Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T10:41:26.849Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - The pity of peace: Germany's economy at war, 1914–1918 and beyond

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 July 2009

Albrecht Ritschl
Affiliation:
Professor, Humboldt University, Berlin
Stephen Broadberry
Affiliation:
University of Warwick
Mark Harrison
Affiliation:
University of Warwick
Get access

Summary

Introduction

The economic history of Germany's Great War appears intellectually unexciting. It is the story of a failed blitz campaign and a subsequent war of attrition. It is the chronicle of disappointed expectations, painful adjustment, and of quixotic efforts to ignore reality. It is the account of an insufficient resource base, and probably of misallocation and disingenuous economic planning. And, last, it is the story of a half-constitutional yet undemocratic system in denial of defeat, unable to compromise, unable to make peace, finally drawing the whole of society into the abyss of its own political and military collapse.

A tragedy foretold: in the winter of 1914, the Kaiser's military commander-in-chief, Erich von Falkenhayn, informed his government that Germany's war effort had failed, that its military machinery lay in pieces, and that the only way out of the deadlock would be through diplomatic channels (Mommsen 2001: 47). Whatever the changing fate of Germany's armies on the battlefield after that date, events in the end proved Falkenhayn right. Hardach (1973) and Ferguson (1998) have taken this point to the extreme. They argued that, contrary to conventional wisdom and popular myths, the economics of World War I explain little, if anything, that goes beyond the military facts of late 1914.

This survey chapter on the German economy at war is about these seemingly residual economics of World War I on the German side.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2005

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ahmed, S. (1986), ‘Temporary and Permanent Government Spending in an Open Economy’, Journal of Monetary Economics 17: 197–224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balderston, T. (1989), ‘War Finance and Inflation in Britain and Germany, 1914–1918’, Economic History Review 62: 222–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. (1981), ‘Output Effects of Government Purchases’, Journal of Political Economy 89: 1086–121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baten, J. and Schulz, R. (2005), ‘Making Profits in War-Time: German Industrial and Service Companies’ Profits During WWI and their Implications', Economic History Review forthcoming.
Bordo, M. and Kydland, F. (1995), ‘The Gold Standard as a Rule: An Essay in Exploration’, Explorations in Economic History 32: 423–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bordo, M. and White, E. (1991), ‘A Tale of Two Currencies: British and French Finance During the Napoleonic Wars’, Journal of Economic History 51: 303–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, S. and Ritschl, A. (1995), ‘Real Wages, Productivity, and Unemployment in Britain and Germany during the 1920s’, Explorations in Economic History 32: 327–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bry, G. (1960), Wages in Germany, 1871–1945, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bulow, J. and Rogoff, K. (1989), ‘A Constant Recontracting Model of Sovereign Debt’, Journal of Political Economy 97: 155–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, G. and Reinhart, C. (2000), ‘When Capital Flows Come to a Sudden Stop: Consequences and Policy’, in Kenen, P. and Swoboda, A. (eds.), Reforming the International Monetary and Financial System, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Daniel, U. (1989), Frauen in der Kriegsgesellschaft, Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht.Google Scholar
Dessirier, J. (1928), ‘Indices comparés de la production industrielle et de la production agricole en divers pays de 1870 à 1928’, Bulletin de la Statistique générale de la France et du Service d'observation des Prix 18: 65–110.Google Scholar
Dornbusch, R. (1987), ‘Lessons from the German Inflation Experience of the 1920s’, in Dornbusch, R. (ed.), Macroeconomics and Finance: Essays in Honor of Franco Modigliani, ed. by R. Dornbusch, Stanley Fisher and John Bossons, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 337–66.Google Scholar
Eaton, J., Gersovitz, M., and Stiglitz, J. (1986), ‘The Pure Theory of Country Risk’, European Economic Review 30: 481–513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (1990), ‘The Capital Levy in Theory and Practice’, in Dornbusch, R. and Draghi, M. (eds.), Public Debt Management: Theory and History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 191–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, B. and Wyplosz, C. (1988), ‘The Economic Consequences of the Franc Poincaré’, in Helpman, E. (ed.), Economic Effects of Government Expenditure, Cambridge, MA.: Macmillan, pp. 257–86.Google Scholar
Elsner, L. and Lehmann, J. (1988), Ausländische Arbeiter unter dem deutschen Imperialismus, Berlin: Dietz.Google Scholar
Feinstein, C. H. (1972), National Income, Expenditure and Output of the United Kingdom 1855–1965, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Feldman, G. (1966), Army, Industry and Labor in Germany, 1914–1918, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ferguson, N. (1998), The Pity of War, London: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Fischer, F. (1967), Germany's Aims in the First World War, London: Chatto and Windus.Google Scholar
Graham, F. D. (1930), Exchange, Prices, and Production in Hyper-Inflation: Germany, 1920–1923, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hardach, G. (1973), Der Erste Weltkrieg, Munich: Deutscher Taschenbuch-Verlag.Google Scholar
Henning, F.-W. (1974), Das industrialisierte Deutschland 1914–1972, Paderborn: Schöningh.Google Scholar
Hoffmann, W. G. (1965), Das Wachstum der deutschen Wirtschaft seit der Mitte des 19. Jahrhunderts, Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holtfrerich, C.-L. (1986), The German Inflation, New York: de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1919), The Economic Consequences of the Peace, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kocka, J. (1978), Klassengesellschaft im Krieg. Deutsche Sozialgeschichte 1914–1918, Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luxemburg, R. (1951[1921]), The Accumulation of Capital, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (1991), Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development: A Long-Run Comparative View, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mitchell, B. (1981), European Historical Statistics (2nd revised edition), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mommsen, W. (2001), Die Urkatastrophe Deutschlands. Der Erste Weltkrieg 1914–1918, Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.Google Scholar
Offer, A. (1989), The First World War. An Agrarian Interpretation, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Petzina, D., Abelshauser, W. and Faust, A. (1978), Sozialgeschichtliches Arbeitsbuch III. Materialien zur Statistik des Deutschen Reiches 1914–1945, Munich: C. H. Beck.Google Scholar
Prati, A. (1991), ‘Poincaré's Stabilization: Stopping a Run on Government Debt’, Journal of Monetary Economics 27: 231–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramsey, F. P. (1927), ‘A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation’, Economic Journal 37: 47–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritschl, A. (1990), ‘Zum Verhältnis von Markt und Staat in Hitlers Weltbild’, in Backes, Uwe, Jesse, Eckhard, and Zitelmann, Rainer (eds.), Die Schatten der Vergangenheit. Impulse zur Historisierung des Nationalsozialismus, Frankurt/Main: Propyläen, pp. 243–64.Google Scholar
Ritschl, A.(1996), ‘Sustainability of High Public Debt: What the Historical Record Shows’, Swedish Economic Policy Review 3: 175–98.Google Scholar
Ritschl, A.(2001), ‘Nazi Economic Imperialism and the Exploitation of the Small: Evidence from Germany's Secret Foreign Exchange Balances, 1938–40’, Economic History Review 54: 324–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritschl, A.(2002), Deutschlands Krise und Konjunktur, 1924–1934. Binnenkonjunktur, Auslandsverschuldung und Reparationsproblem zwischen Dawes-Plan und Transfersperre, Berlin: Akademie-Verlag.Google Scholar
Ritschl, A. and Spoerer, M. (1997), ‘Das Bruttosozialprodukt in Deutschland nach den amtlichen Volkseinkommens- und Sozialproduktstatistiken 1901–1995’, Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte, pp. 11–37.Google Scholar
Roesler, K. (1967), Die Finanzpolitik des Deutschen Reiches im Ersten Weltkrieg, Berlin: Duncker und Humblot.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, R. (1997), Staat und Wirtschaft im Ersten Weltkrieg. Kriegsgesellschaften als kriegswirtschaftliche Steuerungsinstrumente, Berlin: Duncker und Humblot.Google Scholar
Sabrow, M. (1994), Der Rathenaumord. Rekonstruktion einer Verschwörung gegen die Republik von Weimar, Munich: Oldenbourg.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schuker, S. (1976), The End of French Predominance in Europe, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Schuker, S.(1988), American Reparations to Germany, 1924–1933, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sicsic, P. (1993), ‘Was the Franc Poincaré Undervalued?’, Explorations in Economic History 29: 69–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skalweit, A. (1927), Die deutsche Kriegsernährungswirtschaft, Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlagsanstalt.Google Scholar
Statistisches Reichsamt (various years), Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich, Berlin: Puttkammer und Mühlbrecht.
Wagenführ, R. (1933), ‘Die Industriewirtschaft. Entwicklungstendenzen der deutschen und internationalen Industrieproduktion 1860 bis 1932’, Vierteljahreshefte zur Konjunkturforschung Sonderheft 31: 3–70.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×