Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-5wvtr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-19T11:27:53.311Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

15 - ‘Individual Failure’ and a Behavioural Public Sector Economics

from Part IV - Public Sector Consumer Behaviour

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 February 2018

Alan Lewis
Affiliation:
University of Bath
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

15.7 References

Ainslie, G. (1991). Derivation of ’Rational’ Economic Behaviour from Hyperbolic Discount Curves. American Economic Review, 81(2), 334340.Google Scholar
Allingham, M. G. and Sandmo, A. (1972). Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 1(3-4), 323338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alm, J. Expanding the Theory of Tax Compliance from Individual to Group Motivations, in Forte, F., Mudambi, R. and Navarra, P. M. (eds.) (2014). A Handbook of Alternative Theories of Public Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 260277.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 14471458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baddeley, M. (2011). Energy the Environment and Behavioural Change: A Survey of Insights from Behavioural Economics, CWPE 1162, University of Cambridge. Available at: www.repository.cam.ac.uk/handle/1810/242028.Google Scholar
Banford, N. D., Knetsch, J. L., and Mauser, G. A. (1979). Feasibility Judgements and Alternative Measures of Benefits and Costs. Journal of Business Administration, 11(1), 25–35.Google Scholar
Barile, L., Cullis, J. and Jones, P. (2015). Will One Size Fit All? Incentives Designed to Nurture Pro-Social Behaviour. Journal of Behavioural and Experimental Economics, 57, 916.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1971). Economic Theory. New York: A. A.Knopf.Google Scholar
Berglund, C. (2006). The Assessment of Households’ Recycling Costs: The Role of Personal Motives. Ecological Economics, 56(4), 560569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. D. (2016). The Good, the Bad and the Ugly: A Unified Approach to Behavioural Welfare Economics. Journal of Cost Benefit Analysis, 7(1), 1268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beverly, S., Schneider, D. and Tufano, P. (2006). Splitting Tax Refunds and Building Savings: An Empirical Test, in Poterba, J. M. (ed.), Tax Policy and Economy, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 111162.Google Scholar
Bishop, R. C., and Heberlein, T. A. (1979). Measuring values of extramarket goods: Are indirect measures biased? American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 61(5), 926–930.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brekke, K. A., Kipperberg, G. and Nyborg, K. (2007). Reluctant Recyclers: Social Interaction in Responsibility Ascription. Available at: ssrn.com/abstract=1116149 or dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1116149.Google Scholar
Brennan, G. and Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and Decision: The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. and Weber, M. (1992). Recent Developments in Modeling Preferences: Uncertainty and Ambiguity. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 325370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, F. and Johansson-Stenman, O. (2012). Behavioural Economics and Environmental Economics. Annual Review of Resource Economics, 4(1), 7599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chapman, G. B. (1996). Temporal Discounting and Utility for Health and Money. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory and Cognition, 22(3), 771791.Google ScholarPubMed
Christian, R. C. and Alm, J. (2014). Empathy, Sympathy and Tax Compliance. Journal of Economic Psychology, 40, 6282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, C. F., Kotchenb, M. J. and Moorea, M. R. (2003). Internal and External Influences on Pro-EnviEmpathy, Sympathy and Tax Compliance. ronmental Behaviour: Participation in a Green Electricity Program. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 22(3), 237246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Congdon, W., Kling, J. R. and Mullainathan, S. (2009). Behavioural Economics and Taxation. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. 15328.Google Scholar
Cullis, J. and Jones, P. (2009). Public Finance and Public Choice (3rd Ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Czajkowski, M., Hanley, N. and Nyborg, K. (2017). Social Norms, Morals and Self-interest as Determinants of Pro-Environment Behaviours: The Case of Household Recycling. Environmental and Resource Economics, 66(4), 647–670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daskalakis, M. (2016). Specification Required? A Survey of Scientists’ Views About the Role of Behavioural Economics for Assessing Environmental Policy Instruments, in Beckenbach, F. and Kahlenborn, W. (eds.), New Perspectives for Environmental Policies Through Behavioural Economics, Berlin: Springer, 69106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, E. L. (1975). Intrinsic Motivation. New York: Plenum.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, E. L. and Ryan, R. M. (1985). Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behaviour. New York: Pantheon.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Gächter, S. (2000a). Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods Experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Gächter, S. (2000b). Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Co-operation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, Y. and Perez, O. (2009). How Law Changes the Environmental Mind: An Experimental Study of the Effect of Legal Norms on Moral Perceptions and Civic Enforcement. Journal of Law and Society, 36(4), 501535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. and Gächter, S. (2006). Heterogeneous Social Preferences and the Dynamics of Free Riding in Public Goods. Centre for Decision Research and Experimental Economics (CeDEx) Discussion Paper No. 2006-01. Available at: www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/67967/1/506605825.pdf.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S. and Fehr, E. (2001). Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R. H. and Sunstein, C.R. (2001). Cost–Benefit Analysis and Relative Position. University of Chicago Law Review, 68(2), 323374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. and O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. S. (1997). Not Just for the Money, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Eichenberger, R. (1994). Economic Incentives Transform Psychological Anomalies. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation, 23(2), 215234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. and Stutzer, A. (2006). Environmental Morale and Motivation. Available at: www.iew.uzh.ch/wp/iewwp288.pdf.Google Scholar
Gneezy, U., Meier, S. and Rey-Biel, P. (2011). When and Why Incentives (Don’t) Work to Modify Behaviour. Journal of Economic Perspectives 25(4), 191210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodin, R. E. (1982). Discounting Discounting. Journal of Public Policy, 2(1), 5372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guth, W. and Ortmann, A. (2006). A Behavioural Approach to Distribution and Bargaining, in Altman, M. (ed.), Handbook of Contemporary Behavioural Economics. New York: M. E. Sharpe, 379404.Google Scholar
Hammack, J. and BrownJr., G. M. (1974). Waterfowl and Wetlands: Toward Bioeconomic Analysis. Baltimore: John Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Hanley, N. and Shogren, J. (2005). Is Cost-Benefit Analysis Anomaly Proof? Environmental and Resource Economics, 32(1), 1334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanneman, W. M. (1991). Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept: How Much Can They Differ? American Economic Review, 81(3), 635647.Google Scholar
Heberlein, T. A., and Bishop, R. C. (1985). Assessing the Validity of Contingent Valuation: Three Field Experiments. Paper presented at the International Conference on Man’s Role in Changing Global Environment, Italy.Google Scholar
Henderson, N. and Bateman, I. (1995). Empirical and Public Choice Evidence for Hyperbolic Social Discount Rates and the Implications for Intergenerational Discounting. Environmental and Resource Economics, 5(4), 413423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Her Majesty’s Treasury (2003). Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Howarth, R. B. and Wilson, M. A. (2006). A Theoretical Approach to Deliberative Valuation: Aggregating by Mutual Consent. Land Economics, 82(1), 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L. and Thaler, R.H. (1990). Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 13251348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Sugden, R. (2005). Experienced Utility as a Standard of Policy Evaluation. Environmental and Resource Economics, 32(1), 161181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khalil, E. L. (2003). Behavioural Economics and the Transactional View. Transactional Viewpoints, 11(1), 18.Google Scholar
Knetsch, J. L. (1990). Environmental Policy Implication of Disparities Between Willingness to Pay and Compensation Demanded. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 18(3), 227237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knetsch, J. L. (2010). Values of Gains and Losses: Reference States and Choices of Measure. Environmental and Resource Economics 46(2), 179188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, F. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Knox, T. M. (1952). Hegel’s Philosophy of Right: Translated with Notes. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lange, A., Loschel, A., Vogt, C. and Ziegler, A. (2010). On the Self-Interested Use of Equity in International Climate Negotiations. European Economic Review, 54(3), 359375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, J. S., Small, D. A. and Loewenstein, G. (2004). Heart Strings and Purse Strings. Psychological Science, 15(5), 337–41.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loewenstein, G. (1987). Anticipation and the Valuation of Delayed Consumption. Economic Journal, 97(387), 666684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (2007). Exotic Preferences: Behavioural Economics and Human Motivation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Löfgren, Å., Martinsson, P., Hennlock, M. and Sterner, T. (2012). Does Experience Eliminate the Effect of a Default Option? A Field Experiment on CO2-Offsetting for Air Transport. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 63, 6672.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loock, C.-M., Staake, T. and Thiesse, F. (2013). Motivating Energy-Efficient Behaviour with Green IS: An Investigation of Goal Setting and the Role of Defaults. MIS Quarterly, 37(4), 13131332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCaffery, E. J. and Slemrod, J. (2006). Behavioral Public Finance, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Mishan, E. J. and Quah, E. (2007). Cost-Benefit Analysis (5th Ed.). London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Oberholzer-Gee, F., Bohnet, I. and Frey, B. S. (1997). Fairness and Competence in Democratic Decisions. Public Choice 91(1), 89105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1998). A Behavioural Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action: Presidential Address, American Political Science Association, 1997. American Political Science Review, 92(1), 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasche, M. (2016). What Can Be Learned from Behavioural Economics and Environmental Policy? in Beckenbach, F. and Kahlenborn, W. (eds.), New Perspectives for Environmental Policies Through Behavioural Economics. Berlin: Springer, 109126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pichert, D. and Katsikopoulos, K. V. (2008). Green Defaults: Information Presentation and Pro-Environmental Behaviour. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 28(1), 6373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (2013). An Approach to Incorporating Psychology into Economics. American Economic Review, 103(3), 12811302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, L. A. and Hammitt, J. K. (2011). Behavioural Economics and the Conduct of Benefit-Cost Analysis: Toward Principles and Standards. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2(2), 151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandford, C. T., Godwin, M. R. and Hardwick, P. J. W. (1989). Administrative and Compliance Costs of Taxation. Bath: Fiscal Publications.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. (1981). Economic Reasoning and the Ethics of Policy. Public Interest, 63, 3761.Google Scholar
Shefrin, H. M. and Thaler, R. H. (1988). The Behavioural Life-Cycle Hypothesis. Economic Inquiry, 26(4), 609–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shogren, J. F. and Taylor, L. O. (2008). On Behavioural-Environmental Economics. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy Advance Access, 2(1), 2644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shogren, J. F. and Thunstrőm, L. (2016). Do We Need a New Behavioural Benchmark for BCA? Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 7(1), 92106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1979). Rational Decision Making in Business Organisations. American Economic Review, 69(4), 493513.Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (2000). The Perception of Risk, Sterling, VA: Earthscan.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776/1937). The Wealth of Nations. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Stern, N. (2007). The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stigler, G. and Becker, G. (1977). ‘De gustibus non est disputandum’. American Economic Review, 67(2), 7690.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. and Reisch, L. A. (2016). Behaviourally Green: Why, Which and When Defaults Can Help, in Beckenbach, F. and Kahlenborn, W. (eds.), New Perspectives for Environmental Policies Through Behavioural Economics. Berlin: Springer, 161194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1981). Some Empirical Evidence on Dynamic Inconsistency. Economic Letters, 8(3), 201207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (2016). Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, and Future. American Economic Review, 106(7), 15771600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. and Shefrin, H. M. (1981). An Economic Theory of Self-Control. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 392406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Torgler, B., Frey, B. S. and Wilson, C. (2009). Environmental and Pro-Social Norms: Evidence on Littering. BE Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 9(1), 139.Google Scholar
Venkatacalam, L. (2008). Behavioural Economics for Environmental Policy. Ecological Economics, 67(4), 640645.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, W. K. and Gayer, T. (2016). Rational Benefit Assessment for an Irrational World: Toward a Behavioural Transfer Test. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 7(1), 6991.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, T. O., Fooken, J. and Herrmann, B. (2014). Behavioural Economics and Taxation. European Commission Working Paper No. 41.Google Scholar
Willig, R. (1976). Consumer’s Surplus Without Apology. American Economic Review, 66(4), 589–97.Google Scholar
Wittman, D. A. (1995). The Myth of Democratic Failure: Why Political Institutions Are Efficient. London: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×