Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-m9kch Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-01T04:11:17.432Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 November 2019

Alessandro Roncaglia
Affiliation:
Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Age of Fragmentation
A History of Contemporary Economic Thought
, pp. 377 - 418
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramovitz, M. 1989. Thinking about growth and other essays. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. 2008. ‘Oligarchic versus democratic societies’. Journal of the European Economic Association 6: 144.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Cantoni, D. and Johnson, J. A. 2011. ‘The consequences of radical reform: the French Revolution’. American Economic Review 101: 3286–307.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. 2006. Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Adelman, I. 1961. Theories of economic growth and development. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Adelman, I. 1988. ‘Confessions of an incurable romantic’. BNL Quarterly Review 41 (164): 391411.Google Scholar
Adelman, J. 2013. Worldly philosopher: the odyssey of Albert O. Hirschman. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Adelman, M. A. 1972. The world petroleum market. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Adelman, M. A. 1995. The genie out of the bottle: world oil since 1970. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Aftalion, A. 1913. Les crises périodiques de surproduction. Paris: Rivière.Google Scholar
Agarwal, B. 2016. Gender challenges. 3 vols. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. 1992. ‘A model of growth through creative destruction’. Econometrica 60: 323–51.Google Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. 1998. Endogenous growth theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Ahlborn, C. and Grave, C. 2006. ‘Walter Eucken and ordoliberalism: an introduction from a consumer welfare perspective’. Competition Policy International 2(2): 197217.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. 1970. ‘The market for lemons’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 488500.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. 1980. ‘A theory of social custom, of which unemployment might be a consequence’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 94: 749–75.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. 2007. ‘The missing motivation in macroeconomics’. American Economic Review 97: 336.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. and Kranton, R. 2000. ‘Economics and identity’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 715–53.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. 1950. ‘Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory’. Journal of Political Economy 58: 211–22.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. and Woodward, S. 1988. ‘The firm is dead; long live the firm: a review of Oliver E. Williamson’s The economic institutions of capitalism’. Journal of Economic Literature 26: 6579.Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Ardagna, S. 2009. ‘Large changes in fiscal policy: taxes versus spending’. NBER Working Paper 15438. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., Spolaore, E. and Wacziarg, R. 2000. ‘Economic integration and political disintegration’. American Economic Review 90: 1276–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allais, M. 1947. Economie et intérêt. 2 vols. Paris: Imprimerie Nationale.Google Scholar
Allais, M. 1953. ‘Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant de le risque: critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école americaine’. Econometrica 21: 503–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almeida, A. and Goodhart, C. 1998. ‘Does adoption of inflation targets affect central bank behavior?BNL Quarterly Review, Supplement to n. 204, Globalization and stability of financial markets, 19107.Google Scholar
Amable, B. 2003. The diversity of modern capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Amin, S. 1974. The accumulation of capital on a world scale. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Amin, S. 1994. Unequal development: an essay on the social formations of peripheral capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Andrews, P. W. S. 1993. The economics of competitive enterprise: selected essays. Ed. by Lee, F. S. and Earl, P. E.. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Arestis, P. 2009. ‘New consensus macroeconomics: a critical appraisal’. Working Paper 564. Annandale-on-Hudson: Levy Economics Institute.Google Scholar
Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. 2008. ‘A critical reconsideration of the foundations of monetary policy in the new consensus macroeconomics framework’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 32: 761–79.Google Scholar
Ark, B. van, ed. 1997. Economic growth in the long run: a history of empirical evidence. 3 vols. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Arrighi, G. 1978. The geometry of imperialism. New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Arrighi, G. 2007. Adam Smith in Beijing: lineages of the twenty-first century. New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. 1951a. Social choice and individual values. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. 1951b. ‘Alternative approaches to the theory of choice in risk-taking situations’. Econometrica 19: 404–37.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. 1962. ‘The economic implications of learning by doing’. Review of Economic Studies 26: 155–73.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. 1983–5. Collected papers. 6 vols. Boston: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press (vol. 1, Social choice and justice; vol. 2, General equilibrium; vol. 3, Individual choice under certainty and uncertainty; vol. 4, The economics of information; vol. 5, Production and capital; vol. 6, Applied economics).Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. and Debreu, G. 1954. ‘Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy’. Econometrica 22: 265–90.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. and Hahn, F. H. 1971. General competitive analysis. San Francisco: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. and Levhari, D. 1969. ‘Uniqueness of the internal rate of return with variable life of investment’. Economic Journal 79: 560–66.Google Scholar
Arthur, B. 1994. Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asimakopulos, T. 1986. ‘Harrod and Domar on dynamic economics’. BNL Quarterly Review 39(158): 275–90.Google Scholar
Asimakopulos, T. 1991. Keynes’s general theory and accumulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Aspromourgos, T. 1986. ‘On the origins of the term “neoclassical”’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 10: 265–70.Google Scholar
Aspromourgos, T. 2009. The science of wealth: Adam Smith and the framing of political economy. Abington: Routledge.Google Scholar
Aston, T. H. and Philpin, C. H. E., eds. 1976. The Brenner debate: agrarian class struggle and economic development in pre-industrial Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Athey, S. and Imbens, J. W. 2017. ‘The state of applied econometrics: causality and policy evaluations’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 31: 332.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. 1970. ‘On the measurement of inequality’. Journal of Economic Theory 2: 244–63.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. 2009. ‘Economics as a moral science’. Economica 76: 791804.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A., Piketty, T. and Saez, E. 2011. ‘Top incomes in the long run of history’. Journal of Economic Literature 49: 371.Google Scholar
Aumann, R. 1966. ‘Existence of competitive equilibria in markets with a continuum of traders’. Econometrica 34: 117.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1984. The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Babbage, C. 1832. On the economy of machinery and manufactures. London: Charles Knight; reprint of the IV ed. (1835), New York: M. Kelley, 1963.Google Scholar
Backhouse, R. E. 2014a. ‘Paul A. Samuelson’s move to MIT’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplement): 6077.Google Scholar
Backhouse, R. E. 2014b. ‘MIT and the other Cambridge’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplement): 252–70.Google Scholar
Backhouse, R. E. 2017. Founder of modern economics: Paul A. Samuelson, vol. 1, Becoming Samuelson, 1945–1948. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bain, J. S. 1956. Barriers to new competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bair, J. 2009. ‘Taking aim at the New International Economic Order’. In Mirowski and Plehve, pp. 347–85.Google Scholar
Baker, S.R., Bloom, N. and Davis, S.J. 2016. ‘Measuring economic policy uncertainty’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 131: 15931636.Google Scholar
Banerjee, A. and Duflo, E. 2011. Poor economics. New York: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Baran, P. A. 1957. The political economy of growth. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Baran, P. A. and Sweezy, P. M. 1966. Monopoly capital: an essay on the American economic and social order. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Baranzini, M. 2005. ‘Modigliani’s life-cycle theory of savings fifty years later’. BNL Quarterly Review 58 (233–4): 109–72.Google Scholar
Barberis, N.C. 2013. ‘Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: a review and assessment’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27: 173–96.Google Scholar
Barca, F. 1994. Imprese in cerca di padrone: proprietà e controllo nel capitalismo italiano. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Barone, E. 1908. ‘Il ministro della produzione nello stato collettivista’. Giornale degli economisti 2: 267–93 and 391414.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. 1974. ‘Are government bonds net wealth?’. Journal of Political Economy 82: 1095–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Grossman, H. I. 1971. ‘A general disequilibrium model of income and employment’. American Economic Review 61: 8293.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Redlick, C. J. 2011. ‘Macroeconomic effects from government purchases and taxes’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 126: 51102.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. 1959. Business behaviour, value and growth. New York: Harcourt & C.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. and Bowen, W. 1966. Performing arts, the economic dilemma: a study of problems common to theater, opera, music, and dance. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J., Panzar, J. C. and Willig, R. D. 1982. Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. San Diego: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Becker, G. 1974. ‘A theory of social interactions’. Journal of Political Economy 81: 813–46.Google Scholar
Becker, G. 1996. Accounting for tastes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Becker, G. 1998. L’approccio economico al comportamento umano. Ed. by Cigno, A.. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Benes, J., Chauvet, M., Kamenik, D., Kumhof, M., Laxton, D., Mursula, S. and Sebody, J. 2015. ‘The future of oil: geology versus technology’. International Journal of Forecasting 31(1): 207–21.Google Scholar
Benini, R. 1907. ‘Sull’uso delle formule empiriche nell’economia applicata’. Giornale degli economisti, II series, 35: 1053–63.Google Scholar
Bergson, A. 1938. ‘A reformulation of certain aspects of welfare economics’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 52: 310–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berle, A. A. and Means, G. 1932. The modern corporation and private property. New York: The Commerce Clearing House.Google Scholar
Berlin, I. 1958. Two concepts of liberty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Berlin, I. 2002. Liberty. Ed. by Hardy, H.. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bernstein, E. 1899. Die Voraussetzungen des Sozialismus und die Aufgaben der Sozialdemokratie. Stuttgart: Dietz. Italian transl., Socialismo e socialdemocrazia. Bari: Laterza, 1968.Google Scholar
Beveridge, W. H. 1942. Social insurance and allied services: the Beveridge Report in brief. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Beveridge, W. H. 1944. Full employment in a free society: a report. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Bhaduri, A. 1970. ‘A physical analogue to the reswitching problem’. Oxford Economic Papers 22: 148–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bharadwaj, K. 1970. ‘On the maximum number of switches between two production systems’. Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik 106: 409–29.Google Scholar
Bharadwaj, K. 1978. Classical political economy and rise to dominance of supply and demand theories. Calcutta: Orient Longman.Google Scholar
Bhaskar, R. 1978. A realist theory of science. Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Press.Google Scholar
Biasco, S. 1987. ‘Currency cycles and the international economy’. BNL Quarterly Review 40(160): 3160.Google Scholar
Biasco, S. 1988. ‘Dynamic and incapsulating processes in the generation of the world demand’. BNL Quarterly Review 41(165): 179215.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1987. ‘Modeling rational players: Part I’. Economics and Philosophy 3: 179214.Google Scholar
Black, D. 1958. The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Black, F. and Scholes, M. 1973. ‘The pricing of options and corporate liabilities’. Journal of Political Economy 81: 637–54.Google Scholar
Blair, J. 2009. ‘Taking aim at the new international economic order’. In Mirowski and Plehwe, 2009, pp. 347–85.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Leigh, D. 2013. Growth forecast errors and fiscal multipliers. Washington: IMF Working Paper.Google Scholar
Blaug, M. 1980. The methodology of economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bleichrodt, H. and Wakker, P. P. 2015. ‘Regret theory: a bold alternative to the alternatives’. Economic Journal 125: 493512.Google Scholar
Blyth, M. 2013. Austerity: the history of a dangerous idea. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bobbio, N. 1994. Destra e sinistra: ragioni e significati di una distinzione politica. Rome: Donzelli; IV ed., 2004.Google Scholar
Boggio, L. and Seravalli, G. 2003. Lo sviluppo economico: fatti, teorie, politiche. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, E. von. 1889. Kapital und Kapitalzins. zweite Abteilung: Positive Theorie des Kapitales. Innsbruck: Verlag der Wagner’schen Universitäts-Buchhandlung. Italian transl., La teoria positiva del capitale. Turin: Utet, 1968.Google Scholar
Böhme, R., Christin, N., Edelman, B. and Moore, T. 2015. ‘Bitcoin: economics, technology, and governance’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 29: 213–38.Google Scholar
Boianovsky, M. and Hoover, K. D. 2014. ‘In the kingdom of Solovia: the rise of growth economics at MIT, 1956–70’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplement): 198228.Google Scholar
Box, G. E. P. and Jenkins, J. M. 1970. Time series analysis: forecasting and control. San Francisco: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
Boyer, R. 1990. The regulation school: a critical introduction. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Breglia, A. 1965. Reddito sociale. Rome: Edizioni dell’Ateneo.Google Scholar
Brenner, R. 1978. ‘Dobb on the transition from feudalism to capitalism’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 2: 121–40.Google Scholar
Brennetot, A. 2014. ‘Geohistory of neoliberalism’. Cybergeo: European Journal of Geography, art. 677. www.cybergeo.revues.org/26324.Google Scholar
Brundtland, G. H., ed. 1987. Our common future (Brundtland Report, World Commission on Environment and Development). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bruni, L. and Zamagni, S. 2004. Economia civile: efficienza, equità e pubblica felicità. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. 1986. ‘Better than plowing’. BNL Quarterly Review 39(159): 359–75.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. 1989. Stato, mercato e libertà. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. 1962. The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Burmeister, E. 1974. ‘Synthesizing the neo-Austrian and alternative approaches to capital theory: a survey’. Journal of Economic Literature 12: 413–56.Google Scholar
Burmeister, E. 1977. ‘On the social significance of the reswitching controversy’. Revue d’économie politique 87: 330–50.Google Scholar
Burmeister, E. 1979. ‘Professor Pasinetti’s “unobtrusive postulate”, regular economies, and the existence of a well-behaved production function’. Revue d’économie politique 89: 644–52.Google Scholar
Button, K. 2015. ‘A book, the application, and the outcomes: how right was Alfred Kahn in ‘The economics of regulation’ about the effects of the deregulation of the US domestic airline market?’. History of Political Economy 47: 139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caldwell, B. J. 2004. Hayek’s challenge: an intellectual biography of F. A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Caldwell, B. J. 2011. ‘The Chicago school, Hayek, and neoliberalism’. In van Horn et al., pp. 301–34.Google Scholar
Camerer, C., Loewenstein, G. and Prelec, D. 2005. ‘Neuroeconomics: how neuroscience can inform economics’. Journal of Economic Literature 43: 964.Google Scholar
Cantillon, R. 1755. Essai sur la nature du commerce en general. London: Fletcher Gyles. Repr. with an English transl. ed. by Higgs, H.. London: Macmillan 1931; repr. New York: M. Kelley 1964.Google Scholar
Carlin, W. and Soskice, D. 1990. Macroeconomics and the wage bargain. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Casadio Tarabusi, E. and Guarini, G. 2016. ‘Level dependence of the adjustment for unbalance and inequality for the Human Development Index’. Social Indicators Research 126: 527–53.Google Scholar
Cassel, G. 1918. Theoretische Sozialökonomie. Leipzig: C. F. Winter, English transl., Theory of social economy. London: T. F. Unwin 1923.Google Scholar
Chafuen, A. A. 1986. Christians for freedom: Late-Scholastic economics. San Francisco: Ignatius Press.Google Scholar
Chamberlin, E. 1933. The theory of monopolistic competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chandler, A. D. 1990. Scale and scope: the dynamics of industrial capitalism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chenery, H. B. 1955. ‘The role of industrialization in development programs’. American Economic Review 45: 4057.Google Scholar
Chenery, H. B. 1960. ‘Patterns of industrial growth’. American Economic Review 50: 624–54.Google Scholar
Cherrier, B. 2014. ‘Towards a history of economics at MIT, 1940–72’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplement): 1544.Google Scholar
Chilosi, A., ed. 1979. Kalecki. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Chrystal, K. A., ed. 1990. Monetarism. 2 vols. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Ciocca, P. and Rinaldi, R. 1997. ‘L’inflazione in Italia, 1914–20. Considerazioni a margine della tesi di laurea di Piero Sraffa’. Rivista di storia economica 13: 340.Google Scholar
Cipolletta, I. 1992. Congiuntura economica e previsione. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Clapham, J. A. 1922. ‘Of empty economic boxes’. Economic Journal 32: 305–14.Google Scholar
Clark, J. M. 1940. ‘Toward a concept of workable competition’. American Economic Review 30: 241–56.Google Scholar
Clower, R. W. 1965. ‘The Keynesian counter-revolution: a theoretical appraisal’. In Hahn, F. H. and Brechling, F. P. R. (eds.), The theory of interest rates. London: Macmillan, pp. 103–25.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1937. ‘The nature of the firm’. Economica 4; repr. in Coase 1988, pp. 3355.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1960. ‘The problem of social cost’. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 144; repr. in Coase 1988, pp. 95–156.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1988. The firm, the market and the law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Coddington, A. 1983. Keynesian economics: the search for first principles. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Colletti, L. 1968. Il marxismo ed Hegel. Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Collier, P. 2013. Exodus: how migration is changing our world. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Comim, F., Qizilbash, M. and Alkire, S., eds. 2008. The capability approach: concepts, measures and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Condorcet, J.-A.-N., Caritat, marquis de 1785. Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des decisions rendues à la pluralité des voix. Paris: Imprimerie Royale.Google Scholar
Conlisk, J. 1996. ‘Why bounded rationality?’. Journal of Economic Literature 34: 669700.Google Scholar
Corsi, M., ed. 1995. Le diseguaglianze economiche. Turin: Giappichelli.Google Scholar
Costa, S. 2004. Antitrust e software: il caso Microsoft. Rome: Carocci.Google Scholar
Crew, M.A. and Kleindorfer, P.R. 2002. ‘Regulatory economics: twenty years of progress?’. Journal of Regulatory Economics 21: 522.Google Scholar
Croce, B. and Einaudi, L. 1957. Liberismo e liberalismo. Ed. by Solari, P.. Milan and Naples: Riccardo Ricciardi.Google Scholar
Cross, R. 1982. ‘The Duhem-Quine thesis, Lakatos and the appraisal of theories in macroeconomics’. Economic Journal 92: 320–40.Google Scholar
Cyert, R., Simon, H. and Trow, D. B. 1956. ‘Observation of a business decision’. Journal of Business 29: 237–48.Google Scholar
Dahrendorf, R. 1959. Class and class conflict in industrial society. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Dahrendorf, R. 1995. Quadrare il cerchio. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Dallera, G. 2013. ‘La “scuola” italiana di scienza delle finanze’. Moneta e Credito 66(161): 4593.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. 1859. On the origin of species by means of natural selection. London: Murray.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. 1871. The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex. London: Murray.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, P. S. and Heal, G. M. 1979. Economic theory and exhaustible resources. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
David, P. 1985. ‘Clio and the economics of QWERTY’. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 75: 332–7.Google Scholar
Davidson, P. 1972. Money and the real world. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Davidson, P. 2007. John Maynard Keynes. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Deaton, A. 1980. Economics and consumer behavior. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Deaton, A. 1997. The analysis of household surveys: a microeconometric approach to development policy. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of value: an axiomatic analysis of economic equilibrium. Cowles Foundation Monograph n. 17. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Debreu, G. 1974. ‘Excess demand functions’. Journal of Mathematical Economics 1: 1523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Cecco, M. 1993. ‘Piero Sraffa’s “Monetary inflation in Italy during and after the war”: an introduction’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 17: 15.Google Scholar
De Clippel, J. 2008. ‘Equity, envy and efficiency under asymmetric information’. Economics Letters 99: 265–7.Google Scholar
de Finetti, B. 1930. ‘Fondamenti logici del ragionamento probabilistico’. Bollettino dell’Unione matematica italiana 9: 258–61.Google Scholar
de Finetti, B. 1931. Probabilismo: saggio critico sulla teoria delle probabilità e sul valore della scienza. Napoli: Perrella.Google Scholar
de Finetti, B. 1937. ‘La prévision, ses lois logiques, ses sources subjectives’. Annales de l’Institut Henri Poincaré 7: 168.Google Scholar
de Finetti, B. 1974. ‘The value of studying subjective evaluations of probability’. In von Holstein, C.-A. S. (ed.), The concept of probability in psychological experiments. Dordrecht-Boston: Reidel.Google Scholar
Delli Gatti, D., Gaffeo, E., Gallegati, M., Giulioni, G. and Palestrini, A. 2008. Emergent macroeconomics: an agent-based approach to business fluctuations. New York: Springer Science+Business Media.Google Scholar
Denison, E. F. 1967. Why growth rates differ: post-war experience in nine Western countries. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Desai, M. 1989. ‘The scourge of monetarism: Kaldor on monetarism and on money’. In Lawson et al., pp. 171–82.Google Scholar
De Vivo, G. 2017. Nella bufera del Novecento: Antonio Gramsci e Piero Sraffa tra lotta politica e teoria critica. Rome: Castelvecchi.Google Scholar
Diggins, J. P. 1999. Thorstein Veblen, theorist of the leisure class. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
D’Ippoliti, C. 2011. Economics and diversity. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1928. Russian economic development since the revolution. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1946. Studies in the development of capitalism. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1955. On economic theories and socialism. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1973. Theories of value and distribution since Adam Smith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dobb, M., Sweezy, P., Takabashi, H., Hilton, R. and Hill, C. 1954. The transition from feudalism to capitalism: a symposium. New York: Arena Publications.Google Scholar
Domar, E. D. 1946. ‘Capital expansion, rate of growth and employment’. Econometrica 14: 137–47.Google Scholar
Donaldson, B. and Storeygard, A. 2016. ‘The view from above: applications of satellite data in economics’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 30: 171–98.Google Scholar
Donzelli, F. 1986. Il concetto di equilibrio nella teoria economica neoclassica. Rome: NIS.Google Scholar
Donzelli, F. 1988. ‘Introduzione’. In von Hayek, F.A., Conoscenza, mercato, pianificazione. Bologna: il Mulino, pp. 791.Google Scholar
Dorfman, R. 1991. ‘Review article: economic development from the beginning to Rostow’. Journal of Economic Literature 29: 573–91.Google Scholar
Dorfman, R., Samuelson, P. and Solow, R. 1958. Linear programming and economic analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. 1984. Technical change and industrial transformation. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Dosi, G., Freeman, C., Nelson, R., Silverberg, G. and Soete, L., eds. 1988. Technical change and economic theory. London: Pinter.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. and Roventini, A. 2017. ‘Agent-based macroeconomics and classical political economy: some Italian roots’. Italian Economic Journal 3: 261–83.Google Scholar
Dougherty, C. R. S. 1972. ‘On the rate of return and the rate of profit’. Economic Journal 82: 1324–50.Google Scholar
Downs, A. 1957. An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Downs, A. 1967. Inside bureaucracy. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Drèze, J. and Sen, A., eds. 1990. The political economy of hunger. 3 vols. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Duffie, D. and Sonnenschein, H. 1989. ‘Arrow and general equilibrium theory’. Journal of Economic Literature 27: 565–98.Google Scholar
Dunlop, J. T. 1938. ‘The movement of real and money wage rates’. Economic Journal 48: 413–34.Google Scholar
Eatwell, J. 1975. ‘Mr. Sraffa’s standard commodity and the rate of exploitation’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 89: 543–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P., eds. 1987. The new Palgrave: a dictionary of economics. 4 vols. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Edwards, W. 1961. ‘Behavioral decision theory’. Annual Review of Psychology 12: 473–98.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, T. 1990. Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Egidi, M. and Rizzello, S., eds. 2004. Cognitive economics. 2 vols. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Eichner, A. S. 1976. The megacorp and oligopoly. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ellsberg, D. 1961. ‘Risk, ambiguity and the Savage axioms’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 75: 643–69; repr. in Gärdenfors and Sahlin 1988, pp. 245–69.Google Scholar
Emmet, R.B. 2011. ‘Sharpening tools in the workshop’. In van Horn et al., pp. 93115.Google Scholar
Eucken, W. 1949. ‘Die Wettbewerbsordnung und ihre Vertwirklichung’. ORDO 2: 199. English transl. The competitive order and its implementation, 2006, http://cpi.esapience.org.Google Scholar
Fama, E. 1970. ‘Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work’. Journal of Finance 25: 383417.Google Scholar
Fama, E. and French, K. 2010. ‘Luck versus skill in the cross-section of mutual funds returns’. Journal of Finance 65: 1915–47.Google Scholar
Fanon, F. 1961. Les damnés de la terre. Paris: François Maspero; Italian transl., I dannati della terra. Milan: Edizioni di Comunità, 2000.Google Scholar
Faucci, R. 1986. Einaudi. Turin: Utet.Google Scholar
Felipe, J. and McCombie, J. 2013. The aggregate production function and the measurement of technical change. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Ferguson, C. E. 1969. The neoclassical theory of production and distribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fischer, R. 2009. ‘The influence of neoliberals in Chile before, during and after Pinochet’. In Mirowski and Plehwe, pp. 305–46.Google Scholar
Fischer, S. 1977. ‘Long-term contracts, rational expectations and the optimal money supply rule’. Journal of Political Economy 85: 191205.Google Scholar
Fitoussi, J.-P., Sen, A. and Stiglitz, J. 2009. Report by the Commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress. Paris. www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/en/index.htm.Google Scholar
Fleming, J. M. 1962. ‘Domestic financial policies under fixed and floating exchange rates’. IMF Staff Papers 9: 369–79.Google Scholar
Flux, A. W. 1894. ‘Review: K. Wicksell, Über Wert, Kapital und Rente; P. H. Wicksteed, An essay on the coordination of the laws of distribution’. Economic Journal 4: 305–13.Google Scholar
Foley, D. 1967. ‘Resource allocation and the public sector’. Yale Economic Essays 7: 4598.Google Scholar
Foley, D. 1986. Understanding capital. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Forni, M. and Lippi, M. 1997. Aggregation and the microfoundations of dynamic macroeconomics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Foucault, M. 2004. Naissance de la biopolitique: cours au Collège de France 1978–1979. Paris: Seuil-Gallimard. Italian transl., Nascita della biopolitica. Milan: Feltrinelli, 2005; UE Feltrinelli, III ed., 2017.Google Scholar
Frankel, P. H. 1946. Essentials of petroleum. II ed. London: Frank Cass 1969.Google Scholar
Frenkel, J. and Johnson, H. G., eds. 1976. The monetary approach to the balance of payments. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1953. Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1956a. ‘The quantity theory of money: a restatement’. In Friedman 1956b, pp. 3–21.Google Scholar
Friedman, M., ed. 1956b. Studies in the quantity theory of money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1957. A theory of the consumption function. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1960. A program for monetary stability. New York: Fordham University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1962. Price theory. Chicago: Aldine; repr. 2007.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1968. ‘The role of monetary policy’. American Economic Review 58: 117.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1969. The optimum quantity of money and other essays. Chicago: Aldine.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1974. Milton Friedman’s monetary framework: a debate with his critics. Ed. by Gordon, R. J.. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1977. From Galbraith to economic freedom. Occasional Paper 49. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. 1963. A monetary history of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A. 1982. Monetary trends in the United States and the United Kingdom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Frisch, R. 1933. ‘Editorial’. Econometrica 1: 14.Google Scholar
Fuà, G., ed. 1976. Il ‘Modellaccio’: modello dell’economia italiana elaborato dal gruppo di Ancona. 4 vols. Milan: Franco Angeli.Google Scholar
Fuà, G. 1993. Crescita economica: le insidie delle cifre. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. 1991. Game theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Furtado, C. 1964. Development and underdevelopment. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Furtado, C. 1970. Théorie du développement économique. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France. Italian transl., Teoria dello sviluppo economico. Bari: Laterza, 1972.Google Scholar
Galavotti, M. C. 2005. Philosophical introduction to probability. Stanford: CSLI Publications.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1952. American capitalism: the concept of countervailing power. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1955. The great crash. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1958. The affluent society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1967. The new industrial state. Boston: Houghton Mifflin; repr. Harmondsworth: Penguin 1967.Google Scholar
Galbraith, James K. 2008. The predator state. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Galilei, G. 1623. Il Saggiatore. Rome: Accademici dei Lincei; repr. in Opere. Milan and Naples: Ricciardi 1953, pp. 89–352.Google Scholar
Gallaway, L. and Shukla, V. 1974. ‘The neoclassical production function’. American Economic Review 64: 348–58.Google Scholar
Garcia Duarte, P. 2014. ‘The early years of the MIT PhD program in industrial economics’. History of Political Economy 65 (Supplement): 81108.Google Scholar
Gärdenfors, P. and Sahlin, N. E. 1982. ‘Unreliable probabilities, risk taking, and decision making’. Synthese 53: 361–86; repr. in Gärdenfors and Sahlin 1988, pp. 313–34.Google Scholar
Gärdenfors, P. and Sahlin, N. E., eds. 1988. Decision, probability and utility. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gårdlund, T. 1956. Knut Wicksell, rebell l det nya riket. Stockholm: Bonniers. English transl., The life of Knut Wicksell. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 1996.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1960. Il capitale nelle teorie della distribuzione. Milan: Giuffrè.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1970. ‘Heterogeneous capital, the production function and the theory of distribution’. Review of Economic Studies 37: 407–36.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1976. ‘The neoclassical production function: comment’. American Economic Review 66: 424–7.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1979. Valore e domanda effettiva. Turin: Einaudi.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1981. Marx e gli economisti classici. Turin: Einaudi.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1984. ‘Value and distribution in the classical economists and Marx’. Oxford Economic Papers 36: 291325.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1990a. Sraffa: ‘Classical versus Marginalist analysis’. Bharadwaj, K. and Schefold, B. (eds.). Essays on Sraffa. London: Unwin Hyman 1990, pp. 112–41.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1990b. ‘On some supposed obstacles to the tendency of market prices towards natural prices’. Political Economy 6: 329–59.Google Scholar
Garrison, R. W. 1978. Austrian macroeconomics: a diagrammatic exposition. Menlo Park, CA: Institute for Humane Studies.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1936. ‘The pure theory of consumer’s behavior’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 50: 545–93.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1954. ‘Choice, expectation and measurability’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 68: 503–34.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1966. Analytical economics: issues and problems. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1971. The entropy law and the economic process. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1972. ‘Process analysis and the neoclassical theory of production’. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 54: 279–94.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1976. Energy and economic myths. New York: Pergamon.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1988. ‘An emigrant from a developing country: autobiographical notes – I’. BNL Quarterly Review 41 (164): 332; repr. in J. Kregel ed. Recollections of eminent economists, vol. 2. London: Macmillan, 1989, pp. 99–127.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1993. ‘An emigrant from a developing country: autobiographical notes– II’. BNL Quarterly Review 46 (184): 330.Google Scholar
Geroski, P. A. and Schwalbach, J., eds. 1991. Entry and market contestability. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Gilibert, G. 1990. ‘La scuola russo-tedesca di economia matematica e la dottrina del flusso circolare’. In Becattini, G. (ed.), Il pensiero economico: temi, problemi e scuole. Turin: Utet, pp. 387403.Google Scholar
Gilibert, G. 1998. ‘Mani visibili, invisibili, nascoste’. In Sissa-Laboratorio interdisciplinare, Laboratorio dell’immaginario scientifico, Adam Smith e dintorni. Naples: Cuen, pp. 137–56.Google Scholar
Gini, C. 1912. Variabilità e mutabilità: contributo allo studio delle distribuzioni e delle relazioni statistiche, Bologna: Paolo Cuppin; repr. in Biblioteca dell’economista, series V, vol. 13, pp. 1151.Google Scholar
Giraud, Y. 2014. ‘Negotiating the “middle-of-the-road” position: Paul Samuelson, MIT and the politics of textbook writing, 1945–55’. History of Political Economy 65 (Supplement): 135–52.Google Scholar
Godfrey-Smith, P. 2009. Darwinian populations and natural selections. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Godley, W. and Izurieta, A. 2004. ‘The US economy: weaknesses of the “strong” recovery’. BNL Quarterly Review 57(229): 131–9.Google Scholar
Godley, W. and Lavoie, M. 2007. Monetary economics: an integrated approach to credit, money, income, production and wealth. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Goodfriend, M. and King, R. G. 1997. ‘The new neoclassical synthesis and the role of monetary policy’. In Bernanke, B. S. and Rotenberg, J. J. (eds.), NBER macroeconomics annal : 1997. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Goodhart, C. A. E. 1997. ‘Whither now?’. BNL Quarterly Review 50(203): 385430.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R. M. 1967. ‘A growth cycle’. In Feinstein, C. H. (ed.), Socialism, capitalism and economic growth: essays presented to Maurice Dobb. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 54–8.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R. M. 1970. Elementary economics from the higher standpoint. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R. M. 1982a. Essays in economic dynamics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R. M. 1982b. Intervista a un economista. Ed. by M. Palazzi. Biblioteca Walter Bigiavi della Facoltà di economia e commercio dell’Università di Bologna.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R. M. 1990. Chaotic economic dynamics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Gordon, R. J. 2011. ‘The history of the Phillips curve: consensus and bifurcation’. Economica 78: 1050.Google Scholar
Gramsci, A. 1975. Quaderni del carcere. Critical ed., Ed. by Gerratana, V., 4 vols. Turin: Einaudi. English ed., Prison notebooks, 3 vols. New York: Columbia University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Gramsci, A. and Sraffa, P. 1924. ‘Problemi di oggi e di domani’. Ordine nuovo, 1: 4.Google Scholar
Gray, J. 1984. Hayek on liberty. Oxford: Blackwell; repr. 1986.Google Scholar
Graziani, A. 2003. The monetary theory of production. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Greenspan, A. 2009. ‘We need a better cushion against risk’. Financial Times. Supplement on The future of capitalism: the big debate, 12 May.Google Scholar
Greenwood, R. and Scharfstein, D. 2013. ‘The growth of finance’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27: 328.Google Scholar
Grilli, E. 2005. Crescita e sviluppo delle nazioni. Turin: UTET.Google Scholar
Grilli, E. and Yang, M.C. 1988. ‘Primary commodity prices, manufactured good prices, and the terms of trade in developing countries: what the long run shows’. World Bank Economic Review 2: 147.Google Scholar
Grimm, C., Püringer, S. and Kapeller, J. 2018. ‘Paradigms and policies: the state of economics in German-speaking countries’. ICAE Working Paper Series 77, Linz: Johannes Kepler University.Google Scholar
Haavelmo, T. 1944. ‘The probability approach in econometrics’. Econometrica 12 (Supplement): 1118.Google Scholar
Haavelmo, T. 1945. ‘Multiplier effect of a balanced budget’. Econometrica 13: 311–18.Google Scholar
Hacking, I. 1990. The taming of chance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hagemann, H. 2013. ‘Germany after World War II: ordoliberalism, the social market economy and Keynesianism’. History of Economic Theory and Policy 1: 3751.Google Scholar
Hahn, F. 1965. ‘On some problems of proving the existence of equilibrium in a monetary economy’. In Hahn, F. and Brechling, F. (eds.), The theory of interest rates. London: Macmillan, pp. 126–35.Google Scholar
Hahn, F. 1973. On the notion of equilibrium in economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hahn, F. 1982. ‘Stability’. In Arrow, K. and Intriligator, M. (eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics. Amsterdam: North Holland, vol. 2, chapter 16.Google Scholar
Hahn, F. and Matthews, R. C. O. 1964. ‘The theory of economic growth: a survey’. Economic Journal 74: 779902.Google Scholar
Hall, P. and Soskice, D., eds. 2001. Varieties of capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hammond, J. D. 2015. ‘Paul Samuelson on public goods: the road to nihilism’. History of Political Economy 47 (Supplement): 147–73.Google Scholar
Hanappi, G. 2017. ‘Agent-based modeling: history, essence, future’. PSL Quarterly Review 70 (283): 449–72.Google Scholar
Hansen, A. 1938. Full recovery or stagnation? New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Hansen, A. 1949. Monetary theory and fiscal policy. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Hansen, A. 1953. A guide to Keynes. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Harcourt, G. C. 1972. Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Harcourt, G. C. and Laing, N. F., eds. 1971. Capital and growth. Harmondsworth: Penguin.Google Scholar
Hare, R. M. 1982. ‘Ethical theory and utilitarianism’. In Sen and Williams (eds.), pp. 2338.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. 1939. ‘An essay in dynamic theory’. Economic Journal 49: 1433.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. 1951. The life of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. 1961. ‘Review of P. Sraffa, Production of commodities by means of commodities’. Economic Journal 71: 783–87.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. 1977. ‘Morality and the theory of rational behavior’. Social Research 44: 623–56.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. 1988. L’utilitarismo. Milan: Il Saggiatore; II ed., 1994.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. and Selten, R. 1988. A general theory of equilibrium selection in genes. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Harvey, D. 2005. A brief history of neoliberalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. M. and McPherson, M. S. 1996. Economic analysis and moral philosophy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hawkins, D. and Simon, H. 1949. ‘Note: some conditions of macroeconomic stability’. Econometrica 17: 245–8.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1926. ‘Friedrich Freiherr von Wieser’. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 125: 513–30. English transl. in F. Hayek, The fortunes of liberalism. The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol. 4. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1992, pp. 108–25.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1931. Prices and production. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1931–32. ‘Reflections on the pure theory of money of Mr. J. M. Keynes’. Economica 11 (1931): 270–95 and 12 (1932) 2244; repr. in F. Hayek, Contra Keynes and Cambridge, B. Caldwell (ed.), The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol. 9. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995, pp. 121–46 and 174–97.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1932. ‘Money and capital: a reply’. Economic Journal 42: 237–49.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1933. ‘Uber “Neutrales Geld”’. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4 (5): 655–61. English transl., ‘On “neutral” money’. In Hayek 1999a, pp. 228–31.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1935. ‘The nature and history of the problem’ and ‘The state of the debate’. In Hayek, F. (ed.), Collectivist economic planning, London: Routledge; repr. in Hayek 1948, pp. 119–47 and 148–80.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1937. ‘Economics and knowledge’. Economica 4(13): 3354.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1940. ‘Socialist calculation: the competitive “solution”’. Economica 7: 125–49; repr. in Hayek 1948, pp. 181208.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von 1941. The pure theory of capital. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1942. ‘The Ricardo effect’. Economica 9(34): 127–52; repr. in Hayek 1948, pp. 220–54.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1942–4. ‘Scientism and the study of society’. Economica, Part 1 (1942), 9(35): 3463; Part 2 (1943), 10 (37): 34–63; Part 3 (1944), 11 (41): 27–39.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1943. ‘A commodity reserve currency’. Economic Journal 53: 176–84; repr. in Hayek 1999b, pp. 106–14.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1944. The road to serfdom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; repr. 1994.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1945. ‘The use of knowledge in society’. American Economic Review 35: 519–30.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1948. Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1952. The sensory order: an inquiry into the foundations of theoretical psychology. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1960. The constitution of liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1973. Law, legislation and liberty, vol. 1: Rules and order. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1976. Denationalisation of money. London: Institute of economic affairs; II ed., 1978; repr. in Hayek 1999b, pp. 128–229.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1988. Conoscenza, mercato, pianificazione. Ed. by Donzelli, F.. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1991. The trend of economic thinking: essays on political economists and economic history. Bartley, W. W. III and Kresge, S. (eds.), The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol. 3. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1992. The fortunes of liberalism. In P. G. Klein (ed.), The Collected Works of F. A. Hayek, vol. 4. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1994. Hayek on Hayek. Ed. by Kresge, S. and Wenar, L.. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1999a. Good money. Part I. The new world. In Kresge, S. (ed.), The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol. 5. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 1999b. Good money. Part II. The standard. In Kresge, S. (ed.), The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol. 6. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 2011. Autobiografia. Soveria Mannelli: Rubbettino 2011.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. von. 2015. Hayek on Mill: the Mill-Taylor friendship and related writings. In Peart, S. (ed.), The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol. 16. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Heal, G., ed. 1993. The economics of exhaustible resources. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Hendry, D. F. 1980. ‘Econometrics: alchemy or science?’. Economica 47: 387406.Google Scholar
Hennings, K. H. 1997. The Austrian theory of value and capital. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E. and Gintis, H., eds. 2004. Foundations of human sociality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Herndon, T., Ash, M. and Pollin, R. 2013. Does high public debt consistently stifle economic growth? A critique of Reinhart and Rogoff. PERI Working Paper 322.Google Scholar
Heukelom, F. 2014. Behavioral economics: a history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. 1937. ‘Mr. Keynes and the classics: a suggested interpretation’. Econometrica 5: 147–59.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. 1939. Value and capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press; II ed., 1946.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. 1973. Capital and time: a neo-Austrian theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hilferding, R. 1910. Das Finanzkapital. Vienna: Wiener Volksbuchhandlung Ignaz Brand. English transl., Finance capital: a study of the latest phase of capitalist development. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1981.Google Scholar
Hirsch, F. 1976. Social limits to growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1958. The strategy of economic development. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1970. Exit, voice, and loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1977. The passions and the interests. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1982. ‘Rival interpretations of market society: civilizing, destructive, or feeble?’. Journal of Economic Literature 20: 1463–84.Google Scholar
Hobbes, T. 1651. Leviathan. London: Andrew Crooke. Italian transl., Leviatano. Rome and Bari: Laterza, 1974.Google Scholar
Hobbes, T. 1658. De homine. London: Andrew Crooke. Italian transl., De homine. Rome and Bari: Laterza, 1984.Google Scholar
Hobsbawm, E. 1994. Age of extremes: the short twentieth century, 1914–1991. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 1988. Economics and institutions. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 1998. ‘The approach of institutional economics’. Journal of Economic Literature 36: 166–92.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 1999. Evolution and institutions. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Hollander, J. 1904. ‘The development of Ricardo’s theory of value’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 18: 455–91.Google Scholar
Hollander, J. 1910. David Ricardo: a centenary estimate. Baltimore; repr. New York: McKelley, 1968.Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. 1929. ‘Stability in competition’. Economic Journal 39: 4157.Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. 1931. ‘The economics of exhaustible resources’. Journal of Political Economy 39: 137–75.Google Scholar
Howard, M. C. and King, J. E. 2004. ‘The economic contributions of Paul Sweezy’. Review of Political Economy 16: 411–56.Google Scholar
Hume, D. 1752. ‘Of the balance of trade’. In Political discourses. Edinburgh: A. Kincaid and A. Donaldson; repr. in E. F. Miller (ed.), Essays: moral, political, and literary. Indianapolis: Liberty Press 1987, pp. 308–26.Google Scholar
Huntington, S. P. 1996. The clash of civilizations and the remaking of the world order. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Ioannidis, J. P., Stanley, T. D. and Doucouliagos, H. 2017. ‘The power of bias in economic research’. Economic Journal 127: F256F265.Google Scholar
Jackson, D. 2000. The new national accounts. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Janssen, M. C. W., ed. 2004. Auctioning public assets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jeffrey, K. C. 1965. The logic of decision. New York: McGraw-Hill; II ed., Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1865. The coal question. London: Macmillan; repr., New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1871. The theory of political economy. London: Macmillan; II ed. 1879; repr. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1970.Google Scholar
Johansson Heinö, A. 2016. Timbro authoritarian populism index. Stockholm: Timbro.Google Scholar
Johnson, H. G. 1972. The monetary approach to balance of payments theory. In Johnson, H. G., ed., Further essays of monetary economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. and Noll, R. G. 2013. ‘Alfred Kahn, 1917–2010’. Review of Industrial Organization 42: 107–26.Google Scholar
Jossa, B. 2010. Esiste un’alternativa al capitalismo? L’impresa democratica e l’attualità del marxismo. Rome: Manifestolibri.Google Scholar
Kagel, J. and Levin, D. 1986. ‘The winner’s curse and public information in common value actions’. American Economic Review 76: 894920.Google Scholar
Kahn, A. 1970–71. The economics of regulation (vol. 1, Economic principles, 1970; vol. 2, Institutional issues, 1971). New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Kahn, R. F. 1931. ‘The relation of home investment to unemployment’. Economic Journal 41: 173–98; repr. in Kahn 1972, pp. 1–27.Google Scholar
Kahn, R. F. 1954. ‘Some notes on liquidity preference’. Manchester School 22: 229–57; repr. in Kahn 1972, pp. 7296.Google Scholar
Kahn, R. F. 1972. Selected essays on employment and growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kahn, R. F. [1929] 1983. L’economia del breve periodo. Ed. by Dardi, M.. Turin: Boringhieri. English ed., The economics of the short period. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Kahn, R. F. 1984. The making of Keynes’s ‘General theory’. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. 2011. Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. 1979. ‘Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk’. Econometrica 47: 263–91.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1939. ‘Welfare propositions of economics and interpersonal comparisons of utility’. Economic Journal 49: 549–52.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1942. ‘Professor Hayek and the concertina effect’. Economica 9: 359–82.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1956. ‘Alternative theories of distribution’. Review of Economic Studies 23: 94100.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1957. ‘A model of economic growth’. Economic Journal 67: 591624.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1961. ‘Capital accumulation and economic growth’. In Lutz, F. A. (ed.), The theory of capital. London: Macmillan, pp. 177220.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1966. ‘Marginal productivity and the macro-economic theories of distribution: comment on Samuelson and Modigliani’. Review of Economic Studies 33: 309–19.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1970. ‘The new monetarism’. Lloyds Bank Review, July, pp. 1–17; repr. in A. A. Walters (ed.), Money and banking. Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1973, pp. 261–78.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1982. The scourge of monetarism. Oxford: Oxford University Press; II ed., 1985.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. 1943. Studies in economic dynamics. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. 1971. Selected essays on the dynamics of the capitalist economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. 1972. Selected essays on the economic growth of the socialist and the mixed economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kao, Y.-F. and Velupillai, V. 2015. ‘Behavioural economics: classical and modern’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22: 236–71.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1913. Indian currency and finance. London: Macmillan; repr. in J. M. Keynes, Collected writings, vol. 1. London: Macmillan, 1971.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1921. A treatise on probability. London: Macmillan; repr. in J. M. Keynes, Collected writings, vol. 8. London: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1923. A tract on monetary reform. London: Macmillan; repr. in J. M. Keynes, Collected writings, vol. 4. London: Macmillan, 1971.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1930. A treatise on money. 2 vols., London: Macmillan; repr. in J. M. Keynes, Collected writings, vols. 5 and 6. London: Macmillan, 1971.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1931. Essays in persuasion. London: Macmillan; repr. in J. M. Keynes, Collected writings, vol. 9. London: Macmillan, 1972.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan; repr. in J. M. Keynes, Collected writings, vol. 7. London: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1937. ‘Some economic consequences of a declining population’. Eugenics Review 29: 1317; repr. in Keynes 1973, vol. 14, pp. 124–33.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1973. The General Theory and after. In Collected writings, vols. 13 (Part I: preparation) and 14 (Part II: defence and development). Ed. by Moggridge, D.. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1979. The General Theory and after: a supplement. In Collected writings, vol. 29. Ed. by Moggridge, D.. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1980. Activities 1941–1946: shaping the post-war world, Bretton Woods and reparations. In Collected writings, vol. 26. Ed. by Moggridge, D.. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. 1978. Manias, panics and crashes: a history of financial crises. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. 1989. Economic laws and economic history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. 1995. ‘Asset inflation and monetary policy’. BNL Quarterly Review 48(192): 1737.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. 2002. ‘The price level of monetary policy’. BNL Quarterly Review 55(220): 312.Google Scholar
King, J. E. 2015. Post Keynesian economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Kirman, A. 1992. ‘What or whom does the representative individual represent?’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 6: 117–36.Google Scholar
Kirman, A. 2006. ‘Demand theory and general equilibrium: from explanation to introspection, a journey down the wrong road’. History of Political Economy 38 (Supplement): 246–80.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. 1973. Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Klein, L. R. 1991. ‘Econometric contributions of the Cowles Commission, 1944–1947: a retrospective view’. BNL Quarterly Review 44(177): 107–17.Google Scholar
Klugman, J., Rodríguez, F. and Choi, H.-J. 2011. ‘The HDI 2010: new controversies, old critiques’. Journal of Economic Inequalities 9: 249–88.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. 1921. Risk, uncertainty and profit. Boston: Hart, Schaffner & Marx; repr. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1940.Google Scholar
Kosnik, L.-R. 2015. ‘What have economists being doing for the last 50 years? A text analysis of published academic research from 1960–2010’. Economics. The open-access, open-assessment e-journal 9(13): 137.Google Scholar
Krautkraemer, J. A. 1998. ‘Nonrenewable resource scarcity’. Journal of Economic Literature 36: 2065–107.Google Scholar
Kravis, J. B. 1976. ‘A survey of international comparisons of productivity’. Economic Journal 86: 144.Google Scholar
Kravis, J. B., Heston, A. W. and Summers, R. 1978. ‘Real GDP per capita of more than one hundred countries’. Economic Journal 88: 215–42.Google Scholar
Kregel, J. A. 1976. ‘Economic methodology in the face of uncertainty: the modelling methods of Keynes and the post-Keynesians’. Economic Journal 86: 209–25.Google Scholar
Kregel, J. A. 1980a. ‘Economic dynamics and the theory of steady growth: an historical essay on Harrod’s “knife edge”’. History of Political Economy 12: 97123.Google Scholar
Kregel, J. A. 1980b. ‘Markets and institutions as features of a capitalistic production system’. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 3: 3248.Google Scholar
Kregel, J. A. 1996. Origini e sviluppo dei mercati finanziari. Arezzo: Banca popolare dell’Etruria e del Lazio.Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M. 1990. Game theory and economic modelling. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Krouse, C. G. 1990. Theory of industrial economics. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. R. 1990. Rethinking international trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kuhn, T. S. 1962. The structure of scientific revolutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; II ed. 1970.Google Scholar
Kula, W. 1958. Rozwazania o historii. Warszawa: Państwowe Wydawnictwo Naukowe. Italian transl., Riflessioni sulla storia. Venezia: Marsilio, 1990.Google Scholar
Kurz, H. and Salvadori, N. 1995. Theory of production: a long period analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. 1955. ‘Economic growth and income inequality’. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 45: 128.Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. 1965. Towards a theory of economic growth. New York: W. W. Norton & Co.; repr. 1968.Google Scholar
Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. 1977. ‘Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans’. Journal of Political Economy 85: 473–92.Google Scholar
Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. 1982. ‘Time to build and aggregate fluctuations’. Economica 50: 1345–70.Google Scholar
Lachmann, L. 1956. Capital and its structures. London: Bell & Sons; new ed., Institute for Humane Studies, Menlo Park, and Cato Institute, San Francisco, 1978.Google Scholar
Lachmann, L. 1986. The market as an economic process. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Laffont, J.-J. and Tirole, J. 1993. A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Laidler, D. 1985. The demand for money: theories, evidence and problems. New York: Harper Collins; new ed., London: Pearson, 1997.Google Scholar
Lakatos, I. 1978. The methodology of scientific research programmes. Philosophical papers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lancaster, K. 1966. ‘A new approach to consumer theory’. Journal of Political Economy 74: 132–57.Google Scholar
Lancaster, K. 1971. Consumer demand: a new approach. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Landes, D.S. 1986. ‘What do bosses really do?’. Journal of Economic History 46: 585623.Google Scholar
Lange, O. 1936–7. ‘On the economic theory of socialism’. Review of Economic Studies 4: 5371 and 123–42.Google Scholar
Lange, O. 1942. ‘The foundations of welfare economics’. Econometrica 10: 215–28.Google Scholar
Latouche, S. 2006. Le pari de la décroissance. Paris: Librairie Arthème Fayard. Italian transl., La scommessa della decrescita. Milan: Feltrinelli, 2007.Google Scholar
Lawson, T. 1994. ‘The nature of Post Keynesianism and its links to other traditions’. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 16: 503–38.Google Scholar
Lawson, T. 1997. Economics & reality. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lawson, T., Palma, J. G. and Sender, J., eds. 1989. Kaldor’s political economy. London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Layard, R. 2005. Happiness. Harmondsworth: Penguin. Italian transl., Felicità. Milan: Rizzoli, 2005.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, H. 1966. ‘Allocative efficiency vs. “X-efficiency”’. American Economic Review 56: 392415.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. 1968. On Keynesian economics and the economics of Keynes. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lenin, (Vladimir Ilyich Ulianov). 1898. Italian transl., Lo sviluppo del capitalismo in Russia. Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1955.Google Scholar
Lenin, (Vladimir Ilyich Ulianov). 1916. Italian transl., L’imperialismo fase suprema del capitalism. Rome: Edizioni Rinascita, 1956.Google Scholar
Leontief, W. 1941. The structure of the American economy, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press; II ed., 1951.Google Scholar
Leontief, W., Carter, A. P. and Petri, P. A. 1977. The future of the world economy: a United Nations study. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lerner, A. 1934. ‘The concept of monopoly and the measurement of monopoly power’. Review of Economic Studies 1: 157–75.Google Scholar
Lerner, A. and Colander, D. 1980. MAP, a market anti-inflation plan. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Levhari, D. 1965. ‘A nonsubstitution theorem and switching of techniques’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 79: 98105.Google Scholar
Levhari, D. and Samuelson, P. 1966. ‘The nonswitching theorem is false’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 518–19.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. A. 1954. ‘Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour’. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 22: 139–91.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. 1999. Patterns of democracy: government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press; II ed., 2014.Google Scholar
Lindahl, E. R. 1939. Studies in the theory of money and capital. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Lindbeck, A. and Snower, D. J. 1988. The insider-outsider theory of employment and unemployment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Lindert, P. H. 2004. Growing public. 2 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lippi, M. 1979. I prezzi di produzione. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Lipsey, R. G. 1960. ‘The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates: a further analysis’. Economica 27: 131.Google Scholar
Little, I. M. D. 1950. A critique of welfare economics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Loomes, G. and Sugden, R. 1982. ‘Regret theory: an alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty’. Economic Journal 92: 805–24.Google Scholar
Loomes, G. and Sugden, R. 1987. ‘Testing for regret and disappointment in choice under uncertainty’. Economic Journal 97 (Supplement): 118–29.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. 1972. ‘Expectations and the neutrality of money’. Journal of Economic Theory 4: 103–24.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. 1976. ‘Econometric policy evaluation: a critique’. In Brenner, K. and Meltzer, A. M. (eds.), The Phillips curve and labor markets. Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 1946.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. 1988. ‘On the mechanics of economic development’. Journal of Monetary Economics 22: 342.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. 2003. ‘Macroeconomic priorities’. American Economic Review 93: 114.Google Scholar
Lukes, S. 2003. Liberals & cannibals: the implications of diversity. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Lutz, V. 1958. ‘The growth process in a “dual” economic system’. BNL Quarterly Review 11(46): 279325.Google Scholar
Luxemburg, R. 1913. Die Akkumulation des Kapitals: ein Beitrag zur ökonomischen Erklärung Des Imperialismus. Berlin: Paul Singer. Italian transl., L’accumulazione del capitale. Turin: Einaudi, 1960; repr., 1968.Google Scholar
Maas, H. 2014. ‘Making things technical: Samuelson at MIT’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplenement): 272–94.Google Scholar
Machina, M. 1983. ‘Generalized expected utility analysis and the nature of observed violations of the independence axiom’. In Stigum, B. P. and Wenstøp, F. (eds.), Foundations of utility and risk theory with applications. Dordrecht: D. Reidel, pp. 263–93; repr. in Gärdenfors and Sahlin 1982, pp. 215–43.Google Scholar
Machlup, F. 1976. ‘Hayek’s contribution to economics’. In Essays on Hayek. Ed. by Machlup, F.. Hillsdale, MI: Hillsdale College Press, pp. 1359.Google Scholar
Machlup, F. 1978. Methodology of economics and other social sciences. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
MacLean, N. 2017. Democracy in chains: the deep history of the radical right’s stealth plan for America. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. 1984. ‘Origins and impact of the welfare state, 1883–1983’. BNL Quarterly Review 37(148): 5587.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. 2007. Contours of the world economy, 1–2030 AD. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Malcolm, N. 1958. Ludwig Wittgenstein: a memoir. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Malinvaud, E. 1977. The theory of unemployment reconsidered. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Malinvaud, E. 1987. ‘The overlapping generations model in 1947’. Journal of Economic Literature 25: 103–5.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. G. 1985. ‘Small menu costs and hedge business cycles: a macroeconomic model of monopoly’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 529–39.Google Scholar
Mantel, R. 1974. ‘On the characterisation of aggregate excess demand’. Journal of Economic Theory 7: 348–53.Google Scholar
Tse-tung., Mao 1960. Selected works. 5 vols. Peking: Foreign Languages Press.Google Scholar
Marcuse, H. 1956. One-dimensional man. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Marcuzzo, M. C. 2005. ‘Robinson and Sraffa’. In Gibson, D. (ed.), The economic legacy of Joan Robinson. Cheltenham: Elgar, pp. 2942.Google Scholar
Marglin, S. A. 1974. ‘What do bosses do?’. Review of Radical Political Economy 6: 60112.Google Scholar
Markowitz, H. 1952. ‘Portfolio selection’. Journal of Finance 7: 7791.Google Scholar
Marris, R. 1964. The economic theory of ‘managerial’ capitalism. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics. London: Macmillan; VIII ed., 1920; critical ed., C. W. Guillebaud ed., 2 vols. London: Macmillan, 1961.Google Scholar
Marx, K. [1844] 1932. Ökonomisch-philosophische Manuskripte aus dem Jahre 1844. In Karl Marx – Friedrich Engels Historisc-kritische Gesamtausgabe. Ed. by Adoratskij, V.. Berlin: Marx-Engels Gesamtausgabe (MEGA). Italian transl., Manoscritti economico-filosofici del 1844. Turin: Einaudi, 1949, II ed., 1968.Google Scholar
Marx, K. 1867–94. Das Kapital. 3 vols. Hamburg: O. Meissner. Italian transl., Il capitale. Rome: Editori Riuniti, 1968.Google Scholar
Marx, K. 1905–10. Theorien über den Mehrwert. Ed. by Kautsky, K.. Stuttgart: Dietz. English transl., Theories of surplus-value. Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House and London: Lawrence and Wishart, Part 1, 1963; Part 2, 1969; Part 3, 1972.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A. 1985. The theory of general economic equilibrium: a differentiable approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D. and Green, J. R. 1995. Microeconomic theory. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mazzucato, M. C. 2011. The entrepreneurial state. London: Anthem Press.Google Scholar
Mazzucato, M. C. 2018. The value of everything. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
McAfee, R. P. and McMillar, J. 1987. ‘Auctions and biddings’. Journal of Economic Literature 25: 699738.Google Scholar
McClure, S. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G. and Cohen, J. D. 2004. ‘Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards’. Science 306: 503–7.Google Scholar
McKenzie, L. 1954. ‘On equilibrium in Graham’s model of world trade and other competitive systems’. Econometrica 22: 147–61.Google Scholar
Meade, J. 1972. ‘The theory of labour-managed firms and of profit sharing’. Economic Journal 82: 402–28.Google Scholar
Meadows, D. H., Meadows, D. L., Randers, D. L. and Beherens, W. W. III 1972. The limits to growth. New York: New American Library.Google Scholar
Meagher, K. 2019. ‘Reflections of an engaged economist: an interview with Thandika Mkandawire’. Development and Change, in press.Google Scholar
Medema, S. G. 2011. ‘Chicago price theory and Chicago law and economics’. In van Horn et al., pp. 151–79.Google Scholar
Medio, A. 1972. ‘Profits and surplus value: appearance and reality in capitalist production’. In Hunt, E. K. and Schwartz, J. G. (eds.), A critique of economic theory. Harmondsworth: Penguin, pp. 312–46.Google Scholar
Meek, R. 1961. ‘Mr. Sraffa’s rehabilitation of classical economics’. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 8: 119–36. Repr. in Meek 1967.Google Scholar
Meek, R. 1967. Economics and ideology and other essays. London: Chapman and Hall.Google Scholar
Ménard, C., ed. 2004. The international library of the new institutional economics. 7 vols. Abingdon: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Menger, C. 1871. Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre. Vienna: Braumuller; II ed. Ed. by K. Menger, 1923. Italian transl., Principi di economia politica. Turin: Utet, 1976.Google Scholar
Michael, R. and Becker, G. S. 1973. ‘On the new theory of consumer behaviour’. Swedish Journal of Economics 75: 378–96.Google Scholar
Milanovic, B. 2016. Global inequality. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1848. Principles of political economy. London: John W. Parker.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1859. On liberty. London: John W. Parker; repr. in Essays on politics and society. Part I, vol. 18, Collected works of John Stuart Mill. Ed. by J. M. Robson. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1977, pp. 213–310.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1861. ‘Utilitarianism’. Fraser’s Magazine 64: 383–4; repr. in J. S. Mill and J. Bentham, Utilitarianism and other essays. Ed. by A. Ryan. London: Penguin Books, 1987, pp. 272–338.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1873. Autobiography. London: Longmans, Green Read and Dyer; repr., London: Oxford University Press, 1971.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 1964. ‘Financial crisis, financial systems and the performance of the economy’. In Commission on money and credit: private capital markets. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 1975. John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P., 1982. Can ‘it’ happen again? Essays on instability and finance. Armonk, NY: Sharpe.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 1986. Stabilizing an unstable economy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press; new ed., New York: McGraw–Hill,2008.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 1990. ‘Schumpeter and finance’. In Biasco, S., Roncaglia, A. and Salvati, M. (eds.), Market and institutions in economic development. Houndmills: Macmillan, pp. 103–15.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 2013. Ending poverty: jobs, not welfare. Ed. by Papadimitriou, D.. Annandale-on-Hudson: Levy Economics Institute.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. 2002. Machine dreams: economics becomes a cyborg science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. 2006. ‘Twelve theses concerning the history of postwar neoclassical price theory’. History of Political Economy 38: 343–79.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. 2011. ‘On the origins (at Chicago) of some species of neoliberal evolutionary economics’. In van Horn et al., pp. 237–75.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. and Plehwe, D., eds. 2009. The road from Mont Pèlerin: the making of the neoliberal thought collective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Mirrlees, J. A. 1982. ‘The economic uses of utilitarianism’. In Sen and Williams 1982, pp. 63–84.Google Scholar
Mises, L. von. 1912. Theorie des Geldes und der Umlaufsmittel. Munich: Dunker & Humblot; II ed., 1924.Google Scholar
Mises, L. von. 1920. ‘Die Wirtschaftsrechnung im Sozialistischen Gemeinwesen’. Arkiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 47: 86121. Italian transl., ‘Il calcolo economico nello Stato socialista’. In F. von Hayek et al., Pianificazione economica collettivista. Turin: Einaudi, 1946, pp. 85–124.Google Scholar
Mises, L. von. 1949. Human action: a treatise on economics. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press; II ed., 1963; III ed. Washington, DC: Henry Regnery, 1966.Google Scholar
Mishan, E. J. 1967. The costs of economic growth. London: Staples Press.Google Scholar
Mitchell, T. 2009. ‘How neoliberalism makes its world’. In Mirowski and Plehwe, pp. 386–416.Google Scholar
Mkandawire, T. 2001. ‘Thinking about developmental states in Africa’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 25: 289313.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. 1944. ‘Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money’. Econometrica 12: 4588.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. 1958. ‘New developments on the oligopoly front’. Journal of Political Economy 66: 215–32.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. 1963. ‘The monetary mechanism and its interaction with real phenomena’. Review of Economics and Statistics 45 (Supplement): 79107.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. 1977. ‘The monetarist controversy or, should we forsake stabilization policies?’. American Economic Review 67: 119.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. and Brumberg, R. 1954. ‘Utility analysis and the consumption function: an interpretation of cross-section data’. In Kurihara, K. K. (ed.), Post Keynesian economics. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. 1958. ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment’. American Economic Review 48: 161–97.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. and Tarantelli, E. 1976. ‘Market forces, trade union action, and the Phillips curve in Italy’. PSL Quarterly Review 30(120): 165–98.Google Scholar
Montanaro, E. and Tonveronachi, M. 2012. ‘Financial re-regulation at a crossroad: how the European experience strengthens the case for a radical reform built on Minsky’s approach’. PSL Quarterly Review 65(163): 335–83.Google Scholar
Montesano, A. 2005. ‘La nozione di razionalità in economia’. Rivista Italiana degli Economisti 10: 2342.Google Scholar
Moore, B. 1988. Horizontalists and verticalists: the macroeconomics of credit money. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, M. S. 1990. The history of econometric ideas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Moscati, I. 2007. ‘Early experiments in consumer demand theory: 1930–1970’. History of Political Economy 39: 359401.Google Scholar
Moscati, I. 2016. ‘How economists came to accept expected utility theory: the case of Samuelson and Savage’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 30: 219–36.Google Scholar
Motterlini, M. and Guala, F., eds. 2005. Economia cognitiva e sperimentale. Milan: Egea-Università Bocconi.Google Scholar
Mueller, D. C. 1989. Public choice II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mullainathan, S. and Spiess, J. 2017. ‘Machine learning: an applied econometric approach’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 31: 87106.Google Scholar
Mundell, R. 1961. ‘A theory of optimum currency areas’. American Economic Review 51: 657–65.Google Scholar
Mundell, R. 1963. ‘Capital mobility and stabilization policy under flexible exchange rates’. Canadian Journal of Economic and Political Science 29: 475–85.Google Scholar
Muth, J. F. 1961. ‘Rational expectations and the theory of price movements’. Econometrica 29: 315–35.Google Scholar
Myrdal, G. 1968. Asian drama: an inquiry into the poverty of nations. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
Naldi, N. 1998. ‘Dicembre 1922: Piero Sraffa e Benito Mussolini’. Rivista italiana degli economisti 3: 271–99.Google Scholar
Nash, J. F. 1950. ‘Equilibrium points in N-person games’. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA 36: 48–9.Google Scholar
Nash, J. F. 1996. Essays on game theory. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Nash, J. F. 2002. The essential John Nash. Ed. by Kuhn, H. W. and Nasar, S.. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Nell, E. J. 1998. The general theory of transformational growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, R., ed. 1993. National innovation systems: a comparative analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. 1995. ‘Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change’. Journal of Economic Literature 33: 4890.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Neumann, J. von. 1937. ‘Über ein ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes’. In Menger, K. (ed.), Ergebrisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums, 1935–36, vol. 8, pp. 7383. Vienna: Deuticke. English transl., ‘A model of general economic equilibrium’. Review of Economic Studies 13 (1945): 1–9.Google Scholar
Neumann, J. von and Morgenstern, O. 1944. Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; II ed., 1947; III ed., 1953.Google Scholar
Nik-Khah, E. 2011. ‘George Stigler, the Graduate School of Business, and the pillars of the Chicago School’. In van Horn et al., pp. 116–47.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. 1973. ‘The allocation of energy resources’. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 3: 529–70.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. D. 2008. A question of balance. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nozick, R. 1974. Anarchy, state and utopia. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Nurkse, R. 1953. Problems of capital formation in developing countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, M. 1999. Women and human development: the capabilities approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nuti, D. M. 1970. ‘Capitalism, socialism and steady growth’. Economic Journal 80: 3257.Google Scholar
O’Donnell, R. 2014–15. ‘A critique of the ergodic/nonergodic approach to uncertainty’. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 37: 187209.Google Scholar
O’Driscoll, G. P. and Rizzo, M. J. 2015. Austrian economics re-examined. Abington: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ohanian, L. E. 2010. ‘The economic crisis from a neoclassical perspective’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 24: 4566.Google Scholar
Palazzi, P. and Casadio-Tarabusi, E. 2004. ‘An index for sustainable development’. BNL Quarterly Review 57(229): 185206.Google Scholar
Panico, C. 1988. Interest and profit in the theories of value and distribution. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Panzieri, R. 1976. Lotte operaie nello sviluppo capitalistico. Ed. by Mancini, S.. Turin: Einaudi.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1896. ‘La courbe de la répartition de la richesse’. In Recueil publié par la Faculté de Droit de l’Université de Lausanne à l’occasion de l’Exposition nationale de 1896, pp. 373–87. Italian transl., ‘La curva di ripartizione della ricchezza’. In Corsi 1995, pp. 51–70.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1896–7. Cours d’économie politique. 2 vols., Lausanne: F. Rouge.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1906. Manuale di economia politica. Milan: Società editrice libraria; repr., Rome: Bizzarri, 1965.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1916. Trattato di sociologia generale. 2 vols. Florence: Barbera; repr., Rome: Bizzarri, 1964.Google Scholar
Parrinello, S. 1970. ‘Introduzione a una teoria neoricardiana del commercio internazionale’. Studi economici 25: 267321.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1960. ‘A mathematical formulation of the Ricardian system’. Review of Economic Studies 27: 7898.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1962. ‘Rate of profit and income distribution in relation to the rate of economic growth’. Review of Economic Studies 29: 267–79.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1965. ‘A new theoretical approach to the problems of economic growth’. Academiae Pontificiae Scientiarum Scripta Varia 28: 571696.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1966. ‘Changes in the rate of profits and switches of techniques’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 503–17.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1969. ‘Switches of technique and the “rate of return” in capital theory’. Economic Journal 79: 508–31.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1970. ‘Again on capital theory and Solow’s “rate of return”’. Economic Journal 80: 428–31.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1972. ‘Reply to Mr. Dougherty’. Economic Journal 82: 1351–2.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1973. ‘The notion of vertical integration in economic analysis’. Metroeconomica 25: 129.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1974. Growth and income distribution: essays in economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1975. Lezioni di teoria della produzione. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1979a. ‘The unpalatability of the reswitching of techniques’. Revue d’économie politique 89: 637–42.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1979b. ‘The “unobtrusive postulate” of neoclassical economic theory’. Revue d’économie politique 89: 654–6.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1981. Structural change and economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 2000. ‘Critique of the neoclassical theory of growth and distribution’. BNL Quarterly Review 53(215): 383431.Google Scholar
Patinkin, D. 1956. Money, interest and prices. Evanston, IL: Row Peterson; III ed., Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Patinkin, D. 1974. ‘The role of the “liquidity trap” in Keynesian economics’. BNL Quarterly Review 27(108): 311.Google Scholar
Patinkin, D. 1976. ‘Keynes and econometrics: on the interaction between the macroeconomic revolutions of the interwar period’. Econometrica 44: 1091–123.Google Scholar
Peacock, A. 1992. Public choice analysis in historical perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Peck, J. 2011. ‘Orientation’. In van Horn et al., pp. xxv–lii.Google Scholar
Penrose, E. 1952. ‘Biological analogies in the theory of the firm’. American Economic Review 42: 804–19.Google Scholar
Penrose, E. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. 2000. Political economics: explaining economic policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Petty, W. 1690. Political arithmetick. London: Robert Clavel and Henry Mortlock; repr. in W. Petty, Economic writings. Ed. by C. H. Hull, 2 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1899, vol. 1, pp. 233313.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. 1967. ‘Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time’. Economica 34: 254–81.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S., ed. 1970. Microeconomic foundations of employment and inflation theory. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. 1990. Seven schools of macroeconomic thought. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. and Taylor, J. B. 1977. ‘Stabilising powers of monetary policy under rational expectations’. Journal of Political Economy 85: 163–90.Google Scholar
Phillips, A. W. 1958. ‘The relationship between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957’. Economica 25: 283–99.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1912. Wealth and welfare. London: Macmillan; new ed., The Economics of welfare. London: Macmillan, 1920.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1933. The theory of unemployment. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1950. Keynes’s General Theory: a retrospective view. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. 2013. Le capital au XXIe siècle. Paris: Editions du Seuil. English transl., Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Piore, M. and Sabel, C. 1984. The second industrial divide. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. 1985. ‘Short-term equilibrium dynamics of unemployment, vacancies and real wages’. American Economic Review 75: 676–90.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K. 1944. The great transformation. New York: Rinehart.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K. 1966. Dahomey and the slave trade. Seattle: University of Washington Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K. 1968. Primitive, archaic and modern economies: essays of Karl Polanyi. Ed. by Dalton, G.. New York: Doubleday; repr. Boston: Beacon Press, 1971.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K., Arensberg, C. M. and Pearson, H. W., eds. 1957. Trade and market in the early empires. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Pollock, F. 1956. Automation: Materialien zur Beurteilung der ökonomischen und sozialen Folgen. Frankfurt am Main: Europäische Verlagsanstalt; II ed., 1964.Google Scholar
Popper, K. R. 1945. The open society and its enemies. 2 vols. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Popper, K. R. 1969. Conjectures and refutations. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Posner, R. 1973. Economic analysis of law. Boston: Little, Brown and Co.Google Scholar
Prebish, R. 1950. The economic development of Latin America and its principal problems. New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D. 1993. Making democracy work: civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D. 2000. Bowling alone: the collapse and revival of American communities. New York: Touchstone – Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Quadrio Curzio, A. 1967. Rendita e distribuzione in un modello economico plurisettoriale. Milan: Giuffré.Google Scholar
Quadrio Curzio, A. and Pellizzari, F. 1996. Risorse, tecnologia, rendita. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Quadrio Curzio, A. and Scazzieri, R. 1984. ‘Sui momenti costitutivi dell’economia politica’. Giornale degli economisti 43: 3776.Google Scholar
Quandt, R. E. 1976. ‘Some quantitative aspects of the economic literature’. Journal of Political Economy 84: 741–55.Google Scholar
Quesnay, F. 1758–9. Tableau économique, Paris (I, 1758; II, 1759; III, 1759); repr. with English transl. in Kuczynski, M. and Meek, R. L. (eds.), Quesnay’s tableau économique. London: Macmillan and Kelley, 1972; anastatic reprint ed. by G. De Vivo. Milan: Fondazione Raffaele Mattioli per la storia del pensiero economico, 2009.Google Scholar
Quinton, A. 1968. ‘The later philosophy of Wittgenstein’. In Pitcher, G. (ed.), Wittgenstein, a collection of critical essays. London: Macmillan, pp. 821.Google Scholar
Radcliffe Report. 1959. Committee on the working of the monetary system. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Radner, R. 1968. ‘Equilibrium under uncertainty’. Econometrica 36: 3158.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. P. 1931. The foundations of mathematics. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. 1971. A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. 1982. ‘Social unity and primary goods’. In Sen and Williams 1982, pp. 159–86.Google Scholar
Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. S. 2010. ‘Growth in a time of debt’. NBER Working Paper 15639.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D. 1951–5. Works and correspondence. Ed. by Sraffa, P.. 10 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (vol. 11, Indexes, 1973).Google Scholar
Robbins, L. 1932. An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robbins, L. 1971. Autobiography of an economist. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. 1924. ‘Those empty boxes’. Economic Journal 34: 1630.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. 1930. ‘The trees of the forest’. Economic Journal 40: 8089.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1933. The economics of imperfect competition. London: Macmillan; II ed., 1969.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1953. ‘The production function and the theory of capital’. Review of Economic Studies 21: 81106.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1956. The accumulation of capital. London: Macmillan; III ed., 1969.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1970. ‘Capital theory up-to-date: a review of C. E. Ferguson, The neoclassical theory of production and distribution’. Canadian Journal of Economics 3: 309–17; repr. in Collected economic papers, vol. 4. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1973, pp. 144–54.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1974. Time in economics. London: Thames Polytechnic.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1977. ‘Michal Kalecki on the economics of capitalism’. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 33: 717.Google Scholar
Roemer, J. 1994. Egalitarian perspectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rogoff, K.S. 1985. ‘The optimal degree of commitment to an immediate monetary target’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 1169–90.Google Scholar
Romer, P. 1986. ‘Increasing returns and long-run growth’. Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–37.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1975. Sraffa e la teoria dei prezzi. Rome and Bari: Laterza; II ed., 1981. English transl. Sraffa and the theory of prices. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, 1977.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1977. Petty: la nascita dell’economia politica. Milan: Etas Libri; English transl., Petty. The origins of political economy. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe 1985.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1983. L’economia del petrolio. Rome and Bari: Laterza. English transl., The international oil market. London: Macmillan, 1985.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1984. ‘Sraffa e le banche’. Rivista milanese di economia 10: 104–2.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1989. ‘Research in fusion as investment’. Giornale degli economisti 48: 293307.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1990a. ‘Le scuole sraffiane’. In Becattini, G. (ed.), Il pensiero economico: temi, problemi e scuole. Turin: Utet, pp. 233–74. English transl., ‘The Sraffian schools’. Review of Political Economy 1991, 3: 187–219.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1990b. ‘Is the notion of long-period positions compatible with classical political economy?’. Political Economy 6: 103–11.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2005a. The wealth of ideas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2005b. Il mito della mano invisibile. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2009a. ‘Keynes and probability: an assessment’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 16: 485510.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2009b. Piero Sraffa. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2012a. ‘A patchwork post-Keynesian/evolutionary approach to income distribution’. In Gehrke, C., Salvadori, N., Steedman, I. and Sturm, M. (eds.), Classical political economy and modern theory: essays in honour of Heinz Kurz. Abingdon: Routledge, pp. 207–18.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2012b. ‘Keynesian uncertainty and the shaky foundations of statistical risk assessment models’. PSL Quarterly Review 65(263): 437–54.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2013. ‘Hyman Minsky’s monetary production economy’. PSL Quarterly Review 66(265): 7996.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2015a. ‘Oil and its markets’. PSL Quarterly Review 68(273): 151–75.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2015b. ‘Institutions, resources and the common weal’. In Baranzini, M., Rotondi, C. and Scazzieri, R. (eds.), Resources, production and structural dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 259–78.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2016a. Breve storia del pensiero economico. Bari and Rome: Laterza.English transl., A brief history of economic thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2017.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2016b. ‘L’etica dell’economista’. Moneta e Credito 69(273): 719.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2017. ‘La rivoluzione dello shale oil e i mercati finanziari’. Moneta e Credito 70(278): 173–93.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. and Tonveronachi, M. 1985. ‘The pre-Keynesian roots of the neoclassical synthesis’. Cahiers d’économie politique 10: 5165.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. and Tonveronachi, M. 2014. ‘Post-Keynesian, post-Sraffian economics: an outline’. In Papadimitriou, D. (ed.), Contributions to economic theory, policy, development and finance: essays in honor of Jan A. Kregel. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 4064.Google Scholar
Röpke, W. 1947. Civitas humana. Edinburgh: William Hodge.Google Scholar
Röpke, W. 1969. Against the tide. Chicago: Henry Regnery.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, N. 1982. Inside the black box: technology and economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, N. and Birdzell, L. E. 1986. How the West grew rich. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Ross, S. 1973. ‘The economic theory of agency: the principal’s problem’. American Economic Review 63: 134–9.Google Scholar
Rosselli, C. [1930] 1945. Socialismo liberale. Ed. by Garosci, A.. Rome/Florence/Milan:Edizioni U; new ed. Turin: Einaudi 1973; repr. Turin: Einaudi Tascabili, 1997.Google Scholar
Rossi, E. 1946. Abolire la miseria: la fiaccola; repr. ed. by Sylos Labini, P.. Rome and Bari: Laterza, 1977.Google Scholar
Rossi, P. 2007. Max Weber: una idea di Occidente. Rome: Donzelli.Google Scholar
Rostow, W. W. 1960. The stages of economic growth. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. 1962. Man, economy, and state. New York: D. van Nostrand.Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. 1995. An Austrian perspective on the history of economic thought (vol. 1, Economic thought before Adam Smith; vol. 2, Classical economics). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Rothbard, M. 1997. The logic of action. 2 vols. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Rothschild, E. 1994. ‘Adam Smith and the invisible hand’. American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings 84: 319–22.Google Scholar
Rowthorn, R. 1977. ‘Conflict, inflation and money’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 1: 215–39.Google Scholar
Rowthorn, R. 2014. ‘A note on Piketty’s Capital in the twenty-first century’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 38: 1275–84.Google Scholar
Russell, B. and Whitehead, A. N. 1910–13. Principia mathematica. 3 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sabbatini, P. 2000. La concorrenza come bene pubblico. Il caso Microsoft. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Sabel, C. and Piore, M. 1984. The second industrial divide. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Salvadori, M. L. 1976. Kautsky e la rivoluzione socialista, 1880–1938. Milan: Feltrinelli.Google Scholar
Samuelson, L. 2005. ‘Economic theory and experimental economics’. Journal of Economic Literature 43: 65107.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1938. ‘A note on the pure theory of consumer’s behavior’ and ‘An addendum’. Economica ns 5: 61–71 and 353–4.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1947. Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press; expanded ed., 1983.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1948a. Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1948b. ‘International trade and the equalization of factor prices’. Economic Journal 58: 163–84.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1958a. ‘An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money’. Journal of Political Economy 66: 467–82.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1958b. ‘The pure theory of public expenditure’. Review of Economics and Statistics 36: 387–9.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1962. ‘Parable and realism in capital theory: the surrogate production function’. Review of Economic Studies 29: 193206.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1963. ‘Problems of methodology: discussion’. American Economic Review 53: 231–6.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1966. ‘A summing up’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 568–83.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1966–2011. The collected scientific papers of Paul Samuelson. 7 vols. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. and Modigliani, F. 1966. ‘The Pasinetti paradox in neo-classical and more general models’. Review of Economic Studies 33: 269301.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. and Solow, R. 1960. ‘Analytical aspects of anti-inflation policy’. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 50: 177–94.Google Scholar
Sandmo, A. 1990. ‘Buchanan on political economy. A review article’. Journal of Economic Literature 28: 5065.Google Scholar
Savage, L. J. 1954. The foundation of statistics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Schefold, B. 1989. Mr Sraffa on joint production and other essays. London: Unwin & Hyman.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. 1960. The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. 1978. ‘Altruism, meanness, and other potentially strategic behaviors’. American Economic Review 68: 229–30.Google Scholar
Schmalensee, R. and Willig, R. D., eds. 1989. Handbook of industrial organization. 2 vols. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Schulak, M. E. and Unterköfler, H. 2011. The Austrian school of economics. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1908. Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie. Munich and Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot. Italian transl., L’essenza e i principi dell’economia teorica. Rome and Bari: Laterza, 1982.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1912. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Munich and Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot; II ed. 1926; III ed. 1931; IV ed. 1935. English edn., The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1934; repr., New York: Oxford University Press, 1961.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. 1928. ‘The instability of capitalism’. Economic Journal 38: 361–86.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1939. Business cycles: a theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. 2 vols. New York: McGraw-Hill; repr., Philadelphia: Porcupine Press 1982. (Partial repr., R. Fels ed., New York and London: McGraw–Hill, 1964).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1942. Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper & Bros.; II ed. 1947; III ed. 1950.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1946. ‘L’avenir de l’entreprise privée devant les tendences socialistes modernes’. In Comment sauvegarder l’entreprise privée. Canada: Editions Association Professionelle des Industriels, pp. 103–8.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1954. History of economic analysis. Ed. by Boody Schumpeter, E.. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. 1976. The joyless economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Screpanti, E. and Zenezini, M., eds. 1978. Accumulazione del capitale e progresso tecnico. Milan: Feltrinelli.Google Scholar
Sebastiani, M., ed. 1989. Kalecki’s relevance today. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Sebastiani, M. 1994. Kalecki and unemployment equilibrium. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Selten, R. 1975. ‘Reexamination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in extensive games’. International Journal of Game Theory 4: 2555.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1970. ‘The impossibility of a Paretian liberal’. Journal of Political Economy 78: 279–86.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1973. ‘Behaviour and the concept of preference’. Economica 40: 241–59; repr. in Sen 1982, pp. 54–73.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1977. ‘Rational fools: a critique of the behavioural foundations of economic theory’. Philosophy and public affairs 6: 317–44; repr. in Sen 1982, pp. 84–106.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1982. Choice, welfare and measurement. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1984. Resources, values and development. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1987. ‘Rational behaviour’. In Eatwell et al. 1987, vol. 4, pp. 68–76.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1991. Money and value: on the ethics and economics of finance. Rome: Edizioni dell’Elefante.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1992. Inequality reexamined. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1999. Development as freedom. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 2002a. Rationality and freedom. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 2002b. Globalizzazione e libertà. Milan: Mondadori.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 2003. ‘Sraffa, Wittgenstein, Gramsci’. Journal of Economic Literature 41: 1240–55.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 2009. The idea of justice. London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 2012. ‘Values and justice’. Journal of Economic Methodology 19: 101–8.Google Scholar
Sen, A. and Drèze, J., eds. 1990 The political economy of hunger. 3 vols. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. and Williams, B., eds. 1982. Utilitarianism and beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. 1955. Uncertainty in economics and other reflections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shaikh, A. 1974. ‘Laws of production and laws of algebra: the humbug production function’. Review of Economics and Statistics 61: 115–20.Google Scholar
Shaikh, A. 2016. Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, C. and Stiglitz, J. 1984. ‘Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device’. American Economic Review 74: 433–44.Google Scholar
Sharpe, W. F. 1964. ‘Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk’. Journal of Finance 19: 425–42.Google Scholar
Shaw, G. B., ed. 1889. Fabian essays in socialism. London: Walter Scott; repr. Gloucester, MA: Peter Smith, 1967.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. W. 1997. ‘A survey of corporate governance’. Journal of Finance 52: 737–83.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1953. ‘Causal ordering and identifiability’. In Hood, W. C. and Koopmans, T. C. (eds.), Studies in econometric method. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1954. ‘Spurious correlations: a causal interpretation’. Journal of the American Statistical Association 49: 467–79.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1955. ‘A behavioral model of rational choice’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 99118.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1957. Models of man. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1972. ‘Theories of bounded rationality’. In McGuire, C. B. and Radner, C. (eds.), Decision and organization. Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 161–76.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1979a. Models of thought. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1979b. ‘On parsimonious explanations of production relations’. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 81: 459–74.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1979c. ‘Rational decision making in business organizations’. American Economic Review 69: 493512.Google Scholar
Simon, H. 1981. The sciences of the artificial, II ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1983. Reason in human affairs. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press,.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1993. ‘Altruism and economics’. American Economic Review 83: 156–61.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1997. An empirically based microeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sims, C. A. 1980. ‘Macroeconomics and reality’. Econometrica 48: 148.Google Scholar
Sims, C. A. 1982. ‘Policy analysis with econometric models’. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 107–64.Google Scholar
Singer, H. 1950. ‘The distribution of gains between investing and borrowing countries’. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 40: 473–85.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 1983. John Maynard Keynes: hopes betrayed, 1883–1920. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 1992. John Maynard Keynes: the economist as saviour, 1920–1937. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 2000. John Maynard Keynes: fighting for Britain, 1937–1946. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 2010. Keynes: a very short introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1759. The theory of moral sentiments. London: A. Millar; critical ed. ed. by D. D. Raphael and A. L. Macfie. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: W. Strahan and T. Cadell; critical ed. ed. by R. H. Campbell and A. S. Skinner. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1795. Essays on philosophical subjects. London: T. Cadell and W. Davies; critical ed. ed. by W. P. D. Wightman and J. C. Bryce. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Smith, V. 1962. ‘An experimental study of competitive market behavior’. Journal of Political Economy 70: 111–37.Google Scholar
Smith, V. 2003. ‘Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics’. American Economic Review 93: 465508.Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. 1956. ‘A contribution to the theory of economic growth’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 79: 6594.Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. 1957. ‘Technical change and the aggregate production function’. Review of Economics and Statistics 39: 312–20.Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. 1963. Capital theory and the rate of return. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. 1967. ‘The interest rate and transition between techniques’. In Feinstein, C. H. (ed.), Socialism, capitalism and economic growth: essays presented to Maurice Dobb. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 3039.Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. 1970. ‘On the rate of return: reply to Pasinetti’. Economic Journal 80: 423–8.Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. 1988. ‘Growth theory and after’. American Economic Review 78: 307–17.Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. 2000. ‘The neoclassical theory of growth and distribution’. BNL Quartertly Review 53(215): 349–81.Google Scholar
Sonnenschein, H. 1972. ‘Market excess demand functions’. Econometrica 40: 549–56.Google Scholar
Soros, G. 2008 The new paradigm for financial markets. New York: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Spaventa, L. 1959. ‘Dualism in economic growth’. BNL Quarterly Review 12(51): 199250.Google Scholar
Spaventa, L. 1968. ‘Realism without parables in capital theory’. In Récherches récentes sur la fonction de production. Centre d’études et de récherches universitaire de Namur, pp. 15–45.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1920. L’inflazione monetaria in Italia durante e dopo la guerra, Milan: Scuola tipografica salesiana; repr. in Economia politica, 1994: 163–96.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1922a. ‘The bank crisis in Italy’. Economic Journal 32: 178–97.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1922b. ‘Italian banks today’. Manchester Guardian Commercial. The reconstruction of Europe 11: 694–95; repr. (in Italian) in Sraffa 1986, pp. 239–44.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1925. ‘Sulle relazioni fra costo e quantità prodotta’. Annali di economia 2: 277328.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1926. ‘The laws of returns under competitive conditions’. Economic Journal 36: 535–50.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1930. ‘A criticism’ and ‘A rejoinder’, in ‘Symposium on increasing returns and the representative firm’. Economic Journal 40: 8993.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1932. ‘Dr. Hayek on money and capital’ and ‘A rejoinder’. Economic Journal 42: 4253 and 249–51.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1951. ‘Introduction’. In Ricardo, vol. I, pp. xiii–lxii.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1960. Production of commodities by means of commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1962. ‘Production of commodities: a comment’. Economic Journal 72: 477–9.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1986. Saggi. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1991. Lettere a Tania per Gramsci. Ed. by Gerratana, V.. Rome: Editori riuniti.Google Scholar
Steedman, I. 1977. Marx after Sraffa. London: New Left Books.Google Scholar
Steedman, I. 1979. Trade amongst growing economies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Steedman, I. 1989. From exploitation to altruism. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Steindl, J. 1945. Small and big business: economic problems of the size of firms. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Steindl, J. 1952. Maturity and stagnation in American capitalism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; repr., New York: Monthly Review Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Steindl, J. 1990. Economic papers, 1941–88. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Stern, N. 2008. The economics of climate change: the Stern Review. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stern, N. 2009. A blueprint for a safer planet: how to manage climate change and create a new era of progress and prosperity. London: Bodley Head.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1941. Production and distribution theories: the formative period. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1946. The theory of price. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1951. ‘The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market’. Journal of Political Economy 59: 185–93.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1961. ‘The economics of information’. Journal of Political Economy 69: 213–25.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1971. ‘A theory of regulation’. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2: 321.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1994. Mercato, informazione, regolamentazione. Ed. by Fiorentini, G.. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. and Becker, G. 1977. ‘De gustibus non est disputandum’. American Economic Review 67: 7690.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. 2002. Informazione, economia pubblica e macroeconomia. Ed. by Boitani, A. and Petretto, A.. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Stockhammer, E. 2008. ‘Is the NAIRU theory a monetarist, new Keynesian, post Keynesian or Marxist theory?’. Metroeconomica 59: 479–51.Google Scholar
Stone, R. 1997. Some British empiricists in the social sciences, 1650–1900. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stone, R. and Brown, A. 1962. A computable model of economic growth. London: Chapman and Hall.Google Scholar
Streeten, P. 1972. The frontiers of development studies. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Streeten, P. 1986. ‘Aerial roots’. BNL Quarterly Review 39(157): 135–59.Google Scholar
Stuart Hughes, H. 1958. Consciousness and society. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1991. ‘Rational choice: a survey of contributions from economics and philosophy’. Economic Journal 101: 751–85.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2001. ‘The evolutionary turn in game theory’. Journal of Economic Methodology 8: 113–30.Google Scholar
Svorenčík, A. 2014. ‘MIT’s rise to prominence: outline of a collective biography’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplement): 109–33.Google Scholar
Swan, T. W. 1956. ‘Economic growth and capital accumulation’. Economic Record 32: 334–61.Google Scholar
Sweezy, P. 1942. The theory of capitalist development. NewYork: Monthly Review Press, repr. 1968.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1954. ‘Il problema dello sviluppo economico in Marx ed in Schumpeter’. In Papi, G. U. (ed.), Teoria dello sviluppo economico. Milan: Giuffrè; repr. in P. Sylos Labini, Problemi dello sviluppo economico. Bari: Laterza, 1970, pp. 19–73.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1956. Oligopolio e progresso tecnico. Milan: Giuffrè; IV ed., Turin: Einaudi, 1967. English transl., Oligopoly and technical progress. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962; II ed., 1969.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1967. ‘Prices, distribution and investment in Italy 1951–1966: an interpretation’. BNL Quarterly Review 20(83): 316–75.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1972. Sindacati, inflazione e produttività. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P., ed. 1973. Prezzi relativi e distribuzione del reddito. Turin: Boringhieri.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1974. Saggio sulle classi sociali. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1976. ‘Competition: the product markets’. In Wilson and Skinner 1976, pp. 200–32.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1983. Il sottosviluppo e l’economia contemporanea. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1984. Le forze dello sviluppo e del declino. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1987. ‘The theory of unemployment, too, is historically conditioned’. BNL Quarterly Review 40(163): 379435.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1995. ‘Why the interpretation of the Cobb-Douglas production function must be radically changed’. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 6: 485504.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 2000. Sottosviluppo: una strategia di riforme. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 2003. ‘Prospects for the world economy’. BNL Quarterly Review 56(226): 179206.Google Scholar
Syrquin, M. 2018. ‘Quantifying economic development: Kuznets, Chenery, and the quantitative approach to development economics’. History of Political Economy, 50 (Supplement): 211–30.Google Scholar
Tarantelli, E. 1978. Il ruolo economico del sindacato. Rome and Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Tarantelli, E. 1986. Economia politica del lavoro. Turin: Utet.Google Scholar
Targetti, F. 1988. Nicholas Kaldor. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Tarshis, L. 1939. ‘Changes in real and money wages’. Economic Journal 49: 150–54.Google Scholar
Tawney, R. H. 1926. Religion and the rise of capitalism. London: Murray; repr., Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1975.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. 1980. ‘Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts’. Journal of Political Economy 88: 123.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. 1988. ‘Anomalies: the winner’s curse’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2: 191202.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. 1990. ‘Saving, fungibility, and mental accounts’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4: 193205.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. 1992. The winner’s curse: paradoxes and anomalies of economic life. New York: Free Press; new ed., Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. and Sunstein, C. 2003. ‘Libertarian paternalism’. American Economic Review 93: 175–9.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. and Sunstein, C. 2008. Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Thirlwall, A. P. 1979. ‘The balance of payments constraint as an explanation of international growth rate differences’. BNL Quarterly Review 32(128): 4553.Google Scholar
Thirlwall, A. P. 1987. Nicholas Kaldor. Brighton: Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Thirlwall, A. P. 2018. ‘Reflections of an economist’. BNL Quarterly Review 71(284): 939.Google Scholar
Thirlwall, A. P. and Leon-Ledesma, M. 2000. ‘Is the natural rate of growth endogenous?’. BNL Quarterly Review 53(215): 433–45.Google Scholar
Thomas, W. 2014. ‘Decisions and dynamics: postwar theoretical problems and the MIT style of economics’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplement): 295314.Google Scholar
Thornton, H. 1802. Enquiry into the nature and effects of the paper credit of Great Britain. London: Hatchard; repr., ed. by F. Hayek, London: London School of Economics, 1939.Google Scholar
Thünen, J. H. von. 1826–50. Der isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und Nationalökonomie. Rostock: Leopold.Google Scholar
Thurstone, L. L. 1931. ‘The indifference function’. Journal of Social Psychology 2: 139–67.Google Scholar
Tirole, J. 1988. The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. 1958. ‘Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk’. Review of Economic Studies 25: 6586.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. 1969. ‘A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory’. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1: 1529.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. 1971–85. Essays in Economics. 3 vols. (vol. 1, 1971; vol. 2, 1975; vol. 3, 1985), Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Togliatti, P., ed. 1962. La formazione del gruppo dirigente del Partito comunista italiano. Rome: Editori Riuniti.Google Scholar
Tonveronachi, M. 1982. ‘Monetarismo e regole fisse in H.C. Simons’. Moneta e Credito 35: 309–30.Google Scholar
Tonveronachi, M. 1983. J. M. Keynes. Dall’instabilità ciclica all’equilibrio di sottoccupazione. Rome: NIS.Google Scholar
Tonveronachi, M. 1989. Struttura ed evoluzione dei sistemi finanziari. Arezzo: Banca Popolare dell’Etruria e del Lazio.Google Scholar
Tonveronachi, M. 1990. ‘Teorie monetarie a Chicago’. In Becattini, G. (ed.), Il pensiero economico: temi, problemi e scuole. Turin: Utet, pp. 349–85.Google Scholar
Tonveronachi, M. 1992. ‘Keynes and equilibrium: a note’. In Sebastiani, M. (ed.), The notion of equilibrium in the Keynesian theory. Houndmills: Macmillan, pp. 1831.Google Scholar
Toporowski, J. 2000. The end of finance: capital market inflation, financial derivatives and pension fund capitalism. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Toporowski, J. 2013. Michał Kalecki: an intellectual biography, vol. 1: Rendez-vous in Cambridge, 1899–1939. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Tribe, K. 1995. Strategies of economic order. German economic discourse 1750–1950. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Triffin, R. 1974. ‘Crisi del petrolio e problemi internazionali e comunitari’. Moneta e Credito 27(106): 148–61.Google Scholar
Trigilia, C. 2016. ‘Tipi di democrazia e modelli di capitalismo: un’agenda di ricerca’. Stato e Mercato 36: 183213.Google Scholar
Tsuru, S. 1993. Institutional economics revisited. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranowskij, M. J. 1905. Theoretische Grundlagen des Marxismus. Leipzig: Dunker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. 1965. The politics of bureaucracy. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.Google Scholar
Turgot, A.-R.-J. [1766]. ‘Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses’; publ. in 1769–70 in the Ephémérides du citoyen; repr. in Ravix and Romani (eds.), Turgot. Formation et distribution des richesses. Paris: Flammarion, pp. 157–226.Google Scholar
Tutino, S. 1968. L’ottobre cubano. Turin: Einaudi.Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahnemann, D. 1992. ‘Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty’. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5: 297323.Google Scholar
Valdés, J. G. 1995. Pinochet’s economists: the Chicago school in Chile. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Vanek, J. 1970. The general theory of labor managed market economies. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Van Horn, R. 2011. ‘Jacob Viner’s critique of Chicago neoliberalism’. In Van Horn et al., pp. 279–300.Google Scholar
Van Horn, R. 2014. ‘Henry Simon’s death’. History of Political Economy 46: 525–35.Google Scholar
Van Horn, R. and Klaes, M. 2011. ‘Intervening in laissez-faire liberalism: Chicago shift on patents’. In Van Horn et al., pp. 180–207.Google Scholar
Van Horn, R. and Mirowski, P. 2009. ‘The rise of the Chicago school of economics and the birth of neoliberalism’. In Mirowski and Plehwe, pp. 139–78.Google Scholar
Van Horn, R., Mirowski, P. and Stapleford, T. A., eds. 2011. Building Chicago economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Varian, H. R. 1974. ‘Equity, envy and efficiency’. Journal of Economic Theory 9: 6391.Google Scholar
Varian, H. R. 2014. ‘Big data: new tricks for econometrics’. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28: 328.Google Scholar
Vaughn, K. I. 1994. Austrian economics in America: the migration of a tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. 1898. ‘Why is economics not an evolutionary science?’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 12: 373–97.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. 1899. The theory of the leisure class. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. 1904. The theory of business enterprise. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. 1919. The place of science in modern civilization and other essays. New York: B. W. Huebsch.Google Scholar
Verdoorn, P. 1949. ‘Fattori che regolano lo sviluppo della produttività del lavoro’. L’industria 1: 310.Google Scholar
Veritas Foundation. 1960. Keynes at Harvard: economic deception as a political credo. New York: Veritas Foundation.Google Scholar
Vianello, F. 1985. ‘The pace of accumulation’. Political Economy: Studies in the Surplus Approach 1: 6987.Google Scholar
Vicarelli, F. 1977. Keynes: L’instabilità del capitalismo. Milan: Etas libri.Google Scholar
Vicarelli, S. 1975. ‘Il “problema della trasformazione”: fine di una controversia’. Note economiche 8: 91138.Google Scholar
Vickrey, W. 1961. ‘Counterspeculation, auctions and competitive sealed tenders’. Journal of Finance 16: 837.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1927. ‘Adam Smith and laissez-faire’. Journal of Political Economy 35: 198232; repr. in Viner 1991, pp. 85–113.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1931. ‘Cost curves and supply curves’. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 3: 2346.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1978. ‘Religious thought and economic society: four chapters of an unfinished work’. J. Melitz and D. Winch, eds. History of Political Economy 10: 1192.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1991. Essays on the intellectual history of economics. Ed. by Irwin, D. A.. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Visco, I., ed. 1985. Le aspettative nell’analisi economica. Bologna: il Mulino.Google Scholar
Vromen, J. J. 2007. ‘Neuroeconomics as a natural extension of bioeconomics: the shifting scope of standard economic theory’. Journal of Bioeconomics 9: 145–67.Google Scholar
Wald, A. 1936. ‘Über einige Gleichungssysteme der Mathematischen Ökonomie’. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 7: 637–70. English transl., ‘On some systems of equations of mathematical economics’. Econometrica 19 (1951): 368–403.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, I. 1974, 1980, 1989. The modern world-system. 3 vols. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Wallich, H. C. and Weintraub, S. 1971. ‘A tax-based incomes policy’. Journal of Economic Issues 5: 119; repr. in Weintraub 1978, pp. 259–80.Google Scholar
Wallis, J. J. and North, D. C. 1986. ‘Measuring the transaction sector in the American economy, 1870–1970’. In Engerman, S. L. and Gallman, R. E. (eds.), Long-term factors in American economic growth. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 95162.Google Scholar
Wallis, W. A. and Friedman, M. 1942. ‘The empirical derivation of indifference functions’. In Lange, O., Intyre, F. M. and Yntema, T. O. (eds.), Studies in mathematical economics and econometrics, in memory of Henry Schultz. New York: Books for Libraries Press, pp. 175–89.Google Scholar
Walras, L. 1874. Eléments d’économie politique pure. Lausanne: Corbaz; English transl., ed. by W. Jaffé. Elements of pure economics. London: Irwin, 1954; repr., London: Allen & Unwin, 1965.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1904–5. ‘Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus’. Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 2021; II ed. In Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie. Tübingen: Mohr 1922; Italian transl., L’etica protestante e lo spirito del capitalismo. Florence: Sansoni, 1965.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1919. Politik als Beruf, Wissenschaft als Beruf. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot; Italian transl., Il lavoro intellettuale come professione. Turin: Einaudi 1948; repr. 1976.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1920–21. Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie. Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr. Italian transl., Sociologia della religione, ed. by P. Rossi. Milan: Edizioni di Comunità 1982; II ed., 4 vols. Turin: Edizioni di Comunità, 2002.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1922a. Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Wissenschaftslehre. Tübingen: Mohr; Italian transl., Il metodo delle scienze storico-sociali. Turin: Einaudi 1958; repr. Milan: Oscar Mondadori, 1980.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1922b. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. 2 vol. Tübingen: Mohr. Italian transl., Economia e società. 2 vols. Milan: Edizioni di Comunità, 1962.Google Scholar
Weintraub, R. 1977. ‘The microfoundations of macroeconomics: a critical survey’. Journal of Economic Literature 15: 123.Google Scholar
Weintraub, R. 2014. ‘MIT’s openness to Jewish economists’. History of Political Economy 46 (Supplement): 4559.Google Scholar
Weintraub, S. 1978. Keynes, Keynesians, and monetarists. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1893. Über Wert, Kapital, und Rente. Jena: G. Fischer; English transl., Value, capital and rent. London: Allen & Unwin, 1954.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1898. Geldzins und Güterpreise bestimmenden Ursachen. Jena: G. Fischer; English transl., Interest and prices. London: Macmillan, 1936.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1900. ‘Om gränsproduktivitaten såsom grundval för den nationalekonomiska fördelningen’. Ekonomisk Tidskrift 2: 305–37; English transl., ‘Marginal productivity as the basis for distribution in economics’. In K. Wicksell, Selected papers on economic theory. London: Allen & Unwin, 1958, pp. 93–121.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1901–6. Forelasningar i nationalekonomi. 2 vols. Stockholm and Lund: Fritzes-Berlingska. English transl., Lectures on political economy. 2 vols. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1934–5.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, P. H. 1884. Das Kapital: a criticism’. To-day 2: 388409; repr. in P. H. Wicksteed, The common sense of political economy and selected papers and reviews on economic theory. Ed. by L. Robbins. London: Routledge, 1934, vol. 2, pp. 705–24.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. 1990. Latin American adjustment: how much has happened? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. 2004. A short history of the Washington consensus. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. https://piie.com/publications/papers/williamson0904-2.pdf.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1986. Economic organization. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 2000. ‘The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead’. Journal of Economic Literature 38: 595613.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, L. 1921. ‘Logisch-philosophische Abhandlung’. Annalen der Naturphilosophie 14, 185262. Revised English ed., Tractatus logico-philosophicus. London: Kegan Paul, 1922.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, L. 1953. Philosophische Untersuchungen. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Wittman, D. 1995. The myth of democratic failure: why political institutions are efficient. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Wood, A. 1975. A theory of profits. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Xu, He 1963. Italian transl., Trattato di economia politica. 2 vols. Milano: Mazzotta 1975.Google Scholar
Young, A. 1928. Increasing returns and economic progress’. Economic Journal 38: 527–42.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Alessandro Roncaglia, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy
  • Book: The Age of Fragmentation
  • Online publication: 25 November 2019
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Alessandro Roncaglia, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy
  • Book: The Age of Fragmentation
  • Online publication: 25 November 2019
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Alessandro Roncaglia, Università degli Studi di Roma 'La Sapienza', Italy
  • Book: The Age of Fragmentation
  • Online publication: 25 November 2019
Available formats
×