, D. J. (1982b). A Transactions Cost Theory of the Multinational Enterprise. Stanford, Calif.: Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Teece, D. J. (1986). “Transactions Cost Economics and the Multinational Enterprise: an Assessment.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 7, 21–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, D. J. (1987). Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm. Calif.: University of California, Berkeley Business School.Google Scholar
Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., and Shuen, A. (1997). “Dynamic Capabilities and Strategy Management.” Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 509–533.3.0.CO;2-Z>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, J. D. (1967). Organizations in Action. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Vasconcellos, J. A. S., and Hambrick, D. C. (1989). “Key Success Factors: Test of a General Theory in the Mature Industrial Product Sector.” Strategic Management Journal, 10(4), 367–382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vernon, R. (1966). “International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(2), 190–207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Villalonga, B. (2004). “Diversification Discount or Premium? New Evidence from the Business Information Tracking Series.” The Journal of Finance, 59(2), 479–506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. K., Vernon, J. M., and Harrington, J. E. (2000). Economics of Regulation and Antitrust. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Waddock, S. A., and Graves, S. B. (1997). “The Corporate Social Performance–Financial Performance Link.” Strategic Management Journal, 18(4), 303–319.3.0.CO;2-G>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wernerfelt, B. (1984). “A Resource-based Theory of the Firm.” Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171–180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wernerfelt, B., and Montgomery, C. A. (1988). “Tobin's Q and the Importance of Focus in Firm Performance.” The American Economic Review, 78(1), 246–250.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1991). “Strategizing, Economizing, and Economic Organization.” Strategic Management Journal, 12, 75–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1993). “Calculativeness, Trust, and Economic Organization.” Journal of Law and Economics, 36(1), 453–486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1999). “Strategy Research: Governance and Competence Perspectives.” Strategic Management Journal, 20, 1087–1108.3.0.CO;2-Z>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolf, C. (1979). “A Theory of Non-market Failure: Framework for Implementation Analysis.” Journal of Law and Economics, 22(1), 107–139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, D. J. (1991). “Corporate Social Performance Revisited.” The Academy of Management Review, 16(4), 691–718.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yip, G. S. (1989). “Global Strategy.” Sloan Management Review.
Yiu, D., and Makino, S. (2002). “The Choice between Joint Venture and Wholly-owned Subsidiary: an Institutional Perspective.” Organization Science, 13(6), 667–683.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zeithaml, V. A. (1988). “Consumer Perceptions of Price, Quality, and Value: a Means–End Model and Synthesis of Evidence.” Journal of Marketing, 52(3), 2–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhao, H., Luo, Y., and Suh, T. (2004). “Transaction Cost Determinants and Ownership-based Entry Mode Choice: a Meta-analytical Review.” Journal of International Business Studies, 35(6), 524–545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Manuel Becerra
  • Book: Theory of the Firm for Strategic Management
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511626524.013
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Manuel Becerra
  • Book: Theory of the Firm for Strategic Management
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511626524.013
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Manuel Becerra
  • Book: Theory of the Firm for Strategic Management
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511626524.013
Available formats
×