Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-20T05:07:40.986Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

No Families, No Freedom: Human Flourishing in a Free Society

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 January 2009

Jennifer Roback Morse
Affiliation:
Economics, Hoover Institution on War, Revolution, and Peace, Stanford University

Extract

This essay has one simple theme: the family does a very important job that no other institution can do. What is that job? Inside a family, helpless babies are transformed from being self-centered bundles of impulses, desires, and emotions to being adult people capable of social behavior of all kinds. Why is this job important? The family teaches the ability to trust, cooperate, and self-restrain. Neither the free market nor selfgoverning political institutions can survive unless the vast majority of the population possesses these skills. Why is the family uniquely situated to teach these skills and the values that go with them? People develop these qualities in their children as a side effect of loving them. What does this have to do with a free society? Contracts and free political institutions, the foundational structures of a free society, require these attributes that only families can inculcate. Without loving families, no society can long govern itself, for the family teaches the skills of individual self-governance.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Social Philosophy and Policy Foundation 1999

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See, e.g., Self-interest, ed. Paul, Ellen Frankel, Miller, Fred D. Jr., and Paul, Jeffrey (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997).Google Scholar

2 This syndrome is known as the Kaspar Hauser syndrome, or psychosocial dwarfism. See Comprehensive Textbook of Psychiatry/VI, vol. 2, 6th ed., ed. Kaplan, Harold I., M.D., and Sadock, Benjamin J., M.D. (Baltimore: Williams and Wilkins, 1995), ch. 40 and sections 43.3 and 47.3.Google Scholar

3 See Karen, Robert, Becoming Attached: First Relationships and How They Shape Our Capacity to Love (New York: Oxford University Press, 1998)Google Scholar, ch. 1, “Mother Love: Worst Case Scenarios,” pp. 1325Google Scholar, and the references cited therein.

4 See Comprehensive Textbook of Psychiatry/VI, vol. 2, section 43.3Google Scholar, “Reactive Attachment Disorder of Infancy or Early Childhood.” See also Foster Cline, Understanding and Treating the Severely Disturbed Child (Evergreen, CO: Evergreen Consultants, 1979), for an analysis of the most severely disturbed of attachment-disordered children. The classic works on the attachment process in the normal mother/child relationship are: Bowlby, John, Attachment and Loss, Volume 1: Attachment (New York: Basic Books, 1969)Google Scholar; and Ainsworth, Mary, Blehar, Mary, Waters, Everett, and Wall, Sally, Patterns of Attachment A Psychological Study of the Strange Situation (New Jersey: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, 1978).Google Scholar

5 The terminology of “trust bandit” is due to Magid, Ken and McKelvey, Carole, High Risk: Children without a Conscience (New York: Bantam Books, 1987).Google Scholar

6 See the title essay in Sacks, Oliver, An Anthropologist on Mars: Seven Paradoxical Tales (New York: Alfred Knopf, 1995), pp. 244–96Google Scholar, for a sensitive treatment of the world of the high-functioning autistic person.

7 Margaret Brinig has done the most systematic work on the differences in time preferences among men, women, and children, as well as on the development of the length of time preferences. See Brinig, , “Why Can't a Woman Be More Like a Man? Or, Do Gender Differences Affect Choice?” in Neither Victim nor Enemy, ed. Simon, Rita (Lanham, MD: University Press of America, 1995)Google Scholar; and Brinig, , “Does Mediation Systemarically Disadvantage Women?William and Mary Law Reviews, vol. 2 (1995), p. 1.Google Scholar

8 Kagel, John H., Battalio, Raymond, Rachlin, Howard, and Green, Leonard, “Demand Curves for Animal Consumers,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 96 (1981), pp. 116CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Battalio, Raymond, Kagel, John H., and McDonald, Don N., “Animals' Choices over Uncertain Outcomes: Some Initial Experimental Results,” American Economic Review, vol. 75 (1985), pp. 597613.Google Scholar

9 For a discussion of why it might be that animals do not trade, see Levy, David, The Economic Ideas of Ordinary People (London: Routledge, 1992), pp. 1733.Google Scholar

10 See Collins, Randall, Weberian Sociological Theory (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), pp. 5253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar Collins uses the religious orders as examples of Max Weber's theories of the rise of capitalism. For an appreciation of just how far-ranging the activities of the military religious orders really were, see The Atlas of the Crusades, ed. Riley-Smith, Jonathan (New York: Facts on File, 1991)Google Scholar, especially the maps on pp. 53, 90–91, and 98, as well as the text on pp. 100 and 124. For the importance of the trading families and small corporations, see Cameron, Rondo, A Concise Economic History of the World: From Paleolithic Times to the Present, 2d ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993), pp. 6668.Google Scholar See Historical Atlas of the World (Chicago: Rand-McNally, 1981), map 35, p. 71Google Scholar, for an appreciation of the extent of the banking activities of the Medici and Fugger families, as well as the league of Hanseatic towns.

11 See Kreuger, Anne, “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society,” American Economic Review, vol. 64 (1974), pp. 291303.Google Scholar For a survey of recent work on rent-seeking, see Tollison, Robert, “Rent-Seeking: A Survey,” Kyklos, vol. 35 (1982), pp. 575602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 See, for instance, my “The Modern State as an Occasion of Sin: A Public Choice Interpretation of the Welfare State,” Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics, and Public Policy, vol. 11 (1997), pp. 531–48.Google Scholar

13 Marvin Olasky makes substantially the same point with regard to state-sponsored poverty programs. For one of his more provocative statements of this point, see Olasky, , “Persons, Not Pets,” Crisis, vol. 13, no. 11 (12 1995), p. 6.Google Scholar He describes “bad” homeless shelters as ones in which the clients are, in effect, told, “Here's some food in your bowl, here's a place to sleep, that's a good boy.”

14 McKenzie, Richard, The Home: A Memoir of Growing Up in an Orphanage (New York: Basic Books, 1996).Google Scholar Other prominent figures who have spoken publicly about how much they owe to orphanages include Tom Monaghan, Founder and CEO of Domino's Pizza, and Jude Dougherty, Chairman of the Philosophy Department at Catholic University of America. See Monaghan, Thomas S., “Why I Am Still a Catholic,” Crisis, vol. 15, no. 8 (09 1997), pp. 2226Google Scholar; and Fagan, Patrick, “The Child Abuse Crisis: The Disintegration of Marriage, Family, and the American Community,” Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1115 (Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation, 06 3, 1997).Google Scholar