Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-sjtt6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-26T22:09:47.227Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Rise and Fall of Anti-Corruption in North Korea

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2022

Christopher Carothers*
Affiliation:
Center for the Study of Contemporary China, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, USA
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: chris.j.carothers@gmail.com
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

North Korea is widely seen as having among the most corrupt governments in the world. However, the Kim family regime has not always been so accepting of government wrongdoing. Drawing on archival evidence, this study shows that Kim Il-sung saw corruption as a threat to economic development and launched campaigns to curb it throughout the 1950s. I find that these campaigns were at least somewhat successful, and they contributed to post-Korean War reconstruction and rapid development afterwards. So when and why did the regime shift from combating corruption to embracing it? I argue that changes in the country's economic system following the crisis of the 1990s, especially de facto marketization, made corruption more beneficial to the regime both as a source of revenue and as an escape valve for public discontent. This study's findings contribute to our understanding of the politics of corruption control in authoritarian regimes.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the East Asia Institute

Introduction

North Korea is widely seen as having among the most corrupt governments in the world (Corruption Perceptions Index 2018). Corruption—commonly defined as the misuse of public office for private gain—reportedly permeates the North Korean state from the central leadership down to the lowest levels of the bureaucracy and is ubiquitous even in critical sectors, such as the military and the diplomatic corps. For many officials, routine bribe-taking pays the bills; illicit earnings outstrip or even entirely replace government salaries (Park Reference Park2015). The country's entrepreneurial class colludes with officials in a variety of illegal or semi-legal arrangements to mobilize state enterprises or resources for private business ventures (Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017a; Ward, Lankov, and Kim Reference Ward, Lankov and Kim2019). Moreover, the regime is deeply engaged in illegal money-making activities abroad, including cybercrime, insurance fraud, counterfeiting, and drug trafficking (Chestnut Reference Chestnut2007).

However, as this study shows, the North Korean regime has not always been so accepting of corruption. During and after the Korean War (1950–53), founding leader Kim Il-sung launched nationwide campaigns to curb bribery and embezzlement. Among other problems, cadres were appropriating state property from factories and other workplaces and then colluding with businesspeople to sell it off. Kim Il-sung was concerned that corruption was undermining his ambitious plans for national development and revealing a lack of discipline in the Korean Workers’ Party (KWP). Curbing corruption, he argued, would allow for a more efficient and effective mobilization of resources. His campaigns, modeled on anti-corruption efforts pursued in China by the Chinese Communist Party, involved numerous arrests of party members and other officials, the deployment of special investigation teams, self-criticism sessions, and new regulations and party rules targeting wrongdoing.

My research finds that Kim Il-sung's campaigns helped to control corruption and contributed to the country's rapid post-Korean War recovery and economic development. This conclusion is in line with studies arguing that embezzlement and bribery were relatively limited under Kim Il-sung's system of harsh political and social controls between the 1960s and 1980s (Agov Reference Agov2010; Kim Reference Kim2006; Lankov Reference Lankov2015). Some critics might be tempted to see Kim Il-sung's anti-corruption campaigns as simply a way for him to attack political rivals, especially given the factional conflicts that took place in the mid-1950s surrounding the August 1956 Incident. However, an examination of the charges against Kim Il-sung's rivals shows that accusations of corruption did not play a major role, and that there was little overlap with the campaigns.

These historical findings raise an important question: When and why did the North Korean regime shift from combating corruption to allowing it? I argue that this shift occurred after North Korea's economic and political crisis in the 1990s, which caused corruption to boom (Pak et al. Reference Pak, Hyŏnchun, Yŏngcha and Ch'ŏlki2012; OHCHR 2019). The sudden withdrawal of Soviet aid following the dissolution of the Soviet Union led to an implosion of the North Korean economy. This, in turn, led to a decline in state power and a partial breakdown of societal order. Economic implosion also paved the way for the North Korean Famine (1994–98), which was triggered by massive flooding and droughts. Adding to the instability, Kim Il-sung died in 1994. Predictably, this complex mix of economic, political, and social problems triggered a rapid spread of corruption throughout the 1990s. The Kim family regime survived this crisis, to the surprise of many foreign observers, but it never brought corruption back under control.

The crisis of the 1990s brought fundamental changes to North Korea's economic system that incentivized the regime to accept corruption. Under the state socialist system that had characterized the Kim Il-sung era, corruption was economically detrimental. Rising bribery and embezzlement after the Korean War threatened to undercut Kim Il-sung's mission of rapid state-led development. But during the 1990s, North Korea was forced to shift away from its state socialist model and accept substantial de facto marketization. In this new context, corruption often facilitated market activity and generated profits that the regime could capture. Tolerating corruption in a variety of forms became a financial win-win for the regime and for many individual actors involved, including officials, businesspeople, and ordinary citizens. Different forms of corruption have also come to benefit the regime politically by serving as an escape valve for public discontent over its restrictive ideological rules. Kim Il-sung's successors, Kim Jong-il and Kim Jong-un, have launched several anti-corruption crackdowns since 2000, but these have been superficial or narrowly targeted measures that do not attempt to undo corruption's now deep institutionalization.

The above arguments are based on an examination of corruption and anti-corruption in North Korea across several decades. This study is, to my knowledge, the first English-language study to substantively analyze Kim Il-sung's 1950s anti-corruption campaigns and assess their contributions to the country's economic and political development. To elucidate these campaigns, I explored two archival sources that are mainstays of historical research on North Korea: materials captured by United Nations forces during the Korean War, which are now housed at the US National Archives and Records Administration, and diplomatic documents collected in the Wilson Center Digital Archive. I also examined some North Korean journals and newspapers, following Andre Schmid's suggestion that scholars researching North Korea should make better use of the country's “often forgotten … literary and domestic media” (Schmid Reference Schmid2018).

Corruption is a debated term in academic literature.Footnote 1 While the most common definition involves the misuse of public office for private gain, in this study I follow Joseph Nye's (Reference Nye1967) elaboration of this standard definition. Corruption is “behavior which deviates from the formal duties of a public office (elective or appointive) because of private-regarding (personal, close family, private clique) wealth or status gains; or violates rules against the exercise of certain types of private-regarding influence” (Nye Reference Nye1967, 419). This definition covers the broad categories of bribery (bribe-giving, bribe-taking, and other transactional acts) and embezzlement (any theft or misappropriation of state assets), as well as other illicit practices such as extortion and fraud. However, this definition does not include forms of cultural or moral decline that are sometimes termed corruption, as Nye makes clear.

This study's findings, in addition to contributing to our knowledge about North Korea, have broader implications for research on authoritarian politics. Firstly, my analysis of the Kim Il-sung era shows that developmental imperatives can motivate even highly authoritarian regimes to enact corruption control. A large body of scholarship highlights autocrats’ incentives to engage in corruption and casts doubt on their willingness to meaningfully curb it. Scholars argue that autocrats use corruption not only to enrich themselves, as is well-known, but also as a key tool for rewarding loyalists and amassing political support (Geddes Reference Geddes1999; Bueno de Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2003; Brownlee Reference Brownlee2007; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011; Bueno de Mesquita and Smith Reference Bueno de Mesquita and Smith2011; Krastev Reference Krastev2016). Anti-corruption campaigns launched by autocrats are often—correctly—seen as cover for purging rivals and other political maneuvers (Treisman Reference Treisman2002; Lam Reference Lam2015; Pei Reference Pei2018). The highly authoritarian North Korean regime might seem to be a case in point, especially given its unchecked corruption in recent decades. However, I show that in the post-war period the regime's drive to rapidly develop the country—a product of both security needs and ideological commitments—incentivized it to undertake substantial anti-corruption efforts. My analysis of this case builds on previous analyses of “developmental dictators” and “illiberal state-builders” in other nondemocracies, some of whom, such as Rwanda's President Paul Kagame, have also prioritized corruption control (Lee Reference Lee2006; Jones, Soares de Oliveira, and Verhoeven Reference Jones, De Oliveira and Verhoeven2013; Guha Reference Guha2014).

Secondly, my findings about the North Korean regime's shift from combating to allowing corruption after the 1990s suggest that regime type and other structural factors may be insufficient to predict a government's tolerance for corruption. Many scholars have argued that personalist dictatorships—such as North Korea—have higher levels of corruption and worse governance outcomes in other areas compared to party-led regimes, military regimes, and monarchies (Geddes Reference Geddes1999; Ezrow and Frantz Reference Ezrow and Frantz2011; Kailitz Reference Kailitz2013; Chang and Golden Reference Chang and Golden2010).Footnote 2 Personalist autocrats are even less accountable than other autocrats and often rely heavily on doling out material benefits to narrow and poorly institutionalized coalitions of loyalists (Bueno de Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno de Mesquita, Smith, Siverson and Morrow2003). Other scholarship finds that authoritarian regimes with quasi-democratic institutions, such as semi-competitive elections or legislatures that allow some opposition party members, have cleaner governments than “fully authoritarian” regimes that lack these institutions (Boix Reference Boix2003; Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011; Yadav and Mukherjee Reference Yadav and Mukherjee2016). However, despite these and other arguments, there is wide variation in tolerance for corruption among authoritarian regimes of the same type. As Carothers (Reference Carothers2021; Reference CarothersForthcoming 2022) notes, while many personalist regimes are deeply corrupt, in a substantial number of cases dictators have led effective anti-corruption efforts. The North Korean case shows how tolerance for corruption can shift dramatically within the same regime following change in the economic system and the regime's financial or political needs. This variability casts doubt not only on the predictive power of regime type but also on culture-based explanations of cross-national variation in corruption.

The analysis in this study proceeds in five steps. First, I discuss how Kim Il-sung faced the problem of post-war corruption and launched anti-corruption campaigns throughout the 1950s. Second, I ask whether these campaigns were a means for the Chairman to attack his political rivals during the factional conflicts of the mid-1950s. Third, I examine the available evidence regarding the campaign's outcomes and how the evidence fits into existing scholarship on corruption in the Kim Il-sung era. Fourth, I explain how the economic and political crisis of the 1990s led to an explosion of corruption. And fifth, I show how since the 2000s the regime has embraced a variety of forms of corruption and has benefitted from corruption's institutionalization.

Kim Il-sung's anti-corruption campaigns

Following the devastation of the Korean War, the North Korean regime prioritized economic recovery and rapid development. As Balazs Szalontai writes, “economic reconstruction was given preference to almost every other consideration, even military service” (Szalontai Reference Szalontai2005, 45). The regime used its extensive control over society to mobilize the “entire population for reconstruction work” (Szalontai Reference Szalontai2005, 45). The post-war regime pursued development so forcefully both because of its ideological commitment to building a modern socialist state and because continuing inter-Korean competition made development a security imperative. After the war ended without reunification, the contest was on for both Koreas to out-develop their rival state. The North soon pulled ahead of the South—a threatening development for South Koreans that helped justify a coup in Seoul in May 1961.Footnote 3

Yet the regime's development agenda was threatened by corruption, which had grown in the early 1950s as a result of the Korean War. As the conflict dragged on long past Kim Il-sung's initial predictions of swift victory, North Korea suffered economically and party morale faltered, leading to a rise in embezzlement and other forms of corruption and indiscipline. A political knowledge handbook (정치지식) from 1952 captured by United Nations forces reveals what the Chairman wanted to tell his party members and soldiers about the issue. In it, Kim Il-sung is quoted as criticizing the growing trends of misappropriation and misuse of state resources and collusion with “dishonest merchants.” He cites the case of a rubber plant in Pyongyang where there had been “manipulation of production statistics and then selling based on those false numbers, stealing from the national finance. … Many party members in the factory failed to report and criticize this action at the appropriate time,” (Chŏngch'i Chisik 1952, 2–9). A report from the Polish Embassy in North Korea from August 1952 noted that:

Two groups of 5 people each, including the deputy to the general prosecutor of the Republic, have been executed by firing squad for theft and squandering of state property, while the general prosecutor was also dismissed and imprisoned. The total amount of losses incurred by the state through the criminal activity of only one of these groups reached 130 million wons [sic] (WCDA 1952a).

North Korean authorities repeatedly asserted that embezzlement and other forms of indiscipline were due to “remnants of Japanese colonial thinking” and “the influence of capitalism,” and could undermine the new anti-imperialist and socialist regime (Chŏngch'i Chisik 1952, 9).

In February 1952, Kim Il-sung launched the Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Campaign (반탐오, 반낭비투쟁) in the hopes of reversing these troubling trends (US National Archives and Records Administration 1952, Box 1214). This campaign would, he argued, raise the quality of party members, support the war economy, and ultimately help ensure military victory. “In all our institutions,” Kim Il-sung claimed, “there will be strict statistics and control … systematic inspection of expenditures … and sharp criticism and self-criticism to make the theft, embezzlement, and waste of the people's money impossible” (Chŏngch'i Chisik 1952, 2–9). Kim Il-sung was also concerned about the related problem of bureaucratism, especially bureaucrats acting like small tyrants over their subordinates, which had made the leadership in party and state organs ineffective (US National Archives and Records Administration 1952, Boxes 1211, 1214, 1224). Furthermore, there would be a campaign to raise the “consciousness” of cadres, so that they would “cherish the people's money.” If these “immoral” remnants of Japanese thought could not be eliminated, and if “financial regulations cannot be strengthened,” then “the war cannot be won” (Chŏngch'i Chisik 1952, 2–9).

The Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Campaign was modeled at least in part on China's Three Antis Campaign (三反运动), which the Chinese Communist Party had launched in 1951 to address its own post-war corruption (Teiwes Reference Teiwes1978). Kim Il-sung discussed the success of the Three Antis in the rollout of his own campaign (Xu Reference Xu2000, 260). Moreover, the North Korean campaign often used identically worded slogans to the Three Antis: “a struggle against corruption, bureaucratism, and waste,” despite the fact that it dropped the “anti-bureaucratism” in its title (US National Archives and Records Administration 1952, Box 1224). As the Polish Embassy in North Korea reported, the campaign was “using the example of the actions (Three-anti and Five-anti campaigns) conducted in the People's Republic of China” (WCDA 1952a).

Despite the launch of this campaign, wrongdoing by government officials and employees continued to threaten the fragile North Korean economy after the signing of the Korean Armistice Agreement in 1953. Investigations found that theft and waste had lost consumer cooperatives more than 280 million won in the first half of 1954, which was more than half their total profit for the period (WCDA 1955c). Theft and waste also deprived Pyongyang of nearly all its potential income from commission shops, whose employees would rather sell goods on the private market through speculators (WCDA 1955c). At the Tenth KWP Central Committee plenum in April 1955, Kim Il-sung warned that “approximately 1/3 of all resources and materials [are] being wrongly spent and partially looted in all sectors of the state and cooperative economy” (WCDA 1955e). This bleak assessment reflected how keenly aware the party leadership was of that year's food shortages and other economic problems (Szalontai Reference Szalontai2005, 69).

At the 1955 plenum, Kim Il-sung re-launched the Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Campaign and also announced the accompanying Self-Confession Campaign (자백운동), which aimed to elicit confessions from officials guilty of misappropriating funds, illicit profit-seeking, and other misdeeds (WCDA 1955a). Kim Il-sung said that the former campaign would be “a mass movement to improve cadre management of businesses and remold thought in the whole nation”—the first such movement after the end of the Korean War (Sin Reference Sin2008, 215). He called for “the establishment of daily monitoring and strict discipline in the expenditure of financial resources and materials, and a national struggle against theft and embezzlement” (WCDA 1955e).

The Self-Confession Campaign focused on theft of national assets and other “impure activities” during and after the war, especially in the “commercial distribution department and economic institutions” (North Korea Overview 1968, 183). The nationwide campaign, which had a wide reach within state organizations, cooperatives, and even the armed forces, was organized through commissions at various levels of the state. The campaign set national standards for punishing embezzlement and other corrupt behaviors—e.g. cadres who embezzled between 50,000 and 300,000 won faced “forced labor work from six months to a year.” However, it was not just the amount of money involved that determined the level of punishment. The state also took into consideration, according to its own instructions for the campaign, any “services [rendered] in the country's struggle for liberation and freedom,” the guilty party's actions during national reconstruction, the guilty party's intentions in committing this crime, and the feelings of the public regarding the guilty party (WCDA 1955a). Both of the anti-corruption campaigns would last for three years and end in August 1958.

In sum, growing corruption during and after the Korean War threatened to undermine the country's post-war recovery and the regime's ambitious development plans, leading Kim Il-sung to launch substantial reform campaigns throughout the 1950s.

Was anti-corruption actually about purging rivals?

Anti-corruption campaigns launched by autocrats are in many cases excuses to purge political rivals or undertake other self-interested maneuvers. Would this be a fair reading of Kim Il-sung's campaigns?

Kim Il-sung's re-launch of his anti-corruption efforts in 1955 overlapped with intense factional struggle for leadership of the KWP between 1955 and 1958. Although Kim Il-sung was already a powerful dictator in the early 1950s, he was not yet the infallible, unquestionable leader that he would later become (WCDA 1955c). To solidify his leadership of the KWP, Kim Il-sung purged hundreds of high-ranking officials between 1955 and 1958, quashing the KWP's Soviet faction, the domestic faction, and the Yan'an (Chinese) faction in favor of his own guerrilla faction. Shen Zhihua and Xia Yafeng argue that Kim Il-sung “was successful in establishing his personal authority over all the factions in the KWP” even before the August 1956 Incident, in which his leadership was challenged, but that “dissenting voices within the KWP were not completely eliminated” (Shen and Xia Reference Shen and Xia2018, 89). At the absolute latest, it is clear that from March 1958 onward Kim Il-sung ruled without challenge (Shen and Xia Reference Shen and Xia2018, 126–127).

Contrary to what one might assume, anti-corruption barely featured in all this factional conflict. Both scholarly accounts and archival documents about the purges surrounding the August 1956 Incident (and also earlier and later purges in the 1950s) overwhelmingly describe the “crimes” these party officials were purged for as being political—criticizing Kim Il-sung, criticizing the cult of personality, cooperating with foreign powers, and so on (Lee and Oh Reference Lee and Oh1968; Person Reference Person2019). For example, Szalontai (Reference Szalontai2005) makes no mention of corruption or charges of corruption in relation to any of the high-profile purges.

Autocrats often use accusations of corruption to justify purging political rivals, but for Kim Il-sung in the late 1950s, this kind of excuse was not necessary. He was openly accusing his rivals of being anti-party factionalists, coup plotters, American-backed spies, or traitors—all much more serious charges than corruption. Former foreign minister Pak Hŏnyŏng and former secretary of the Central Committee Yi Sŭng-yŏp were purged on trumped-up charges of being American spies trying to foment a coup (WCDA 1956e; Lee and Oh Reference Lee and Oh1968, 276). Central Committee members Pak Ch'ang-ok and Ch'oe Ch'ang-ik, who led the movement to challenge Kim Il-sung's one-man rule, were repeatedly attacked by the Chairman and his supporters as “anti-party factionalists,” and purged explicitly for their political speeches and actions (WCDA 1956f; WCDA 1957a; WCDA 1957c). Former chairman of the KWP Kim Tubong was also accused of being part of this anti-party group (WCDA 1957c). Minister of Trade Yun Kong-hŭm was purged for disagreeing with Kim Il-sung, who labeled him and his supporters a “hostile anti-Party faction” and accused them of plotting a takeover (WCDA 1956e; WCDA 1957a; Person Reference Person2019). Vice Premier Pak Ui-wan and former minister of the coal industry Yi Songwook were expelled for being “connected to the August group” (WCDA 1958). Trade Union Federation Central Committee Chairman Sǒ Hwi and Head of Construction Materials Yi P'il-gyu were purged for “anti-party activity” (WCDA 1956b). And former DPRK ambassador to Moscow Yi Sang-jo was attacked for being “infected by the cult of personality,” meaning that he opposed Kim Il-sung's leadership, and for illicitly cooperating with Pak Ui-wan (WCDA 1956d; WCDA 1958).

Only a few high-ranking officials were arrested primarily on corruption charges in this period. Kim Yeol, who had earned the nickname “king of swindlers” during his tenure as Chairman of the Party Committee of South Hamgyeong Province, was brought down by criticism from party members shortly after the re-launch of the anti-corruption campaign (WCDA 1955d). Central Committee Member and Minister of Communications Pak Il-U was purged for “anti-party, factional activity” in 1955, but among the charges leveled against Pak by the KWP Central Committee were the theft and misuse of “enormous state resources” (WCDA 1955b).

In sum, while there was a temporal overlap between factional conflict and continuing anti-corruption efforts, the latter should not be written off as an excuse for Kim Il-sung to purge rivals in his political struggles. Kim Il-sung mostly did not use accusations of corruption to attack his rivals, and both anti-corruption investigations and anti-corruption reforms extended far beyond elite factional conflict, as discussed below.

Anti-corruption Outcomes

The existing evidence suggests that Kim Il-sung's anti-corruption campaigns were at least somewhat effective at curbing corruption and aided the country's rapid economic development. The campaigns produced wide-ranging anti-corruption enforcement—investigations and punishments—as well as institutional reforms that tightened the government's control over officials’ economic activity, winning positive contemporaneous assessments from outside analysts.

After Kim Il-sung launched the first anti-corruption campaign, in February 1952, the Polish Embassy reported to Warsaw in July that without a doubt “the current action of purging the state and economic apparatuses is strengthening them” (WCDA 1952a). A follow-up report in December 1952 noted that North Korea's state apparatus was “increasingly efficient and effective;” “the leadership of the KWP has to a certain degree purged the state and social apparatuses, and mostly brought them closer to the masses” (WCDA 1952b). The wartime cleanup was particularly effective in Hamheung City, where after numerous discoveries of “mistakes,” “dishonesty,” and “abuses,” all the members of the City Committee of the KWP were dismissed (WCDA 1953).

Anti-corruption enforcement increased after the end of the Korean War. A stunning 22,000 party members were investigated for acts of embezzlement between June 1953 and July 1954 (WCDA 1955c). It is not clear whether this represents a spike in enforcement or simply a lack of information about anti-corruption investigations in subsequent years. In 1955, Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Commissions were established at central, provincial, city, and lower levels of government to monitor them. These commissions reportedly sent 6,000 people to do hard labor and disciplined more than 2,000 others for corruption and waste. In Pyongyang alone, some 400 officials lost their jobs or party membership, and some were executed (North Korea Overview 1968, 183). “In 1955 more than 70% of all court cases were connected with the theft, misappropriation, and waste of state and cooperative property, and bribery and squandering of state and cooperative money” (WCDA 1956g).

The Self-Confession Campaign elicited numerous confessions, mostly regarding the theft of state assets. “For example, 12 percent of all the members in a producer's cooperative of the province of North Hwanghae confessed to theft and squandering” (WCDA 1956g). The North Korean journal Kŭlloja (근로자, Worker) reported that many people who confessed in the campaign also implicated other low-level officials. In public meetings, supposedly non-coerced participants compelled these officials to confess, even yelling swear words at them and threatening them (Kŭlloja 1955b, 5). After confessing, offenders would continue to be watched to prevent recidivism (Kŭlloja 1955b, 9). Both this campaign and the Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Campaign were accompanied by mass propaganda and lengthy educational meetings of the kind that would have been familiar to people living in Maoist China (NK Chosun 2013).

Beyond increasing anti-corruption enforcement, the regime also undertook various institutional reforms that strengthened its ability to check the emergence of new corrupt activity. In addition to the nationwide network of Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Commissions, the government also ordered auditing commissions to be established both at the central level and within cooperatives. Agricultural cooperatives’ auditing commissions were composed of three to five people and met at least quarterly to monitor the cooperative's finances and prevent “theft and embezzlement” (WCDA 1956c). The regime leadership understood that the state's ability to function cleanly depended on improving its ability to “study and monitor the staff of state institutions” (WCDA 1956a). By 1955, the KPW recognized that mistakes made in grain collection had allowed officials to steal grain and engage in rampant speculation, and that this was a critical problem for the economy (WCDA 1955f). But the party was able to undertake reforms to reduce theft and speculation, including strengthening government oversight of private trade, according to the Chinese Embassy in North Korea (WCDA 1957b).

In addition, personnel reorganization strengthened anti-corruption organs. After the KWP plenum in April 1955, the Central Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Commission was packed with important officials. It was headed by Choe Yong-geon, Minister of Defense and Deputy Chairman of the Cabinet of Ministers, and had as members “the chief of the KWP CC Organization Department, the Minister of State Control, the Minister of Internal Affairs, the Minister of Finance, the General Procurator, the Chairman of the KWP CC Control Commission,” and others (WCDA 1955a). The DPRK “State Control Commission was turned into the Ministry of State Control,” and personnel were reshuffled to put experienced officials at the helm (WCDA 1955a).

Just as Polish intelligence judged North Korea's anti-corruption measures in 1952 to have been effective, Soviet intelligence on the new measures announced in 1955 assessed them positively. In December 1955, the Soviet ambassador to the DPRK reported back to Moscow that “the steps taken have had a positive influence on strengthening financial discipline, austerity measures, and control over the waste of money and material” (WCDA 1955a). In an overview of the DPRK's economic situation in June 1960, Soviet analysts noted that North Korea's successful economic recovery and rapid development had been aided by successful efforts to rein in various “abuses of administrative authority” by KWP officials (WCDA 1960). Critics might argue that foreign countries friendly to North Korea gave biased assessments of the Kim regime's policies, but Polish and Soviet diplomats were often critical of domestic policies in North Korea that they disagreed with and had previously reported on the situation of widespread corruption.

The state-run journal Kŭlloja discussed anti-corruption work as helpful to national development, while also admitting errors. It reported concrete improvements in economic efficiency as a result of Kim Il-sung's anti-corruption campaigns, citing the examples of a textile machine factory and a tobacco plant, both in Pyongyang (Kŭlloja 1955a, 72–74). It also credited Kim Il-sung's April 1955 speech with improving leadership quality at all levels in the party and therefore advancing socialist construction and the socialist revolution (Kŭlloja 1960). Yet the campaigns did not always run smoothly. The journal noted that although some activists came forward from the masses to support anti-corruption work (as should happen in mass campaigns), many citizens were only passive participants. Sometimes the party organizations were not making the right decisions on leniency versus punishment for offenders, or were not taking the campaigns seriously enough. Moreover, dogmatism and formalism in the teaching of party literature had led to some “lost morale” in the anti-corruption campaign (Kŭlloja 1955a, 70).

That these anti-corruption campaigns were effective overall helps explain the finding of several North Korea scholars that corruption was relatively low in the Kim Il-sung era, at least compared to what came after the system broke down. Andrei Lankov explains that, in the 1960s and 1970s, “while personal connections mattered and nepotism was rampant, there was relatively little graft and embezzlement was not commonplace” (Lankov Reference Lankov2015). The Public Distribution System, which was more extensive even than those in other communist countries, made money less useful, and therefore less tempting. Many luxury goods were available to officials of a certain rank but could not otherwise be purchased, decreasing incentives for in-kind bribe-taking. North Korean newspapers and journals in this period sometimes discussed the problem of corruption, but this was almost always with reference to South Korea and its corrupt military regime (e.g. Ryu Reference Ryu1967). Certainly, Kim Il-sung and his family abused their positions for financial gain in this period (Martin Reference Martin2004, 186), but the point is that there were limits on the regime's tolerance for corruption throughout the state in general (Silberstein Reference Silberstein2019). Avram Agov notes that North Korea's “low level of corruption … increased the efficiency” of how socialist aid was used (Agov Reference Agov2010, 31). Kim Sung Chull argues that it was only in the late 1980s that an influx of foreign capital and the growth of black market activity led to a substantial rise in “bureaucratic deviance,” which “typically appeared as corruption, such as bribes and embezzlement” (Kim Reference Kim2006, 77).

Systemic Crisis and an Explosion of Corruption

North Korea's period of relative stability came to an end in the 1990s, when the country suffered a systemic crisis. The loss of critical Soviet aid at the beginning of the decade, as mentioned, triggered the North Korean economy's implosion. Economic difficulties led to a weakening of state power and increased social unrest. The Public Distribution System, which had been more important and was responsible for providing a greater variety of goods than in other socialist countries, broke down. Unusually severe flooding and droughts hit North Korea in 1994 and 1995. The North Korean Famine, which began in 1994, reduced the population by 600,000 to 1 million people, or possibly significantly more (Noland Reference Noland2004). This period of economic suffering and starvation, known in North Korea as the Arduous March (고난의 행군), lasted at least until 1998.

The crisis of the 1990s greatly exacerbated bribery and embezzlement by officials and petty corruption throughout society, whether these actions were motivated by greed or—as in many cases—desperation (Pak et al. Reference Pak, Hyŏnchun, Yŏngcha and Ch'ŏlki2012, 171). The collapse of the Public Distribution System was a major culprit in motivating embezzlement by any citizens or officials with access to state resources, and the system was never fully reconstituted (OHCHR 2019, 2). Appallingly, North Korea's numerous state employees were still required to show up to work at factories and offices even after the state ceased to be able to pay them. Disillusioned and in need, many began to abuse their positions to earn money instead, demanding bribes for basic services and looting state assets to set up private business ventures. “Public anger is … typically reflected in growing corruption, black market activities, and other anti-system behavior” (Natsios Reference Natsios1999, 1). In 1998, Kim Jong-il, Supreme Leader following his father's death, admitted to Japanese visitors that corruption at the important Hwanghae Steel Mill (in North Hwanghae Province) had become so extreme that nearly everyone working there was complicit. The army had to be sent to “surround the mill,” after which it arrested the thieves and recovered some of the stolen property (Martin Reference Martin2004, 573). The government did not revise its anti-corruption laws or punishment standards to reflect the new reality that paying bribes or stealing state resources was often done out of desperation, meaning that there was sometimes vicious enforcement of standards that even North Koreans highly loyal to the regime could no longer meet.

The regime intermittently tried to control the growing indiscipline with new crackdowns and high-profile arrests, but had little success. In 1992, then-heir apparent Kim Jong-il wrote a letter to party cadres warning about the evils of “anti-socialist” behavior, “commercial activity,” and “corrupt activity” (Quoted in Chŏn et al. Reference Chŏn, Kuksin, Yŏngt'ae, Suyŏng and Chinhwan2009, 262). The regime launched a large-scale two-year anti-corruption campaign between 1991 and 1993 and pursued investigations into “anti-socialist” activity in localities across the country (Kim Reference Kim1996, 97; Pak et al. Reference Pak, Hyŏnchun, Yŏngcha and Ch'ŏlki2012, 172). One crackdown in 1992 targeted “widespread civilian looting” and “extortion of food supplies by government officials” (Quoted in Martin Reference Martin2004, 834). During the famine, officials could be sentenced to death for stealing or trading grain (Haggard and Noland Reference Haggard and Noland2007, 170). The kŭruppa (그루빠), special investigatory teams, were often deployed to root out corruption. “A particular target was Kimchaek Iron and Steel [in Chongjin], the largest steelworks in North Korea.” Eventually, “the steelworks’ managers … were executed by firing squad” (Demick Reference Demick2010, 184).Footnote 4 In the scandal involving perhaps the highest-ranking official, Chairperson of the Kim Il Sung Socialist Youth League and member of the KWP Central Committee Ch'oe Ryonghae was sentenced to death for selling scrap metal “(collected by youth league members) to foreign buyers without official permission” (North Korea Leadership Watch 2018). But Ch'oe was saved by personal connections within the regime's inner circle. In 1998, authorities also arrested the head of the Rajin-Sonbong Special Development Project (Martin Reference Martin2004, 641).

The Regime Embraces Corruption

The 1990s crisis brought about permanent changes in North Korea's economic system, most notably widespread de facto marketization. This marketization was grassroots-led; unable to rely on the Public Distribution System, households turned to informal markets to barter and trade for food and other necessities. Local party and government units increasingly engaged in illicit commerce and entrepreneurial activity to make ends meet. The regime initially resisted marketization, sometimes with harsh crackdowns, but the state's control over society had weakened and the economic necessity of marketization was undeniable. The regime formalized its acceptance of at least some of the economic liberalization that had taken place with a set of agricultural and financial reform measures in 2002. Accepting economic change that was already taking place was a way for the regime to impose greater post-hoc control over the process (Noland Reference Noland2006, 195).

In the country's increasingly marketized economy, corruption took on a new and often productive role. Whereas in the Kim Il-sung era corruption had siphoned resources away from the state and undercut the regime's developmental agenda, afterwards it began to facilitate commerce and help generate profits. Recent research on the post-famine economy highlights at least three emerging varieties of corruption in North Korea that have been economically productive. These can be summarized as: the widespread use of bribes by small entrepreneurs to facilitate trade and other market activity, state–business collusion involving large private players, and various forms of illegal and semi-legal integration between state-owned and private enterprises. Since the early 2000s, these varieties of corruption have all become institutionalized and have become regular features of the new North Korean economy. The same is true of the regime's well-documented criminal activities abroad, which, while not necessarily “productive,” have certainly helped the regime financially.Footnote 5

First and most widespread is the use of bribes to bypass restrictions on trading and other market activity. This fits with the old argument that corruption can help “grease the wheels” of an overly regulated economy (Leys Reference Leys1965, 215–230). In surveys of recent refugees, “fully 85 percent of respondents reported that they needed to pay bribes to engage in market activity,” Stephan Haggard and Marcus Noland find (Haggard and Noland Reference Haggard and Noland2012, 681). Ordinary citizens and small entrepreneurs pay bribes to officials who agree to overlook their illegal or semi-legal businesses, unapproved travel throughout the country, or unsanctioned trade with Chinese companies. The practice of paying bribes as the cost of doing business—essentially as a form of taxation—has become institutionalized, often including with clear rules about how much is expected by what level of official and what service is to be rendered (Silberstein Reference Silberstein2010). Many bribes are small and are paid with cigarettes, alcohol, or grains, but for more serious “offenses,” the bribes must be accordingly larger. Hastings and Wang (Reference Hastings and Wang2018) explores this issue in the context of cross-border trade with China. The article finds that Chinese traders hoping to make formal investments in North Korea may need to bribe “essentially every official involved in the process: border guards, customs officials, and local and high-level Party, military, and government officials” (Hastings and Wang Reference Hastings and Wang2018, 192). In sectors where goods and services had previously been allocated according to political or ideological rules, such as housing, “bribery has become institutionalized in ways akin to the setting of a market price” (Park Reference Park2015, 137). Moreover, it is worth noting that in much of this bribery there is a gender dynamic at play. Men dominate positions of power in the state and use them to extract resources from market actors, who are more likely to be women; surveys find that “95% of female traders report paying bribes” (Haggard and Noland Reference Haggard and Noland2013).

Second, large private economic actors use corruption to gain access to and protection from the state as they manage their businesses. North Korea's new class of wealthy private elites, known as “money masters” (tonju, 돈주), has a corrupt yet symbiotic relationship with the state. Through connections and relationships, tonju gain permission to use state assets to generate profits, with their state partners of course taking a sizeable cut (Kong Reference Kong2020). State–business collusion may take many forms, such as tonju “renting” access to state factories for production, buying official titles that allow them to bypass regulations, investing in and realizing profits from state-owned building projects, or mobilizing private resources to help state-owned enterprises meet their production goals. Chŏng Yŏngch'ŏl argues that recent legislative changes, such as the 2015 amendments to North Korea's Enterprise Law, show that the regime is trying to further mobilize the tonju's economic power (Chŏng Reference Chŏng2019). Given its own financial limitations, the North Korean state has no choice but to increasingly rely on mutually beneficial cooperation with large private actors (Kwŏn Reference Kwŏn2020). In this process, Kim (Reference Kim2020, 3) highlights how a noticeable number of women have become tonju and how these women have sometimes won praise from Kim Jong-un for their individual contributions to the fulfillment of the state's economic plans.

Third, related and sometimes overlapping with the tonju's collusion with the state, there are varied forms of illegal and semi-legal public-private integration that have facilitated economic activity. Since the early 2000s, there has been a proliferation of “pseudo-state enterprises”: enterprises that on paper are state-owned but in practice are controlled by private interests that take most of the profits (Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017a). Private entrepreneurs choose to tie themselves to the state in this way because their activities lack a legal framework and they need to protect themselves. Becoming a pseudo-state enterprise also makes it easier for entrepreneurs to hire and manage personnel (Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017b). The financial cooperation between entrepreneurs and state agents is often sophisticated, with de facto stakeholders, dividends, and sometimes agreements resembling a “management buy-in.” At the same time, “it should not be forgotten that every PSE-operating entrepreneur is technically guilty of large-scale embezzlement as well as a multitude of other ‘economic crimes,’ many punishable with death” (Lankov et al. Reference Lankov, Ward, Yoo and Kim2017a, 60). Embezzlement has not always been productive—sometimes it is simply looting—but in many cases diverted state assets become the capital for productive business ventures. Besides pseudo-state enterprises, many other privately managed enterprises fall on a spectrum of embeddedness with the state. Peter Ward, Andrei Lankov, and Kim Ji-young find that enterprises fall into four rough categories: closely embedded, loosely embedded, semi-autonomous, or autonomous (Ward, Lankov, and Kim Reference Ward, Lankov and Kim2021). Their study shows the limits of North Korean state power, which is sometimes erroneously seen as absolute. In addition, illegal or semi-legal state–business collusion is also happening within fully state-owned enterprises, such as with the use of “funding squads”—essentially private contractors. State-owned enterprises increasingly rely on funding squads to provide labor and mobilize state assets. Some funding squads work specifically on projects that earn foreign currency for the regime. Entrepreneurs who organize funding squads, including tonju, can make large profits and obtain privileges associated with state employment (Kim Reference Kim2006, 155–60).

These varieties of corruption have been invaluable to the regime financially. Ordinary bribes provided by or extorted from citizens and small entrepreneurs are essential to the livelihoods of many government officials. With nominal wages so low, much of the North Korean bureaucracy might cease to function without this stream of revenue. Anti-corruption inspectors themselves have become bribe-collectors, defectors report (Kim Reference Kim2013). Even the elite kŭruppa had become corrupted by the early 2000s (Pak et al. Reference Pak, Hyŏnchun, Yŏngcha and Ch'ŏlki2012, 40, 172). Tonju-led businesses generate profits that partly fund the regime's operation and tonju investments support the state-run economy. Pseudo-state enterprises and other forms of public–private partnerships allow for the more effective mobilization of state assets. Some state organizations support themselves through control of business activities that would be illegal for others. The Korean People's Army, for example, earns revenue through the monopolies it holds on certain manufacturing and construction projects, without which it would financially “drown” (Daily NK 2015).

Moreover, the institutionalization of various forms of corruption has specifically benefitted North Korea's “court economy”—the money and goods flowing directly to the personal accounts of members of the ruling Kim family and a small group of other elites. The Kim family's special privileges are of course not new phenomenon starting in the 1990s, but Kim Jong-il had more extravagant tastes than his father and there is some evidence that luxury imports increased yet again in the early years of the Kim Jong-un era (Kim Reference Kim2014). John S. Park (Reference Park2009) explains how the regime's “hierarchical food chain” demands that new revenue should fund government operations only after a designated percentage goes into the leader's personal accounts (Park Reference Park2009, 9). The money in these accounts goes not only toward luxury goods for top elites, but also toward projects that glorify the Kim family and the regime, such as parades on national holidays, Park notes.

Corruption has helped the regime not only financially, but also politically. Officials able to enrich themselves by abusing their position of power in a regime are not likely to challenge it. Refugee surveys from the 2000s reveal that official positions are greatly sought after in North Korea not because hard work or merit are rewarded but because “public office constitutes an entitlement and increasingly provides a platform for engaging in business or corrupt or criminal rent extraction” (Haggard and Noland Reference Haggard and Noland2010, 77). Ordinary citizens hate having to pay bribes to avoid government harassment, of course, but they find the current system much preferable to the government actually enforcing its theoretical bans on capitalist activity. Allowing corrupt practices also reduces discontent among private economic elites. Because wealthy elites can buy their way out of the strict controls of the North Korean system—including restrictions on where one can live, where one can travel to, what one can own, and what business one can engage in—there is less chance that this potentially powerful class will protest or lobby the government for systemic change. The state demands a portion of tonju's profits from their semi-legal business empires, but allows them to live a luxurious and relatively free lifestyle in North Korea as long as they demonstrate loyalty to the Kim family. On the whole, the spread of corruption has served as an escape valve for anger over oppressive government rather than as a catalyst for public mobilization against the regime, as has sometimes been the case in other countries (Kwŏn Reference Kwŏn2020).

After Kim Jong-un came to power in Reference Kim2011, he seemed to challenge the regime's tolerance for pervasive corruption by ramping up rhetoric about the need to curb government wrongdoing.Footnote 6 His administration advanced the slogan of “war against corruption” (부정부패와의 투쟁) and he consistently raises the issue of corruption in his important New Year's addresses. In November 2012, Kim Jong-un instructed prosecutors to “strengthen the legal struggle against the phenomenon of corruption and waste of national assets” (Minjujosŏn 2013). Under Kim Jong-un, corruption is more likely to be publicized and discussed in state-run media than previously. In a typical statement, the party mouthpiece Rodong Sinmun argued in an editorial in 2018 that “abuses of authority, bureaucratism, and corruption are totally unacceptable enemies to our party, which as the mother-party responsible for and watching over the fate of the people struggles to maintain its original nature and shine” (Rodong Sinmun 2018). At the Eighth Party Congress in January 2021, Kim Jong-un reiterated that “abuse of power” was a problem within the KPW at all levels and placed the topic at the top of the agenda for one of the congress's plenary session (Zwirko Reference Zwirko2021).

However, there is little evidence that Kim Jong-un has gone beyond anti-corruption rhetoric and launched a serious campaign to reverse the growth of corruption described above. Whereas Kim Il-sung's campaigns in the 1950s involved institutional reforms aimed at disincentivizing wrongdoing, the Kim Jong-un administration has failed to enact reforms that would reduce incentives for officials to take bribes or extort citizens, prevent state–business collusion, or set transparent standards for the informal arrangements that have sprung up between state-owned and private enterprises. In fact, his administration has taken steps to encourage tonju investment in the state-owned economy in return for special privileges. Tonju have only grown more important to state enterprises and planning under Kim Jong-un (Park et al. Reference Park, Jeong-ah, Hwan, Eunlee, Mee, Seogki, Youngsun and HoJye2018, 28). Moreover, the Kim Jong-un administration's crackdowns on corruption have been much more narrowly targeted than Kim Il-sung's were. For example, a crackdown that began in late 2018 resulted in the purge of “some 50 to 70 individuals” (Jeong and Martin Reference Jeong and Martin2019). The goal of the crackdown was likely to confiscate assets from wealthy elites who had been accumulating foreign currency—the regime may have netted several million dollars—and to silence critics of Kim Jong-un's diplomatic opening to the US, according to the Seoul-based North Korea Strategy Center (Jeong and Martin Reference Jeong and Martin2019). Sometimes the targets are individual elites. During the highly public purge and execution of Jang Song-thaek, Kim Jong-un's uncle-in-law, one of the accusations that the regime leveled was that Jang had allegedly spent “4.6 million Euros” in a “foreign casino” (Minjujosŏn 2013). More recently, early 2020 saw two high-profile cases: the purges of Director of the Organization and Guidance Department and KPW Vice Chairman Ri Man'gŏn and Pak T'aedŏk, also a KPW Vice Chairman, for corruption and other abuses of power. Intermittent crackdowns aimed at individuals or small groups of elites suggest that so far Kim Jong-un is primarily concerned with keeping elites in line rather than bringing about systemic reform.

In sum, in the context of North Korea's increasing marketization in the late 1990s and 2000s, various forms of corruption helped facilitate market activity and generate profits. After some initial resistance, the regime accepted the spread of corruption as economically and politically necessary. The Kim Jong-un administration has repeatedly promised to crack down on corruption, but there is little evidence that the regime has made any serious attempt to dismantle the pervasive corrupt arrangements that it has come to rely on.

Conclusion

A perennial question in the study of North Korea is how the regime has endured and remained stable, especially after the systemic crisis of the 1990s. This article's findings suggest that the regime's strategic use of corruption and anti-corruption is one often overlooked factor that helps explain its durability through crises. Early on, combating corruption helped the regime to overcome the economic difficulties that resulted from the Korean War and threatened to hobble North Korea in the critical post-war decade. Kim Il-sung's Anti-Corruption and Anti-Waste Campaign and Self-Confession Campaign prevented or reversed large-scale theft from the state by corrupt actors. By contributing to the country's post-war reconstruction and rapid development, anti-corruption efforts indirectly aided the regime's construction of the powerful state apparatus that would enforce a harsh domestic stability throughout the Kim Il-sung era. After the crisis of the 1990s, reversing course and allowing corruption helped the regime to stay afloat both financially and politically. As the incidence of corruption increased amidst an unprecedented economic collapse, the Kim Jong-il administration initially tried to use harsh anti-corruption crackdowns to restore order and stem the looting of state resources. But the regime soon found that the country's economic system had undergone irreversible changes and that in an increasingly marketized economy corruption actually served to generate capturable profits. Since 2000, the regime leadership has used targeted anti-corruption crackdowns to keep wealthy elites in check and purge political rivals while continuing to tolerate a wide range of nominally illegal capitalist practices by officials, businesspeople, and ordinary citizens.

Considered from a comparative perspective, North Korea's trajectory on the issue of corruption is unusual, but it also has points of similarity with other authoritarian cases. South Korea is often a natural comparative case for North Korea, and indeed Kim Il-sung's anti-corruption efforts were not entirely dissimilar from the campaigns launched by Park Chung-hee in the 1960s and 1970s, such as the General Administrative Reform (서정쇄신, 1973–77). Like Kim Il-sung, Park was also motivated to curb corruption by the need to support an ambitious developmental agenda, although a capitalist one (Carothers Reference CarothersForthcoming 2022). The boom of corruption in North Korea in the 1990s was extreme, but also similar to the rapid spread of embezzlement and bribe-taking in Cuba in the 1990s following the devastating reduction of Soviet aid there. Revolutionary leader Fidel Castro had initially brought corruption under control in the 1960s, but abuses of power expanded in the 1980s and exploded in the 1990s (See Thomas Reference Thomas1971, 1344; Domínguez Reference Domínguez1978, 230). China under the Chinese Communist Party, North Korea's closest foreign partner and a major influence, is another regime which has at different times combated and tolerated corruption to advance its interests and maintain its rule. In the 1980s, Deng Xiaoping largely accepted that corruption would increase as a side effect of China's economic liberalization. Much of the corruption in the early reform era was economically productive and, from Deng's perspective, gave local officials the right incentives to support further reforms (Kroeber Reference Kroeber2016, 207; Ang Reference Ang2020). Xi Jinping's anti-corruption campaign, which began in 2012 and is still ongoing, represents the most serious effort in decades to eliminate China's pervasive corruption.

Looking to the future, is the North Korean regime likely to undertake reforms to bring corruption under control? For various reasons, the prospects are slim. If we take Xi Jinping's sweeping campaign as a point of comparison, there are few signs that Kim Jong-un is launching a comparable campaign in North Korea, despite his heightened anti-corruption rhetoric in recent years. One reason is that North Korea has become an economic underperformer heavily reliant on illicit revenue streams and bribes funneled upwards from officials. In this regard, the regime is more similar to underperforming regimes in Turkmenistan, Zimbabwe, or Afghanistan, which Sarah Chayes has characterized as a “vertically integrated criminal syndicate” (Chayes Reference Chayes2015, 58). Moreover, waging an effective anti-corruption campaign requires a certain level of state capacity. Whereas the Chinese state has over the last few decades steadily grown richer, more professional, and more adept at using modern technology, North Korean state power was weakened by the crisis of the 1990s and continues to lag behind in its development in numerous areas. Perhaps most importantly, changing deeply entrenched norms of corruption requires a certain amount of disruption and upheaval. Kim Jong-un has led significant economic reforms since 2012, but he has also moved cautiously and incrementally; even the concept of “reform” is too provocative for the regime to openly embrace. In sum, corruption is likely to continue unchecked in North Korea at least until some future crisis or transformative moment for the regime and society.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares none.

Footnotes

1. See Heidenheimer and Johnston (Reference Heidenheimer and Johnston2002, 15–94) for a review of different definitions and uses.

2. The degree of personalism in North Korea has varied over time, but as Song and Wright (Reference Song and Wright2018) show, the regime was already highly personalist before the sharp rise in corruption in the 1990s.

3. Most expert assessments place the moment the South passed the North economically in the mid-1970s, e.g. Shen and Xia (Reference Shen and Xia2012), but Andrei Lankov has argued that it was actually earlier, around 1970 (Lankov Reference Lankov2018).

4. Demick argues that the highly unusual dissolution of the 6th corps of the People's Army in 1995 was most probably not because it had attempted a coup against the Kim family but because its officers were too corrupt, skimming too much money off for themselves (Demick Reference Demick2010, 183).

5. See Kan, Bechtol, and Collins (Reference Kan, Bechtol and Collins2010) for an overview.

6. Kim Jong-un has started using the word for corruption that is most commonly used in South Korea, pup'ae, which was not previously how most North Korean authorities had referred to the problem. This linguistic change reflects the growing influence of outside ideas on how North Koreans understand political and economic issues. Source: Author's interviews with South Korean experts on North Korea, January 2019.

References

List of References

Agov, Avram Asenov. 2010. “North Korea in the Socialist World: Integration and Divergence, 1945–1970. The Crossroads of Politics and Economics.” PhD diss., University of British Columbia.Google Scholar
Ang, Yuen Yuen. 2020. China's Gilded Age: The Paradox of Economic Boom and Vast Corruption. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa. 2011. Elections and Distributive Politics in Mubarak's Egypt. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brownlee, Jason. 2007. “Hereditary Succession in Modern Autocracies.” World Politics 59 (4): 595628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and Smith, Alastair. 2011. The Dictator's Handbook: Why Bad Behavior Is Almost Always Good Politics, 1st ed. New York: PublicAffairs.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Smith, Alastair, Siverson, Randolph, and Morrow, James. 2003. The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carothers, Christopher. 2021. “The Autocrat's Corruption Dilemma.” Government and Opposition, online: 1–17, doi:10.1017/gov.2021.23.Google Scholar
Carothers, Christopher. Forthcoming 2022. Corruption Control in Authoritarian Regimes: Lessons from East Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Chang, Eric, and Golden, Miriam A.. 2010. “Sources of Corruption in Authoritarian Regimes.” Social Science Quarterly 91 (1): 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chayes, Sarah. 2015. Thieves of State: Why Corruption Threatens Global Security. New York: WW Norton.Google Scholar
Chestnut, Sheena. 2007. “Illicit Activity and Proliferation: North Korean Smuggling Networks.” International Security 32 (1): 80111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chŏn, Hyŏnchun, Kuksin, Kim, Yŏngt'ae, Chŏng, Suyŏng, Ch'oe, and Chinhwan, Kim. 2009. Puk'an Kungnyŏng P'yŏngga Yŏn'guwŏn [North Korea's State Power Evaluation Study]. Seoul: T'ongiryŏn'guwŏn.Google Scholar
Chŏng, Yŏngch'ŏl. 2019. “Puk'an Kyŏngjeŭi Pyŏnhwat'kshijang, T'rtonjut,’ Kŭrigo Kukkaŭi Chaedŭngjang Chŏngyŏngch'ŏl Yŏksabip'yŏng” [Changes in North Korea's Economy—The Market, ‘Donju,’ and the Re-emergence of the State]. Yŏksabip'yŏng [Historical Criticism] 126: 134159.Google Scholar
“Chŏngch'i Chisik” [Political Knowledge]. 1952. Chungangwiwŏnhoe Sŏnjŏn Sŏndongbu [Central Committee Propaganda Agitation Department] 3, May. US National Archives and Records Administration, Record Group 242, Box 1223: National Archives Collection of Foreign Records Seized, 1675–1958.Google Scholar
Corruption Perceptions Index. 2018, Transparency International, www.transparency.org/en/cpi/2018/index/dnk.Google Scholar
Daily NK. 2015. “KPA and PLA's Corruption Problems Reflect Economic Differences.” Daily NK, March 30, www.dailynk.com/english/kpa-and-plas-corruption-problems-r/.Google Scholar
Demick, Barbara. 2010. Nothing to Envy: Real Lives in North Korea. London: Granta.Google Scholar
Minjujosŏn [Democratic Korea]. 2013. “Ch'ŏnman'gunminŭi ch'isonnŭn punnoŭi p'okpal man'goyŏkchŏng tanhohi ch'ŏdan” [The explosion of the soaring anger of 10 million people. Firmly punish the rebellion], December 13.Google Scholar
Domínguez, Jorge I. 1978. Cuba: Order and Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ezrow, Natasha M., and Frantz, Erica. 2011. Dictators and Dictatorships: Understanding Authoritarian Regimes and Their Leaders. New York: Bloomsbury Academic; Professional.Google Scholar
Geddes, Barbara. 1999. “What Do We Know about Democratization after Twenty Years?Annual Review of Political Science 2: 115144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guha, Ramachandra, ed. 2014. Makers of Modern Asia. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Noland, Marcus. 2007. Famine in North Korea: Markets, Aid, and Reform. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Noland, Marcus. 2010. Witness to Transformation: Refugee insights into North Korea. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Noland, Marcus. 2012. “Economic Crime and Punishment in North Korea.” Political Science Quarterly 127 (4): 659683.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Noland, Marcus. 2013. “Gender in Transition: The Case of North Korea.” World Development 41: 5166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hastings, Justin V., and Wang, Yaohui. 2018. “Informal Trade along the China–North Korea Border.” Journal of East Asian Studies 18 (2): 181203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heidenheimer, Arnold J., and Johnston, Michael. 2002. Political Corruption: Concepts & Contexts, 3rd ed. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Jeong, Andrew, and Martin, Timothy W.. 2019. “Kim Jong Un Purges Wealthy Elite and Opponents of Outreach to U.S.” The Wall Street Journal, February 19.Google Scholar
Jones, Will, De Oliveira, Ricardo Soares, and Verhoeven, Harry. 2013. “Africa's Illiberal State-Builders,” Refugee Studies Centre, Working Paper Series, No. 89.Google Scholar
Kailitz, Steffen. 2013. “Classifying Political Regimes Revisited: Legitimation and Durability.” Democratization 20 (1): 3960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kan, Paul Rexton, Bechtol, Bruce E., and Collins, Robert M.. 2010. Criminal Sovereignty: Understanding North Korea's Illicit International Activities. Strategic Studies Institute, US Army War College. www.hsdl.org/?view&did=26207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Byung-Kook. 2011. “The Leviathan: Economic Bureaucracy under Park.” In The Park Chung Hee Era: The Transformation of South Korea, edited by Kim Byung-Kook and Ezra F. Vogel. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Myŏngsŏng. 2013. “How Oppression in N. Korea Fuels Corruption.” Chosun Ilbo, November 18, http://english.chosun.com/site/data/html_dir/2013/11/18/2013111800497.html.Google Scholar
Kim, Soo. 2014. “Luxury Goods in North Korea: Tangible and Symbolic Importance to the Kim Jong-un Regime.” Korea Economic Institute of America, 7: 127138.Google Scholar
Kim, Sung Chull. 1996. “Development of Systemic Dissonance in North Korea.” Korean Journal of National Unification 5: 83109.Google Scholar
Kim, Sung Chull. 2006. North Korea under Kim Jong Il: From Consolidation to Systemic Dissonance. Albany: SUNY Press.Google Scholar
Kim, Sung Kyung. 2020. “North Korean Women as New Economic Agents: Drivers and Consequences.” Issue Brief, October 21, Institute for Security & Development Policy, Sweden.Google Scholar
Kong, Tat Yan. 2020. “The Advance of Marketization in North Korea: Between Political Rigidity and Economic Flexibility.” Modern Asian Studies 54 (3): 830867.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krastev, Ivan. 2016. “Why Putin Tolerates Corruption,” The New York Times, May 16, www.nytimes.com/2016/05/16/opinion/why-putin-tolerates-corruption.html.Google Scholar
Kroeber, Arthur R. 2016. China's Economy: What Everyone Needs to Know. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kŭlloja. 1955a. “Pant'amo Pallangbi T'ujaenggwa Tang Tanch'e” [The Anti-Corruption, Anti-Waste Struggle and Party Organizations], Kŭlloja 116 (7): 6574.Google Scholar
Kŭlloja. 1955b. “Pant'amo Pallangbi T'ujaengŭi Kailch'ŭngŭi Kanghwarŭl Wihayŏ” [To Raise One Level Higher the Anti-Corruption, Anti-Waste Struggle], Kŭlloja 118 (9): 310.Google Scholar
Kŭlloja. 1960. “Pan'gwallyojuŭi T'ujaengŭl Wihan Kangnyŏngjŏng Munhŏn” [Programmatic Literature for the Struggle Against Bureaucratism], Kŭlloja 178 (9): 3238.Google Scholar
Kwŏn, Jimin. 2020. Puk'anesŏ ‘Tonju’ŭi Sŏngjanggwa Chŏngch'ich'ejeihaeng Koch'al—Kŭndaehwa Ironŭl Chungshimŭro [A Study on the Growth of ‘Donju’ and Political System Implementation in North Korea—Focused on Modernization Theory]. Sahoegwahaktamnon'gwa Chŏngch'aek [Social Science Discourse and Policy] 32 (6): 89108.Google Scholar
Lam, Willy Wo-Lap. 2015. Chinese Politics in the Era of Xi Jinping: Renaissance, Reform, or Retrogression? New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lankov, Andrei. 2015. “Why North Korea is So Corrupt, and Why That May Be Good.” NKNews, October 16.Google Scholar
Lankov, Andrei. 2018. “NKNews interviews DPRK expert Andrei Lankov on his recent trip to Yanji and more.” NKNews Podcast episode 1, February 12.Google Scholar
Lankov, Andrei, Ward, Peter, Yoo, Ho-yeol, and Kim, Ji-young. 2017a. “Making Money in the State: North Korea's Pseudo-State Enterprises in the Early 2000s.” Journal of East Asian Studies 17 (1): 5167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lankov, Andrei, Ward, Peter, Yoo, Ho-yeol, and Kim, Ji-young. 2017b. “North Korea's New Capitalists and Their Workers: Business Practice and Labor Relations.” Communist and Post-Communist Studies 50 (3): 157167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Byeong-Cheon. 2006. Developmental Dictatorship and the Park Chung-Hee Era: The Shaping of Modernity in the Republic of Korea. Paramus: Homa & Sekey.Google Scholar
Lee, Chong-Sik, and Oh, Ki-Wan. 1968. “The Russian Faction in North Korea.” Asian Survey 8 (4): 270288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leys, Colin. 1965. “What is the Problem About Corruption?Journal of Modern African Studies 3 (2): 215–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2008. Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and Its Demise in Mexico, 1st edn. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Martin, Bradley K. 2004. Under the Loving Care of the Fatherly Leader: North Korea and the Kim Dynasty. New York: Thomas Dunne.Google Scholar
Natsios, Andrew. 1999. “The Politics of Famine in North Korea.” United States Institute of Peace, Special Report, August 2.Google Scholar
NK Chosun. 2013. “Chabaegundong” [Self-Confession Movement], NK Chosun, October 30, http://nk.chosun.com/bbs/list.html?table=bbs_23&idxno=3749&page=9&total=247&sc_area=&sc_word.Google Scholar
Noland, Marcus. 2004. “Famine and Reform in North Korea.” Asian Economic Papers 3 (2): 140.Google Scholar
Noland, Marcus. 2006. “Transition from the Bottom-up: Institutional Change in North Korea.” Comparative Economic Studies 48 (2): 195212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North Korea Leadership Watch. 2018. “Choe Ryong Hae to OGD?” North Korea Leadership Watch, January 11. www.nkleadershipwatch.org/2018/01/11/choe-ryong-hae-to-ogd/.Google Scholar
North Korea Overview. 1968. Puk'anch'onggam, 1945–’68. Seoul: Kongsan'gwŏnmunjeyŏn'guso.Google Scholar
Nye, Joseph S. 1967. “Corruption and Political Development: A Cost-Benefit Analysis.” American Political Science Review 61 (2): 417427.Google Scholar
OHCHR. 2019. “The Price is Rights: The Violation of the Right to an Adequate Standard of Living in the Democratic People's Republic of Korea.” United Nations Human Rights Office of the High Commissioner, May.Google Scholar
Pak, Hyŏngch'ung, Hyŏnchun, Chŏn, Yŏngcha, Pak, and Ch'ŏlki, Yun. 2012. “Puk'an Pup'ae Shilt'aewa Panbup'ae Chŏllyang: Kukchehyŏmnyŏgŭi Mosaeng” [The Real Situation of Corruption in and Anti-Corruption Strategies for North Korea: The Search for Economic Cooperation]. Seoul: T'ongiryŏn'guwŏn.Google Scholar
Park, John S. 2009. North Korea, Inc: Gaining Insights into North Korean Regime Stability from Recent Commercial Activities. United States Institute of Peace.Google Scholar
Park, Young-Ja. 2015. “Informal Political System in North Korea: Systematic Corruption of ‘Power-Wealth Symbiosis,’International Journal of Korean Unification Studies 24 (1):123156.Google Scholar
Park, Young-ja, Jeong-ah, Cho, Hwan, Hong Jea, Eunlee, Joung, Mee, Jeong Eun, Seogki, Lee, Youngsun, Jeon, and HoJye, Kang. 2018. “Eight Changes in North Korean Economy and Society under the Kim Jong Un Regime.” Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification.Google Scholar
Pei, Minxin. 2018. “How Not to Fight Corruption: Lessons from China.” Daedalus 147 (3): 216230.Google Scholar
Person, James F. 2019. “North Korea in 1956: Reconsidering the August Plenum and the Sino-Soviet Joint Intervention.” Cold War History 19 (2): 253274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodong Sinmun. 2018. “Uri tangi paranŭn ch'amdoen ilgun” [Our Party's Ideal True Workers]. Rodong Sinmun, December 20.Google Scholar
Ryu, Il. 1967. “‘Ton taet'ongnyŏng’ : pujŏng pup'ae ro pidae haejin ‘Samsŏng chaebŏl’” [‘Money President’: Samsung Chaebol [sic] Is Bloated With Corruption]. Ch'ollima 1: 126129.Google Scholar
Schmid, Andre. 2018. “Historicizing North Korea: State Socialism, Population Mobility, and Cold War Historiography.” The American Historical Review 123 (2): 439462.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shen, Zhihua, and Xia, Yafeng. 2012. “China and the Post-War Reconstruction of North Korea, 1953–1961.” North Korea International Documentation Project Working Paper 4.Google Scholar
Shen, Zhihua, and Xia, Yafeng. 2018. A Misunderstood Friendship: Mao Zedong, Kim Il-sung, and Sino–North Korean Relations, 1949–1976. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Silberstein, Benjamin. 2010. “North Korea: Fading Totalitarianism in the ‘Hermit Kingdom.’North Korean Review 6 (2): 4054.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silberstein, Benjamin. 2019. “Understanding North Korea's Surveillance State.” NKNews Podcast episode 96, September 17. www.nknews.org/2019/09/understanding-north-koreas-surveillance-state-nknews-podcast-ep-96/?c=1570425626561.Google Scholar
Sin, Taewŏn. 2008. “Puk'an Pant'amo Pannangbi T'ujaengŭi Chŏn'gaewa Sŏnggyŏng” [The Evolution and Character of North Korea's ‘Anti-Corruption, Anti-Waste Struggle]. Han'guk'angnonjim [Collection of Korean Essays] 43.Google Scholar
Song, Wonjun and Wright, Joseph. 2018. “The North Korean Autocracy in Comparative Perspective.” Journal of East Asian Studies 18 (2): 157180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szalontai, Balazs. 2005. Kim Il Sung in the Khrushchev Era: Soviet-DPRK Relations and the Roots of North Korean Despotism, 1953–1964. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Teiwes, Frederick C. 1978. Elite Discipline in China: Coercive and Persuasive Approaches to Rectification, 1950–1953. Canberra: Contemporary China Centre, Research School of Pacific Studies, Australian National University.Google Scholar
Thomas, Hugh. 1971. Cuba: The Pursuit of Freedom. London: Eyre & Spottiswoode.Google Scholar
Treisman, Daniel. 2002. “Russia Renewed?” Foreign Affairs 81 (6) November/December.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
US National Archives and Records Administration. 1952. Foreign Records Seized, 1952, various boxes. Record Group 242: National Archives Collection Of Foreign Records Seized, 1675–1958.Google Scholar
Ward, Peter, Lankov, Andrei, and Kim, Jiyoung. 2019. “Capitalism from Below with North Korean Characteristics: The State, Capitalist Class Formation, and Foreign Investment in Comparative Perspective.” Asian Perspective 43 (3): 533555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ward, Peter, Lankov, Andrei, and Kim, Jiyoung. 2021. “Embedded and Autonomous Markets in North Korea's Fishing Industry: Resource Scarcity, Monitoring Costs, and Evolving Institutions.” Journal of East Asian Studies 21 (1): 5374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
WCDA. 1952a. “Report from the Embassy of the People's Republic of Poland in the Democratic People's Republic of Korea for the Period of 25 June to 25 July 1952.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, August 8. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/114935.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1952b. “Report from the Embassy of the People's Republic of Poland in the Democratic People's Republic of Korea for the Period of 20 November to 31 December 1952.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, December 31. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/114937.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1953. “Report No. 1 of the Embassy of the People's Republic of Poland in the Democratic People's Republic of Korea for the Period of 1 January 1953 to 28 February 1953,” Wilson Center Digital Archive, February 28. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/114943.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1955a. “Concerning the Self-Confession Movement in the DPRK.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, December 21. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/115704.pdf?v=646698a3ecb4f7227f6777274c29a523.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1955b. “Decision of the KWP CC December Plenum, 2–3 December 1955, ‘Concerning the Anti-Party, Factional Activity of Pak Il-U.’” Wilson Center Digital Archive, December 2. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/120180.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1955c. “Information on the Situation in the DPRK,” Wilson Center Digital Archive, April. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/114590.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1955d. “Journal of Soviet Ambassador to the DPRK V. I. Ivanov for 7 December 1955.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, December 7. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/120764.pdf?v=2f19cde85d7d50d42b142a573bca8021.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1955e. “Record of Conversation with Chairman of the Jagang Provincial People's Committee Illarion Dmitriyevich Pak.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, April 5. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/116309.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1955f. “Resolution of the 1st Meeting of the KWP CC Presidium of 1–2 February 1955,” Wilson Center Digital Archive, March 12. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/116304.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1956a. “Decision of the KWP CC Plenum, 30–31 August 1956, ‘The Results of the Work of the Government Delegation which Visited Fraternal Countries, and Some Pressing Tasks of Our Party.’” Wilson Center Digital Archive, September 15. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/121797.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1956b. “Diary of Ambassador of the USSR to the DPRK V.I. Ivanov for the Period from 29 August to 14 September 1956.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, September 1. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/114136.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1956c. “DPRK Ministry of Agriculture, ‘Model Charter of an Agricultural Cooperative, 3rd Form.’” Wilson Center Digital Archive, January 10. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/120807.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1956d. “Letter from Seo Hwi, Yun Gong-heum, Li Pil-gyu, and Kim Gwan to the Chinese Communist Party Central Committee.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, September 5. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/120173.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1956e. “Memorandum of Conversation with Kim Il Sung.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, April 19. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/111639.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1956f. “Minutes of the KWP CC Plenum Held on 23 September 1956.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, September 23. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/120162.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1956g. “Report from the USSR Ministry of Foreign Affairs to A. A. Okhotin, ‘Some Issues of the Domestic Political Situation in the DPRK.’” Wilson Center Digital Archive, April 14. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/120798.pdf?v=97d0808165c484881a4f0bd530bd11e8.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1957a. “Journal of Soviet Ambassador to the DPRK A.M. Puzanov for 9 April 1957.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, April 09. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/115599.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1957b. “Notes from a Conversation between the 1st Secretary of the PRL Embassy in the DPRK with Cheng Wenjin, 1st Secretary of the Embassy of the PRC,” Wilson Center Digital Archive, December 7. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/111729.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1957c. “Notes from a Conversation Between the 1st Secretary of the PRL Embassy in the DPRK with Comrade Pimenov, 1st Secretary of the Embassy of the USSR, on 15.X.1957.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, October 16. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/111722.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1958. “Note Concerning the August Group, Developed on the Basis of Party Documents, as well as on the Basis of Unofficial Sources of Information.” Wilson Center Digital Archive, May 6. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/114972.Google Scholar
WCDA. 1960. “The Economic and Political Situation of the DPRK,” Wilson Center Digital Archive, June 12. https://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/116389.Google Scholar
Xu, Dongwan. 2000. “6 • 25ka Puk'ansahoe • Ch'ejee Mich'in Yŏnghyang” [The Korean War's Influence on North Korea's Society and System]. Kwanhunjŏnŏl 41 (2): 252263.Google Scholar
Yadav, Vineeta, and Mukherjee, Bumba. 2016. The Politics of Corruption in Dictatorships. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Zwirko, Colin. 2021. “Kim Jong Un Hints at an Even Stronger Crusade against Political ‘Abuse Of Power.’” NKNews, January 12. www.nknews.org/2021/01/kim-jong-un-hints-at-an-even-stronger-crusade-against-political-abuse-of-power/.Google Scholar