Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T11:23:50.826Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Health risk and the welfare effects of Social Security

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 October 2022

Shantanu Bagchi*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Towson University, Towson, MD, USA
Juergen Jung
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Towson University, Towson, MD, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: sbagchi@towson.edu

Abstract

We quantify the importance of idiosyncratic health risk in a calibrated general equilibrium model of Social Security. We construct an overlapping generations model with rational-expectations households, idiosyncratic labor income and health risk, profit-maximizing firms, incomplete insurance markets, and a government that provides pensions and health insurance. We calibrate this model to the US economy and perform two computational experiments: $\left (i\right)$ cutting Social Security’s payroll tax, and $\left (ii\right)$ modifying Social Security’s benefit-earnings rule. Our findings suggest that health risk amplifies the welfare implications of both experiments: downsizing Social Security always leads to higher overall welfare, but the welfare gain is larger when we account for health risk, and increasing the progressivity of Social Security’s benefit-earnings rule has a larger positive effect on welfare in the presence of health risk. We also find that allowing households additional tools to self-insure against health risk weakens the precautionary motive, so our experiments have similar welfare implications both with and without health risk.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We thank Matt Chambers, Svetlana Pashchenko, Ponpoje Porapakkarm, Kai Zhao, participants of the CBE D&R Conference at Towson University in 2019, participants of the Midwest Macro Meetings 2019, and participants of the IIPF Annual Congress 2019.

References

Abel, A. B. (1985) Precautionary saving and accidental bequests. The American Economic Review 75(4), 777791.Google Scholar
Aizer, A. (2003) Low take-up in medicaid: Does outreach matter and for whom? The American Economic Review 93(2), 238241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alonso-Ortiz, J. (2014) Social security and retirement across the OECD. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 47(0), 300316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1989) Giving with impure altruism: Applications to charity and ricardian equivalence. Journal of Political Economy 97(6), 14471458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auerbach, J. A. and Kotlikoff, L. J.. (1987) Dynamic Fiscal Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bagchi, S. (2015) Labor supply and the optimality of social security. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 58(4), 167185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagchi, S. (2019) Differential mortality and the progressivity of social security. Journal of Public Economics 177(14), 104044.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bakıs, O., Kaymak, B. and Poschke, M.. (2015) Transitional dynamics and the optimal progressivity of income redistribution. Review of Economic Dynamics 18(3), 679693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, F. C. and Miller, M. L.. (2005) Life Tables for the United States Social Security Area 1900-2100, Actuarial Study No. 116, Office of the Chief Actuary, Social Security Administration.Google Scholar
Benabou, R. (2002) Tax and education policy in a heterogeneous agent economy: What levels of redistribution maximize growth and efficiency? Econometrica 70(2), 481517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernard, D., Cowan, C., Selden, T., Cai, L., Catling, A. and Heffler, S.. (2012) Reconciling medical expenditure estimates from the MEPS and NHEA, 2007. Medicare & Medicaid Research Review 2(4), 119.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blundell, R., Britton, J., Dias, M. C. and French, E.. (2021) The impact of health on labour supply near retirement. Journal of Human Resources, 12179240R4.Google Scholar
Braun, R. A., Kopecky, K. A. and Koreshkova, T.. (2017) Old, sick, alone and poor: A welfare analysis of old-age social insurance programs. Review of Economic Studies 84, 580612.Google Scholar
Capatina, E. (2015) Life-cycle effects of health risk. Journal of Monetary Economics 74, 6788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casanova, M. (2013) Revisiting the Hump-Shaped Wage Profile 2013, mimeo.Google Scholar
Claxton, G., DiJulio, B., Finder, B., Lundy, J., McHugh, M., Osei-Anto, A., Whitmore, H., Pickreign, J. and Gabel, J.. (2010) Employer Health Benefits: 2010 Annual Survey, Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research and Educational Trust.Google Scholar
Conesa, J. C. and Krueger, D.. (1999) Social security reform with heterogeneous agents. Review of Economic Dynamics 2(4), 757795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conesa, J. C. and Krueger, D.. (2006) On the optimal progressivity of the income tax code. Journal of Monetary Economics 53(7), 14251450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conesa, J. C. and Garriga, C.. (2009) Optimal response to a transitory demographic shock in social security financing. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 91(1), 3348.Google Scholar
De Nardi, M. (2004) Wealth inequality and intergenerational links. Review of Economic Studies 71(3), 743768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyrda, S. and Pedroni, M.. (2022) Optimal fiscal policy in a model with uninsurable idiosyncratic shocks. The Review of Economic Studies forthcoming 109, 659.Google Scholar
Elminejad, A., Havránek, T. and Horváth, R.. (2021) Publication and Identification Biases in Measuring the Intertemporal Substitution of Labor Supply, CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP16032, ZSCC: NoCitationData[s0].CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorito, R. and Zanella, G.. (2012) The anatomy of the aggregate labor supply elasticity. Review of Economic Dynamics 15(2), 171187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
French, E. (2005) The effects of health, wealth, and wages on labour supply and retirement behaviour. The Review of Economic Studies 72(2), 395427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
French, E. and Jones, J. B.. (2017) Health, health insurance, and retirement: A survey. Annual Review of Economics 19(1), 383409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glomm, G. and Jung, J.. (2013) The timing of redistribution. Southern Economic Journal 80(1), 5080.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golosov, M., Shourideh, A., Troshkin, M. and Tsyvinski, A.. (2013) Optimal pension systems with simple instruments. American Economic Review 103(3), 502507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gomme, P., Ravikumar, B. and Rupert, P.. (2011) The return to capital and the business cycle. Review of Economic Dynamics 14(2), 262278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guner, N., Lopez-Daneri, M. and Ventura, G.. (2016) Heterogeneity and government revenues: Higher taxes at the top? Journal of Monetary Economics 80(3), 6985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guner, N., Kaygusuz, R. and Ventura, G.. (2014) Income taxation of U.S. households: Facts and parametric estimates. Review of Economic Dynamics 17(4), 559581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Havránek, T. (2015) Measuring intertemporal substitution: The importance of method choices and selective reporting. Journal of the European Economic Association 13(6), 11801204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Havránek, T., Horváth, R., Irsova, Z. and Rusnak, M.. (2015) Cross-country heterogeneity in intertemporal substitution. Journal of International Economics 96(1), 100118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heathcote, J., Storesletten, K. and Violante, G. L.. (2017) Optimal tax progressivity: An analytical framework. Quarterly Journal of Economics 132(4), 16931754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heer, B. and Rohrbacher, S.. (2021) Endogenous longevity and optimal tax progressivity. Journal of Health Economics 79(8), 102515.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Holter, H. A. (2015) Accounting for cross-country differences in intergenerational earnings persistence: The impact of taxation and public education expenditure. Quantitative Economics 6(2), 385428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holter, H. A., Krueger, D. and Stepanchuk, S.. (2019) How do tax progressivity and household heterogeneity affect laffer curves? Quantitative Economics 10(4), 13171356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosseini, R., Kopecky, K. and Zhao, K.. (2021) How important is health inequality for lifetime earnings inequality?, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Hubbard, R. G. and Judd, K. L.. (1987) Social security and individual welfare: Precautionary saving, borrowing constraints, and the payroll tax. The American Economic Review 77(4), 630646.Google Scholar
Huggett, M. and Ventura, G.. (1999) On the distributional effects of social security reform. Review of Economic Dynamics 2(3), 498531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
İmrohoroğlu, S. and Kitao, S.. (2012) Social security reforms: Benefit claiming, labor force participation, and long-run sustainability. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4(3), 96127.Google Scholar
İmrohoroğlu, A., İmrohoroğlu, S. and Joines, D. H.. (1995) A life cycle analysis of social security. Economic Theory 6(1), 83114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
İmrohoroğlu, A., İmrohoroğlu, S. and Joines, D. H.. (2003) Time-inconsistent preferences and social security. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(2), 745784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IRS. (2010) Medical and Dental Expenses (including the Health Coverage Tax Credit), Department of the Treasury, Internal REvenue Service, Publication 502, Cat. No. 15002QGoogle Scholar
Jeske, K. (2003) Pension systems and aggregate shocks. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review Q1, 1531.Google Scholar
Jeske, K. and Kitao, S.. (2009) U.S. tax policy and health insurance demand: Can a regressive policy improve welfare? Journal of Monetary Economics 56(2), 210221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, J. B. and Li, Y.. (2018) The effects of collecting income taxes on social security benefits. Journal of Public Economics 159, 128145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, J. B. and Li, Y.. (2020) Social Security Reform with Heterogeneous Mortality, Working Paper 20-09, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,Google Scholar
Jung, J. and Tran, C.. (2014) Medical consumption over the life cycle: Facts from a U.S. Medical Expenditure Panel Survey. Empirical Economics 47(3), 927957.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jung, J. and Tran, C.. (2016) Market inefficiency, insurance mandate and welfare: U.S. health care reform 2010. Review of Economic Dynamics 20, 132159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jung, J. and Tran, C.. (2022) Health Risk, Insurance and Optimal Progressive Income Taxation, Towson University, Department of Economics, Working Paper No. 2017-01 Google Scholar
Kaiser. (2013) Where Are States Today? Medicaid and CHIP Eligibility Levels for Children and Non-Disabled Adults, Kaiser Family Foundation Fact Sheet.Google Scholar
Kaplan, G. (2012) Inequality and the life cycle. Quantitative Economics 3(3), 471525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kitao, S. (2014) A life-cycle model of unemployment and disability insurance. Journal of Monetary Economics 68, 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, D. and Ludwig, A.. (2016) On the optimal provision of social insurance: Progressive taxation versus education subsidies in general equilibrum. Journal of Monetary Economics 77, 7298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Low, H. and Pistaferri, L.. (2015) Disability insurance and the dynamics of the incentive-insurance tradeoff. American Economic Review 105(10), 29863029.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
NHEA. (2020a) National health expenditures by type of service and source of funds, CY 1960-2020 (ZIP-File). National Health Expenditure Accounts, Website:, https://www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/NationalHealthExpendData/NationalHealthAccountsHistorical Google Scholar
NHEA. (2020b) NHE summary, including share of GDP, CY 1960-2020 (ZIP). National Health Expenditure Accounts, Website:, https://www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/NationalHealthExpendData/NationalHealthAccountsHistorical Google Scholar
Nishiyama, S. and Smetters, K.. (2008) The Optimal Design of Social Security Benefits, Michigan Retirement Research Center Research Paper No. 2008-197 Google Scholar
Pashchenko, S. and Porapakkarm, P.. (2013) Quantitative analysis of health insurance reform: Separating regulation from redistribution. Review of Economic Dynamics 16(3), 383404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterman, W. B. (2016) Reconciling micro and macro estimates of the Frisch labor supply elasticity: A sensitivity analysis. Economic Inquiry 54(1), 100120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Remler, D. K., Rachling, J. E. and Glied, S. A.. (2001) What can the take-up of other programs teach us about how to improve take-up of health insurance programs?, NBER Working Paper 8185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rupert, P. and Zanella, G.. (2015) Revisiting wage, earnings, and hours profiles. Journal of Monetary Economics 72(April (2)), 114130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sing, M., Jessica, B., Selden, T., Cowan, C. and Keehan, S.. (2006) Reconciling medical expenditure estimates from the MEPS and NHEA, 2002. Health Care Financing Review 28(1), 2540.Google ScholarPubMed
Smetters, K. (2003) Is the social security trust fund worth anything? Working Paper 9845, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
SSA. (2007) Social Security Update 2007. SSA Publication No. 05-10003.Google Scholar
SSA. (2010) The 2010 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust Funds, Social Security Administration.Google Scholar
Suen, R. M. H. (2006) Technological Advance and the Growth in Health Care Spending, Economie D’Avant Garde, Research Report No. 13, University of Rochester.Google Scholar
Swanson, E. T. (2012) Risk aversion and the labor margin in dynamic equilibrium models. The American Economic Review 102(4), 16631691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tauchen, G. and Hussey, R.. (1991) Quadrature-based methods for obtaining approximate solutions to nonlinear asset pricing models. Econometrica 59(2), 371396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallenius, J. (2013) Social security and cross-country differences in hours: A general equilibrium analysis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(12), 24662482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whalen, C. and Reichling, F.. (2017) Estimates of the frisch elasticity of labor supply: A review. Eastern Economic Journal 43(1), 3742.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wooldridge, J. M. (1995) Selection corrections for panel data models under conditional mean independence assumptions. Journal of Econometrics 68(1), 115132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhao, K. (2014) Social security and the rise in health spending. Journal of Monetary Economics 64(2), 2137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Bagchi and Jung supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Bagchi and Jung supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1 MB