Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wg55d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T20:10:16.375Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Moral Sentiments and the Minimum Wage

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

David H. Plowman
Affiliation:
The University of Western Australia Business School
Chris Perryer
Affiliation:
The University of Western Australia Business School

Abstract

Adam Smith is widely regarded as the father of political economics, and as one who provided the philosophical underpinnings of much of neoclassical economics. Since the mid-1970s there has been renewed interest in, and reinterpretation of, Smith’s work. This paper looks at two aspects of this reinterpretation, the first of which is Smith’s writing on wages. Smith was an advocate of high wages, a view that strongly contrasted with the received wisdom of the day. He considered that a wage which provided for a reasonable standard of living was essential for the development of an economy. The second aspect encompasses Smith’s notion of the subsistence wage which traces its historic lineage to the Greek philosophers. The paper concludes that Smith, the champion of ‘liberty’ and non-government interference in markets, would probably have supported the notion of minimum wages, such as are now mandated in the United Kingdom, the United States and Australia. Nevertheless, the mandating of minimum wages is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for the achievement of living wage outcomes.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

1.

The authors would like to thank the journal’s anonymous referees for helpful comments.

References

Becker, G. (1976) The Economic Approach to Human Behavior, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Billet, L. (1976) ‘The just economy: The moral basis of the wealth of nations’, Review of Social Economy 34(3), pp. 295315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bretano, L. (1894) Hours and Wages in Relation to Production, translated by Arnold, W., Swan Sonnenschein, London.Google Scholar
Brown, W. (2002) ‘The operations of the Low Pay Commission’, Employee Relations, 24(6), pp. 595605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burke, E. (1800) Thoughts and Details on Scarcity, F. and R. Rivington, London.Google Scholar
Buss, J. and Franceschi, D. (2003) ‘Employment trends in some American cities with living wage ordinances’, Local Economy 18(3), pp. 208221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, R. (1929) Evidence to the Royal Commission on Child Endowment or Family Allowances.Google Scholar
Clary, B. J. (2009) ‘Smith and living wages’, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 68(5), pp. 10631084.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commonwealth Arbitration Reports (CAR) various issues.Google Scholar
Danner, P. L. (1976) ‘Sympathy and exchange value: Keys to Adam Smith’s social philosophy’, Review of Social Economy, 34(3), pp. 317331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dempsey, B. W. (1965) ‘Just prices in a functioning economy’, in Gherity, J.A. (ed.) Economic Thought: Historical Anthology, Random House, New York, pp. 423.Google Scholar
Dengate, R. (2010) Adam Smith: Architect of a flawed system or ignored prophet, paper delivered at Oxford Round Table Conference, Harris Manchester College, Oxford University, March 21–26.Google Scholar
Evensky, J. (2005), Adam Smith’s Moral Philosophy: A Historical and Contemporary Perspectives on Markets, Law, Ethics and Culture, Cambridge University Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleischacker, S. (2004), On Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations, Princeton University Press, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Haakonssen, K. and Winch, D. (2006) ‘The legacy of Adam Smith’, in Haakonssen, K. (ed.) The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith, Cambridge University Press, New York, pp. 366394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heilbroner, R. L. (1986), The Essential Adam Smith, Norton and Company, New York.Google Scholar
ILO (1970) International Labour Organisation, Minimum Wage Fixing Convention, ILO, Geneva, ILO.Google Scholar
Irvine, W. B. (1990) ‘The other side of Adam Smith’, The Freeman, 40(2), available: http://www.thefreemanonline.org/columns/the-other-side-of-adam-smith/ [accessed 20 November 2010].Google Scholar
Isaac, J. and Macintyre, S. (2004) ‘Introduction’ in Isaac, J. and Macintyre, S. (eds) The New Province for Law and Order: 100 years of Australian Industrial Conciliation and Arbitration, Cambridge University Press, Melbourne, pp. 117.Google Scholar
Levin-Waldman, O. M. (2000) ‘Minimum wage and justice?’, Review of Social Economy, 53(1), pp. 4361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin-Waldman, (2004), The Case of the Minimum Wage: Competing Models, State University of New York Press, New York.Google Scholar
Mandeville, B. (1924) ‘An essay on charity and the charity-schools’, The Fable of the Bees or Private Vices, Publick Benefits, Vol 1. 1732, reprinted with a Commentary Critical, Historical, and Explanatory by E B. Kaye, Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
May, R. (2005) ‘The British Low Pay Commission and the proposed Australian Fair Pay Commission’, Journal of Political Economy, 56, pp. 92104.Google Scholar
Mehta, P. B. (2006) ‘Self-interest and other interests’, in Haakonssen, K. (ed.) The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith, Cambridge University Press, New York, pp. 246269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, J. A. (2009) ‘Leaving the sphere of exchange with David Houston, Karl Marx, and even Adam Smith: Insights into the debate about sweatshops’, Review of Radical Political Economics, 41(3), pp. 358364.Google Scholar
Morrow, G. (1973)[1923] The Ethical and Economic Theories of Adam Smith Augustus M. Kelley, Clifton NJ.Google Scholar
Noel, E. S. (2006) ‘Smith and a living wage: Competition, economic compulsion, and the scholastic legacy’, History of Political Economy, 38(1), pp. 151174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plowman, D. H. (1995) ‘Protecting the low income earner: Minimum wage determination in Australia’, The Economic and Labour Relations Review, 6(2), pp. 252287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rimlinger, G. V. (1976) ‘Smith and the merits of the poor’, Review of Social Economy, 34(3), pp. 333344.Google Scholar
Rothschild, E. (2001), Adam Smith, Condorcet, and the Enlightenment, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1995) ‘Moral codes and economic success’, in Market Capitalism and Moral Codes: Proceedings of Section F (Economics) of the British Association for the Advancement of Sciences, Edward Elgar, Hants, UK, pp. 2334.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1759), The Theory of Moral Sentiment, Millar, London.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776/1904) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Methuen, London.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1976), Lectures on Jurisprudence, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Stabile, D. R. (1997) ‘Adam Smith and the natural wage: Sympathy, subsistence and social distance’, Review of Social Economy, 55(3), pp. 292311.Google Scholar
Stabile, D. R. (2008), The Living Wage: Lessons From the History of Economic Thought, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham UK.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, H. (1994) ‘Remembering Adam Smith’, The Wall Street Journal, April 6, p. A14.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. (1975) ‘Smith’s travels on the ship of state’, in Skinner, A. and Wilson, T. (eds) Essays on Adam Smith, Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp. 237246.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. (1976) ‘The successes and failures of Professor Smith’, Journal of Political Economy, 84(6), pp. 11991213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Webb, B. (1886) Diary July 30, Passfield Mss. London School of Economics, London.Google Scholar
Webb, S. and Webb, B. (1902), The History of Trade Unionism, Longman Green and Co., London.Google Scholar
Wight, J. B. (2006) ‘Adam Smith’s ethics and the “noble arts,’” Review of Social Economy, 64(2), pp. 155179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, J. T. (1986) ‘The impartial spectator and natural jurisprudence: An interpretation of Adam Smith’s theory of the natural price’, History of Political Economy, 12(6–7), pp. 118133.Google Scholar