Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-5nwft Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-01T22:24:46.825Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Appendix B - A note on the degree of openness of the Chinese economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2010

Nicholas R. Lardy
Affiliation:
University of Washington
Get access

Summary

Economists conventionally use the ratio of exports plus imports relative to gross national product or national income as an indicator of the degree of “openness” of an economy. This measure, frequently referred to as the trade ratio, is a convenient method both for measuring how the degree of openness of an economy changes over time and for comparing the degree of openness of different economies. Intercountry comparisons, of course, are somewhat problematic because ceteris paribus “large” countries have lower trade ratios than “small” countries. There are several reasons for this. First, large countries are less likely to depend on imports of minerals and other raw materials. Second, they are more likely to have levels of domestic demand sufficiently large to take advantage of economies of scale, which exist in some types of manufacturing, without exporting part of the output. Finally, relatively higher transport costs in large countries tend to provide domestic producers a greater degree of natural protection against foreign competition (Perkins and Syrquin, 1, 705–22).

In the text of this study I have avoided using estimates of China's trade ratio to measure the degree of openness of the Chinese economy. This is because of the uncertainties involved in measuring China's trade volume and its gross national product (GNP) in a common currency. China compiles its trade data in U.S. dollars and its GNP in terms of domestic currency. Although it is a simple matter to convert these to a common currency by dividing the reported GNP in domestic currency by the official exchange rate, it is a dubious procedure, particularly for an economy such as China's in which the relative prices of nontraded goods and particularly services are fixed by the government at unusually low levels.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×