Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-v5vhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-23T06:17:59.614Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Learning from full employment history: The 1945 Australian White Paper in practice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

John Nevile*
Affiliation:
The University of New South Wales, Australia
*
John Nevile, School of Economics, UNSW Business School, The University of New South Wales, Sydney, NSW 2052, Australia. Email: j.nevile@unsw.edu.au

Abstract

The part played by unemployment in the rise to power of Hitler weighed on the minds of leaders in Western democracies. There was a determination to create a world in which large-scale unemployment was abnormal and at worst only a temporary phenomenon. The war had shown that this was possible in a community united to pursue a common goal and the aim was to create such a community in a world free from the horrors of war, by creating communities in which the welfare of every person was important. Australia was remarkably successful in achieving this for 30 years. Its success depended on governments responding to any sustained increase in unemployment by undertaking large increases in public sector expenditure supported by accommodating monetary policy and tax cuts if desirable. In bad times as well as good, there was a determination to ensure that both the incomes and prices paid for necessities by the less well-off did not force anyone to live in poverty. The biggest obstacle to achieving this today is the growth of neoliberalism with its emphasis on ‘freedom’ or giving individuals the ability to act as they please with minimal constraints and an ideological commitment to small government.

Type
Symposium: The White Paper and Full Employment
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arndt, HW, Corden, WM (eds) (1963) The Australian Economy: A Volume of Readings. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: F.W. Cheshire.Google Scholar
Aschauer, DA (1989) Is public expenditure productive? Journal of Monetary Economics 23(2): 177200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coombs, HC (1971) Other People’s Money. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian National University Press.Google Scholar
Coombs, HC (1981) Trial Balance. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Coombs, HC (1994) From Curtin to Keating. Darwin, NT, Australia: Australian National University North Australia Research Unit.Google Scholar
Domar, ED (1944) The ‘burden of the debt’ and the national income. American Economic Review 34(4): 798827.Google Scholar
Harcourt, GC (2001) Investment expenditure, unrealised expectations and offsetting monetary policies. In: Harcourt, G (ed.) 50 Years a Keynesian and Other Essays. New York: Palgrave, pp. 197205. (Reprinted from Bellofiore R and Ferri P (eds) (2000) Financial Fragility and Investment in the Capitalist Economy: The Economic Legacy of Hyman Minsky. Cheltenham; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.)Google Scholar
Harvey, P (2006) Funding a job guarantee. International Journal of Environment, Workplace and Employment 2(1): 114132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, JM (1973 [1936]) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, vol. 7. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kriesler, P (ed) (1995) The Australian Economy: The Essential Guide. St Leonards, NSW, Australia: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Kriesler, P, Nevile, JW (2009) A history of aggregate demand policy in Australia and lessons for Australia today. In: Wrightson, G (ed.) Labour Underutilisation, Unemployment and Underemployment Proceedings: Refereed Papers. Callaghan, NSW, Australia: University of Newcastle, pp. 158168.Google Scholar
Martin, E (2003) Social work, the family and women’s equality in post-war Australia. Women’s History Review 12(3): 445468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minsky, HP (1985) The financial instability hypothesis: A restatement. In: Arestis, P, Skouras, T (eds) Post-Keynesian Economic Theory: A Challenge to Neoclassical Economics. Brighton, UK: Wheatsheaf, pp. 2455.Google Scholar
Nevile, JW (2002) Policies to minimise the costs of unemployment. In: Saunders, P, Taylor, R (eds) The Price of Prosperity: The Economic and Social Costs of Unemployment. Sydney, NSW, Australia: University of New South Wales Press, pp. 249271.Google Scholar
Nevile, JW, Kriesler, P (2002) Tools of choice for fighting recessions. In: Carlson, E, Mitchell, W (eds) The Urgency of Full Employment: Centre of Applied Economic Research. Sydney, NSW, Australia: University of New South Wales, pp. 7394.Google Scholar
O’Donnell, A (2015) Unemployment in a time of full employment: Counting and regulating worklessness in mid-twentieth century Australia. Labour History 108: 7188.Google Scholar
Sen, A (2011) Power of financial institutions is urgent threat to democracy. The Age, 24 June. Available at: https://www.theage.com.au/politics/federal/power-of-financial-institutions-is-urgent-threat-to-democracy-20110623-1ghcn.html (accessed 10 August 2018).Google Scholar
Solow, RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1): 6594.Google Scholar
Solow, RM (2000) The neoclassical theory of growth and distribution. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review 53(215): 349381.Google Scholar
Swan, T (1956) Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record 32(2): 334361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar