Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-2xdlg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-06T14:22:26.816Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Estimating sentiment and risk in a consumption model: a factor analysis approach

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 February 2023

Mohammed Bouaddi
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, The American University in Cairo, New Cairo, Egypt
Johnson Kakeu*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Prince Edward Island, Charlottetown, PE C1A4P3, Canada
*
*Corresponding author. Email: j.kakeu@upei.ca
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This empirical paper deals with the impacts of sentiment about the future, short-run risk, and long-run risk in a dynamic economic model of optimal consumption decisions with Schroder and Skiadas [(1999) Journal of Economic Theory 89, 68–126.] continuous-time stochastic recursive preferences. The empirical strategy combines both a latent factor method and a democratic orthogonalization technique. The latent factor method is applied to a large database of macroeconomic indicators, and a democratic orthogonalization technique is used to separate the relative importance of sentiment about the future and long-run risk channels in shaping optimal consumption decisions. The empirical results suggest that consumers with recursive preferences are not indifferent to long-run uncertainty shocks to future consumption prospects. Endogenous consumption variations are driven by a multicomponent mechanism, where on average, the sentiment component accounts for 15.33%, the short-run risk accounts for 16.89%, and the long-run risk pertains to 34.51%.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

Sentiment and attitudes towards long-run uncertainty constitute an important dashboard for gauging by how much consumers feel optimistic or pessimistic about future economic prospects. Over the past decades, much interest has been aroused in understanding the role played by sentiment about the future in shaping the dynamics of economic decisions (Driscoll and Holden (Reference Driscoll and Holden2014); Milani (Reference Milani2017); Salamaliki and Venetis (Reference Salamaliki and Venetis2019); Pan (Reference Pan2020)). Among the popular measures of sentiment about future economic prospects, the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers and the Conference Board’s Consumer Confidence Index are closely watched by news media and decision-makers.Footnote 1 They are leading indicators of future developments of households’ consumption (Bram and Ludvigson (Reference Bram and Ludvigson1998); Dominitz and Manski (Reference Dominitz and Manski2004); Ludvigson (Reference Ludvigson2004); Curtin (Reference Curtin2007)), based upon answers regarding their sentiment about the general economic situation, unemployment, and capability of savings. Early preoccupation about the role played by expectations about future prospects in dynamic economic analysis goes back at least to Pigou (Reference Pigou1927), and it continues to spark the interest of market participants, business managers, and policy makers (Barro (Reference Barro1994); Biolsi and Du (Reference Biolsi and Du2020); Benhabib and Spiegel (Reference Benhabib and Spiegel2018)). Despite the important progress made in the empirical literature assessing the link between consumer’s sentiment about the future and consumption expenditures (Dominitz and Manski (Reference Dominitz and Manski2004); Ludvigson (Reference Ludvigson2004)), an approach that builds on a formal structural economic growth model and combines both sentiment and long-run risks remains under-explored. Bram and Ludvigson (Reference Bram and Ludvigson1998) and Ludvigson (Reference Ludvigson2004) rightfully note that there is a need for empirical studies grounded in a theoretical economic model that explicitly incorporates sentiment as a driving factor of consumer decisions. While a great deal of effort has been devoted to surveying consumers’ sentiment about the future, explicitly linking empirical research and theoretical economic models related to consumers’ optimizing behavior, again, remains largely uncharted. One possible explanation for the gap is that the previous empirical works on the relationship between consumption and sentiments about the future did not fully incorporate insights from an optimal consumption model with recursive utility. In fact, only recently have stochastic dynamic models that include sentiment about the future among the explanatory factors of consumer behavior appeared in the optimal growth-related literature. For example, the paper compiled by Kakeu and Byron (Reference Kakeu and Byron2016) is among the few papers that explicitly point to the role of sentiment about the future as a factor affecting optimal consumption choices in a dynamic stochastic model of optimal consumption with recursive utility.Footnote 2 The work of these authors features several factors that dynamically impact optimal consumption choices over time, including sentiment about the future, as well as short-run and long-run risks. Previous empirical inquiries have not explicitly incorporated these insights in their econometric specification. Building on the theoretical optimal consumption model by Kakeu and Byron (Reference Kakeu and Byron2016), our work complements the previous empirical literature by explicitly incorporating sentiment about the future as well as various risk factors in the analysis.

The forward-looking feature of recursive utility allows a potential role for sentiment to matter endogenously in the consumer’s decision (Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2005); Sargent (Reference Sargent2007); Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012)).Footnote 3 Sentiment about the future refers to changes in future expectations (Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012); Kakeu and Byron (Reference Kakeu and Byron2016)). A positive sentiment about the future reflects an increase in expectations about future prospects whereas a negative sentiment reflects a decrease in expectations about future prospects. The paper by Kakeu and Byron (Reference Kakeu and Byron2016) shows that the optimal consumption path is shaped in a nontrivial way by factors such as changes in expectations about future prospects (sentiment), short-run risks, and long-run risks. The rich framework offered by recursive preferences provides greater flexibility for understanding plausible channels by which long-term uncertainty matters in current decision-making (Kreps and Porteus (Reference Kreps and Porteus1978); Duffie and Epstein (Reference Duffie and Epstein1992); Sargent (Reference Sargent2007); Skiadas (Reference Skiadas2007); Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012)). The implications of assuming a preference for the temporal resolution of uncertainty have proven useful for explaining several puzzles in the macro-finance literature.Footnote 4 Recursive utility allows for adopting a flexible approach to capturing how agents behave regarding the temporal resolution of uncertainty alongside the concomitant implications for the attitudes toward long-run risks (Kreps and Porteus (Reference Kreps and Porteus1978); Sargent (Reference Sargent2007); Hansen et al. (Reference Hansen, Heaton and Li2008); Kaltenbrunner and Lochstoer (Reference Kaltenbrunner and Lochstoer2010); Ericson and Fuster (Reference Ericson and Fuster2011); Swanson (Reference Swanson2012); Strzalecki (Reference Strzalecki2013); Epstein et al. (Reference Epstein, Farhi and Strzalecki2014)).

To estimate the dynamic structural model, we use consumption and total productivity data available at the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank, data on capital stocks from the Penn World Table, and sentiment data from the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers. The University of Michigan’s Survey focuses on consumer’s prospects for their own financial situation, their prospects about the economy over the near term, and their prospects about the economy over the long term.

From an empirical point of view, our analysis combines both the latent factor method and the democratic orthogonalization method in empirically exploring an economic growth model that delivers sentiment and risk as drivers of the consumption path. Consumption variations are decomposed into sentiment factors and risk factors by using the democratic orthogonalization method developed by (Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970). The democratic decomposition method developed by Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970) is a statistical method that allows to transform a matrix of correlated variables into an information-equivalent matrix of variables that are noncorrelated.Footnote 5 The democratic decomposition allows to isolate the specific contribution of each component of the matrix of variables, important in light of common variation, permitting a clear interpretation of the role of each individual variable. Using this procedure allows us to compute the relative individual contribution of sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk to changes in the expected consumption growth. The results provide empirical evidence that sentiment about the future, short-run risk, and long-run risk are factors that matter for understanding the optimal consumption path. The sentiment factor accounts for 13.8% of variations in consumption while macroeconomic risk factors account for 50.86%, of which 15.8% pertains to the short-run risk and 35% pertains to the long-run risk.

Our paper makes at least three contributions to the literature. First, previous studies have used an estimation procedure that imposes a linear relationship between consumption and sentiment without reference to dynamic preference structures. From a methodological point of view, this paper differs from standard approaches that look at the relationship between sentiment about the future and consumption by empirically estimating both sentiment and risk impacts from an economic growth model perspective. Second, our work offers a bridge that connects the empirical literature that looks at sentiments in macroeconomics and the literature devoted to economic growth models in a recursive utility framework. Third, the empirical strategy uses both the latent factor method and the democratic orthogonalization method. The methodology of latent factor analysis is a technique that allows a large panel of indicators on consumer future expectations to be summarized by a relatively small number of estimated factors. In the past few years, a growing number of applied works in finance and macroeconomics have used latent factor models [see for instance Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002); Bernanke and Boivin (Reference Bernanke and Boivin2003); Bernanke et al. (Reference Bernanke, Boivin and Eliasz2005); Favero et al. (Reference Favero, Marcellino and Neglia2005); Boivin and Giannoni (Reference Boivin and Giannoni2006); Forni et al. (Reference Forni, Giannone, Lippi and Reichlin2009); Ludvigson and Ng (Reference Ludvigson and Ng2009); Bouaddi and Taamouti (Reference Bouaddi and Taamouti2012, Reference Bouaddi and Taamouti2013); Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Favilukis and Ludvigson2013); Kakeu and Bouaddi (Reference Kakeu and Bouaddi2017); and Thimme (Reference Thimme2017)]. To provide endogenous approximation of the value function of the consumer problem, it is replaced with a log linear function of sentiment latent factors and parameters to be estimated through the dynamics of the optimal consumption. This strategy is in line with Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2017), [p. 955] who suggests that while the utility index itself is not observable, one way to deal with the estimation is to substitute it as a function of quantifiable variables, such as latent factors, related to the state of the economy. While estimating the risk factors involved in the dynamic of consumption behavior, we make use of the Engle (Reference Engle2002) Dynamic Conditional Correlation model approach. A similar tool is used by Bali and Engle (Reference Bali and Engle2010). As mentioned earlier, we also make use of the democratic orthogonalization method developed by (Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970)) in the Quantum Chemistry literature to compute the relative importance of sentiments and risk factors in contributing to variations in consumption.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 briefly presents the stochastic growth model by Kakeu and Byron (Reference Kakeu and Byron2016) that features sentiment and long-run risk factors associated with future growth prospects in optimal consumer behavior. Section 3 describes an econometric methodology that incorporates the latent factor analysis for estimating the optimal consumer behavior. Section 4 presents the data. Section 5 presents empirical results. The last section offers concluding comments.

2. A stochastic growth model with recursive utility

This empirical paper builds on the stochastic growth model by Kakeu and Byron (Reference Kakeu and Byron2016) that analyzes how uncertainty and expectations about future prospects affect optimal consumer behavior. The representative consumer is endowed with stochastic recursive preferences à la Duffie and Epstein (Reference Duffie and Epstein1992). Recursive preferences give rise to an “aggregator” function for current utility at each time $t$ , $f(c(t),J(t))$ , that combines current consumption, $c(t)$ , and an index of future utility, $J(t)$ . The index $J(t)$ may also be viewed as prospective utility (Koopmans (Reference Koopmans1960)), which expresses expectations about future consumption prospects. In combining both current consumption and expectations about future consumption prospects, recursive utility allows a potential role for sentiment about future consumption to matter in the consumer’s decision (Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2005); Sargent (Reference Sargent2007); Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012)). The consumer’s optimization problem consists in choosing a consumption process $c=\{c(t)\,{:}\,t\geq 0\}$ so as to maximize the present discounted value of the entire stream of net benefits subject to the capital accumulation constraint. That is, the consumer’s decision problem is

(1) \begin{equation} \max _{\{c(t):\,t\geq 0\}}E_{0}\Big [\int _{0}^{\infty }f(c(t),J(t))dt\Big ], \end{equation}

subject to:

(2) \begin{align} dK(t) &=\Big [F(K(t))-c(t)-\delta K(t)\Big ]dt+\sigma (K(t))dB(t), \end{align}
(3) \begin{align} c(t)\geq 0, \end{align}
(4) \begin{align} K(t)\geq 0, \end{align}
(5) \begin{align} K(0)=K_{0}\gt 0. \end{align}

As mentioned earlier, the forward-looking flexible feature of recursive utility allows a potential role for sentiment about future consumption to matter endogenously in the consumer’s decision (Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2005); Sargent (Reference Sargent2007); Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012)). Sentiment about the future is shaped dynamically by changes in uncertainty shocks to the economy as well as changes in the state of the economy. In analyzing how uncertainty and expectations about future consumption prospects affect optimal consumer behavior, Kakeu and Byron (Reference Kakeu and Byron2016) show that the expected consumption growth rate is given by

(6) \begin{eqnarray} &&\frac{1}{c(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc(t)=\left ( \frac{-c(t)f_{cc}(t)}{f_{c}(t)}\right ) ^{-1}. \notag\\ &&\left [ \underbrace{f_{J}(c(t),J(t))}_{\text{Endogenous discount rate}}+\underbrace{F_{K}(t)-\delta }_{\text{Marginal product}}+\underbrace{\left [ \frac{J(t)f_{cJ}(t)}{f_{c}}\right ] \left ( \frac{1}{J(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dJ(t)\right ) }_{\text{Sentiment effect}}\right ] \notag \\ &+&\frac{1}{2}\left [ \underbrace{\frac{-c^{2}(t)f_{ccc}(t)}{c(t)f_{cc}(t)}\sigma _{c}^{2}}_{\text{Short-run risk}}-\underbrace{\frac{J^{2}(t)f_{cJJ}(t)}{c(t)f_{cc}(t)}\sigma _{J}^{2}(t)-\frac{2c(t)J(t)f_{ccJ}(t)}{c(t)f_{cc}(t)}\sigma _{cJ}(t)}_{\text{Long-run risk}}\right ] \end{eqnarray}

Equation (6) shows the link among the expected growth rate of consumption, sentiments about future prospects, short-run risk factors, and long-run risk factors.

In equation (6), the term $\left [ \frac{-c(t)f_{cc}(t)}{f_{c}(t)}\right ] ^{-1}$ is the inverse of the Arrow–Pratt measure of relative risk aversion associated with consumption.

The term $-f_{J}(c,J(t))$ highlights the role of an endogenous discount rate on the optimal expected consumption growth rate.

The term $F_{K}(t)-\delta$ is the net marginal product of the capital stock.

The term $\left (\frac{J(t)f_{cJ}(t)}{f_{c}(t)}\right )\left (\frac{1}{J(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dJ(t)\right )$ contains the growth rate of the future utility index which updates the expectations about future consumption prospects. It gives the overall effect of sentiment on the consumer’s future consumption prospects.

In equation (6), the weight $-\frac{c^{2}(t)f_{ccc}(t)}{c(t)f_{cc}(t)}$ is a measure of prudence regarding short-run uncertainty. The weight $-\frac{J^{2}(t)f_{cJJ}(t)}{c(t)f_{cc}(t)}$ is a measure of prudence regarding long-run uncertainty. The weight $\frac{c(t)J(t)f_{ccJ}(t)}{c(t)f_{cc}(t)}$ is a measure of cross-prudence regarding both short-run and long-run uncertainty.

In the very particular case where the aggregator takes the form $f(c,J)=U(c)-\beta J,$ which is the aggregator of the time-additive utility,Footnote 6 then equation (6) reduces to:

(7) \begin{equation} \frac{1}{c(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc(t)=\left ( \frac{-c(t)u_{cc}(t)}{u_{c}(t)}\right ) ^{-1}[(F_{K}(t)-\delta )-\beta ]-\frac{1}{2}\left [ -\frac{c^{2}(t)u_{ccc}(t)}{c(t)u_{cc}(t)}\right ] \sigma _{c}^{2}(t). \end{equation}

It is worth noting that in such a case, neither sentiment nor long-run risk appears in equation (7). With a time-additive utility function, risks involving future growth prospects do not affect the optimal consumption decision. If in addition, it is assumed that there is no uncertainty, then the optimal consumption rule equation (7) reduces to the following well-known Keynes−Ramsey rule:

(8) \begin{equation} \frac{\dot{c}}{c}=\left [ -c\frac{U_{cc}(c)}{U_{c}(c)}\right ] ^{-1}[(F_{K}(t)-\delta )-\beta ], \end{equation}

where a single dot over a variable signifies its first derivative with respect to time. In this very particular case, where the aggregator is additive with respect to the future utility index, $f_{cJ}(t)=0$ . Therefore, sentiments about the future and long-run risk do not affect the optimal consumption path.

2.1. A parametric example

The aggregator $ f(c,J)$ encodes tradeoffs between current consumption and the future utility index. To better understand how sentiment about the future as well as short-run and long-run risk affect the expected growth rate of consumption, we consider the aggregator of a parametric recursive utility for which existence and unicity are discussed by Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999). The time-additve expected utility is a special case of the Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999) recursive utility.

2.1.1. Aggregator of the Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999)

To estimate equation (6), we rely on the aggregator of the Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999)’s parametric recursive utility given by

(9) \begin{equation} f(c,J)=(1+\alpha )\Big [\frac{c^{\gamma }}{\gamma }J^{\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }}-\beta J\Big ], \end{equation}

with $\alpha \gt -1$ and $\gamma \lt \min{\left ( 1,\frac{1}{1+\alpha }\right ) }$ . This parametric recursive utility is more general than the time-additive expected utility. Additionally, it simplifies the exposition of the econometric model and the interpretation of the parameters to be estimated.

The discount parameter $\beta$ is assumed to be positive. In a time-additive utility model, $\beta$ would simplify the rate of time preference. Time preference is generally endogenous in nonadditive recursive utility settings. The ratio $\frac{1}{1-\gamma }$ is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution and the parameter $\alpha$ captures the dependency of current utility to future utility $J$ .Footnote 7 The curvature of the aggregator $f(x,J)$ with respect to the future utility argument, $J,$ characterizes preferences for the timing of resolution of uncertainty (Kreps and Porteus (Reference Kreps and Porteus1978); Duffie and Epstein (Reference Duffie and Epstein1992); Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999); Strzalecki (Reference Strzalecki2013); Epstein et al. (Reference Epstein, Farhi and Strzalecki2014); Zhao (Reference Zhao2017)), with a convex aggregator favoring early resolution, and a concave aggregator favoring late resolution (Skiadas (Reference Skiadas1998)). An additive temporal aggregator then corresponds to indifference towards the timing of resolution. The sign of the product term $\gamma \alpha$ expresses the curvature of the aggregator with respect to the second argument, and it, therefore, captures attitudes towards the temporal resolution of uncertainty.Footnote 8 As will be later evidenced in subsections 2.1.3 and 3.1, the parameter $\alpha$ calls attention to the role played by sentiment about the future as well as long-run risks in shaping the dynamic of optimal consumption behavior. Additionally, the sign of the product parameter $\alpha \gamma$ helps understand consumers’ attitudes towards the temporal resolution of uncertainty. A value of $\gamma \alpha$ different from zero expresses nonindifference towards the temporal resolution of uncertainty. A negative sign, $\gamma \alpha \lt 0,$ expresses a preference for early resolution of uncertainty whereas a positive sign, $\gamma \alpha \gt 0,$ expresses a preference for late resolution of uncertainty. In the very particular case where $\alpha =0,$ which corresponds to the indifference towards the timing of resolution, the aggregator of the standard time-additive expected utility is obtained as $f(x,V)=\frac{x^{\gamma }}{\gamma }-\beta J.$

Let us mention that in a deterministic setting, a world without uncertainty $(\sigma =0),$ concerns for temporal resolution of uncertainty is not relevant ( $\alpha =0$ ), and the Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999) parametric recursive utility reduces to the aggregator of the time additive expected utility, that is $f(x,J)=\frac{x^{\gamma }}{\gamma }-\beta J.$

2.1.2. Production function

Let us assume the per capital production function is given by

(10) \begin{equation} F(K(t))=A(t)(K(t))^{\nu }, \end{equation}

where $0\lt \nu \leq 1$ and parameter $A(t)\gt 0$ is the total factor productivity (TFP) at time $t$ . This functional form includes the A(t)K(t) production function as a special case, $(\nu =1)$ .

2.1.3. Optimal consumption path

Substituting the production function (10) and the parametric aggregator specification (9) in the expected consumption growth (6) gives

(11) \begin{eqnarray} \frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc &=& \frac{1}{1-\gamma }\left [\left (-\beta (1+\alpha )+\alpha \frac{c^{\gamma }}{\gamma }J^{\frac{-1}{1+\alpha }}\right )+(\nu AK^{\nu -1}-\delta ) +\underbrace{\left [\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }\right ]\left (\frac{1}{J}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dJ\right )}_{\text{Sentiment}}\right ] \notag \\ &+& \frac{1}{2}\left [\underbrace{(2-\gamma )\sigma _{c}^{2}}_{\text{Short-run risk}}+\underbrace{\frac{\alpha }{(1+\alpha )^{2}(\gamma -1)}\sigma _{J}^{2}(t)-\frac{ 2\alpha }{1+\alpha }\sigma _{cJ}(t)}_{\text{Long-run risk}}\right ] \end{eqnarray}

It is also worth mentioning that the special case where $\alpha =0$ which relates to a time-additive expected utility, expresses indifference towards the resolution of uncertainty. In that case, equation (11) reduces to

(12) \begin{eqnarray} \frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc &=& \frac{1}{1-\gamma }\left [-\beta +(\nu AK^{\nu -1}-\delta )+\frac{1}{2}\underbrace{(2-\gamma )\sigma _{c}^{2}}_{\text{Short-run risk}} \right ] \end{eqnarray}

As we can see in equation (12), the special case where $\alpha =0$ would imply that consumption variations are not impacted neither by sentiment component accounts nor by long-run risks. The statistical significance of the preference parameters in estimating the consumption path (11) will be of paramount interest in the empirical section.

3. Empirical strategy based on latent factor method

This section describes our data, calibration approach and presents details regarding the main estimation procedure for the consumption growth equation. A combination of calibrated and estimated parameters is used.

3.1. Estimation of the parameters

The estimation of the parameters $\alpha$ and $\gamma$ requires to obtain the proxies of variables in both the right-hand side of the optimal consumption rule (11). The left-hand side corresponds to the optimal consumption. It will be estimated using the method of estimating continuous time diffusion process of Nowman (Reference Nowman1997). On the other hand, the variables that appear on the right-hand side of the optimal consumption (11) include the value function and its growth rate. While the value function is not directly observable, it depends on expectations about future prospects of the economy. To emphasize this point, Koopmans (Reference Koopmans1960) refers to the value function as the prospective utility. The value function can be estimated by using a small numbers of factors $F=(F_{1},\ldots,F_{L})$ called latent variables that capture expectations about future prospects of the economy. The estimation of latent factors is based on the procedure proposed by Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002) and presented in Appendix A. Other studies that have used the latent factor approach include Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002); Bernanke and Boivin (Reference Bernanke and Boivin2003); Bernanke et al. (Reference Bernanke, Boivin and Eliasz2005); Favero et al. (Reference Favero, Marcellino and Neglia2005); Boivin and Giannoni (Reference Boivin and Giannoni2006); Forni et al. (Reference Forni, Giannone, Lippi and Reichlin2009); Ludvigson and Ng (Reference Ludvigson and Ng2009); Bouaddi and Taamouti (Reference Bouaddi and Taamouti2012); Bouaddi and Taamouti (Reference Bouaddi and Taamouti2013); Kakeu and Bouaddi (Reference Kakeu and Bouaddi2017).

In general, there is no closed-form solution to the value function. An approximation of the value function is used for empirical purposes. The empirical estimate of models with a recursive utility framework is still difficult due to the latency of the value function (Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Favilukis and Ludvigson2013); Thimme (Reference Thimme2017)), and researchers must use approximations. While the utility index itself is not observable, one way to deal with the estimation is to substitute it as a function of quantifiable variables, such as latent factors, related to the state of the economy (Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2017)). In a recursive utility framework, the value function depends upon expectations about future consumption growth. Proxying the recursive utility index by using latent factor techniques that capture expectations about the future of the economy is well grounded following tradition in empirical works using recursive utility (Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2005); Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012); Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Favilukis and Ludvigson2013); Kakeu and Bouaddi (Reference Kakeu and Bouaddi2017)). For instance, Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Favilukis and Ludvigson2013) use latent factor techniques to explicitly estimate the unobservable continuation value of the future consumption plan in a discrete time Epstein and Zin (Reference Epstein and Zin1989) recursive utility framework. We use a Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999) continuous-time stochastic recursive preferences, and we assume that the logarithm of the value function is a linear function of the estimated latent factors related to sentiment about the future.Footnote 9 We will use the Michigan consumer sentiment index which is a monthly assessment of consumer expectations about the future. The Michigan survey is a leading indicator that attempts to predict economic conditions a full year into the future.

Our approach uses a latent factor approximation of the value function which takes the following functional form.

(13) \begin{equation} J(t)=e^{\left ( \theta +\sum _{i=1}^{L}\phi _{i}F_{i}(t)\right ) }. \end{equation}

Equation (13) can be viewed as a way of log linearizing the model. Note that the differential form of equation (13) implies that changes in the value function can be approximated linearly by changes in the latent factors. Log-linear approximations are often used in macroeconomic and financial models (Bansal and Yaron (Reference Bansal and Yaron2004); Ljungqvist and Sargent (Reference Ljungqvist and Sargent2004); Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2005); Lau and Ng (Reference Lau and Ng2007); Restoy and Weil (Reference Restoy and Weil2011)). The estimation of the latent factors is done in the first step of the econometric procedure. The approximated value function $\widetilde{J}(t)=J(\widetilde{F_{1}}_{t},\ldots,\widetilde{F_{L}}_{t})$ is a function of those estimated latent factors obtained from sentiment variables. The estimated value function $\widetilde{J}(t)$ is a consistent estimate of the value function $J(t)$ that is not observable.

When the value function is replaced by its approximate in the pricing equation, the estimation of the parameters $\theta$ , and $(\phi _{i})_{i=1,..L}$ in the expression (13) are done simultaneously with the preference parameters $\alpha$ , $\beta$ , and $\gamma$ described in the expression (9). That is, this specification allows the value function to be endogenously and jointly estimated with the preference parameters in the structural model.Footnote 10

The optimal consumption rule (11) reduces to

(14) \begin{align} \nonumber \frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc &= \frac{1}{1-\gamma }\left[\left ( -\beta (1+\alpha )+\alpha \frac{c^{\gamma }}{\gamma }\left ( e^{\left ( \theta +\sum _{i=1}^{L}\phi _{i}F_{i}(t)\right ) }\right ) ^{\frac{1}{1+\alpha }} \right ) +(\nu AK^{\nu -1}-\delta ) \phantom{\underbrace{\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }\left ( \sum _{i=1}^{L}\phi _{i}F_{i}(t)+\theta \right ) }}\right.\\&\quad\quad\qquad \left.+\underbrace{\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }\left ( \sum _{i=1}^{L}\phi _{i}F_{i}(t)+\theta \right ) }_{\text{Sentiment}}\right ] \nonumber\\ &\quad + \frac{1}{2}\left \{ \underbrace{(2-\gamma )\sigma _{c}^{2}(t)}_{\text{Short-run risk}}+\underbrace{\frac{\alpha }{(1+\alpha )^{2}(\gamma -1)}\sum _{i=1}^{L}\phi _{i}^{2}F_{i}^{2}(t)\sigma _{F_{i}}^{2}(t)-\frac{2\alpha }{1+\alpha }\sum _{i=1}^{L}\phi _iF_{i}(t)\sigma _{cF_{i}}(t)}_{\text{Long-run risk}}\right \} \end{align}

The factor decomposition provided by equation (14) gives a description of the relationship between the expected optimal consumption, sentiment, and long-run risks. Following Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012), this shows that recursive preferences provide a channel for sentiment to matter in consumption decision-making. The present work aims at quantifying the impact of sentiments and long-run risks on optimal consumption decisions. The long-run risk components in equation (14) encapsulate the uncertainty shocks to the latent factors, which follow stochastic processes. Movements in the latent factors should be traced to movements in sentiment indicators. The sentiment indicators are forward-looking indicators as they capture information about the state of the economy as well as expectations about future prospects of the economy.

3.2. Description of the data on consumption per capita

Consumption data come from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank and cover the period from February 1980 to December 2014. We used the real personal consumption expenditures of services, the real personal consumption expenditures of nondurable goods, and capital stock at constant national prices.Footnote 11 We also use the total civilian population to get the real consumption per capita and the real capital stock per capita.Footnote 12 We computed the per capita real consumption as the sum of the real personal consumption expenditures of services and real personal consumption expenditures of nondurable goods over civilian population to get the per capita consumption level. Similarly, we compute the per capita capital as the real capital stock over civilian population. We then use the growth rate (log-difference) on real per capita personal consumption expenditures of services and nondurable goods (See Figure 1).

3.2.1. Estimation of the expected growth rate of consumption $\frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc$

The consumption is expected to follow a stochastic process

(15) \begin{equation} dC(t) = \mu _{C}(t,C(t))dt+\sigma _{C}(t,C(t))d\zeta (t), \end{equation}

where

\begin{equation*} C(t)=\int _{0}^{t}\frac {dc (\tau )}{c (\tau )} \end{equation*}

represent the cumulative consumption, and $\mu _{C}(t,C(t))=\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dC=\frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc$ represents the expected growth rate of consumption.

Figure 1. Consumption per capita growth rate.

For estimation purposes, let us assume the following parametric specification

(16) \begin{align} dC(t)=(\alpha _{1}+\alpha _{2}C(t))dt+\delta C(t)^{\alpha _{3}}d\zeta (t), \end{align}

for which a discrete approximation was developed by Nowman (Reference Nowman1997) and based on some results found in Bergstrom (Reference Bergstrom1983) as follows:

(17) \begin{equation} C_{t}=e^{\alpha _{2}}C_{t-1}+\frac{\alpha _{1}}{\alpha _{2}}(e^{\alpha _{2},}-1)+\eta _{t} \end{equation}

where the conditional distribution of the error term $\eta _{t}$ satisfies

\begin{equation*} E_{t-1}(\eta _{s}\eta ^{t})=\displaystyle \begin {cases} 0 & \mathrm {if\ }s\neq t, \\ \\[-7pt] \frac {\delta ^{2}}{2\alpha _{2}}(e^{\alpha _{2}}-1)(C_{t-1})^{2\alpha _{3}} & \mathrm {if\ }s=t.\end {cases}\end{equation*}

The logarithm of the Gaussian likelihood function is

\begin{equation*} L(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2},\alpha _{3},\delta )=\sum _{t=1}^{T}[\log E_{t-1}(\eta _{t}^{2})+\frac {(C_{t}-e^{\alpha _{2}}C_{t-1}-\frac {\alpha _{1}}{\alpha _{2}}(e^{\alpha _{2}}-1))^{2}}{E(\eta _{t}^{2})}], \end{equation*}

where $E_{t-1}(\eta _{t}^{2})=\frac{\delta ^{2}}{2\alpha _{2}}(e^{\alpha _{2}}-1)(C_{t-1})^{2\alpha _{3}}.$

Maximum likelihood estimation consists of solving

(18) \begin{equation} (\widehat{\alpha }_{1},\widehat{\alpha }_{2},\widehat{\alpha }_{3},\widehat{\delta })=\arg \max _{\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2},\alpha _{3},\delta }L(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2},\alpha _{3},\delta ). \end{equation}

It follows from equation (16) that

(19) \begin{equation} \frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc=\widehat{\alpha }_{1}+\widehat{\alpha }_{2}C(t). \end{equation}

3.2.2. Estimation of the latent factors related to the panel of Sentiment data

The latent factor analysis is used to estimate a small number of latent factors the panel of consumer sentiment indicators, spanning from February 1980 to December 2014. The panel of sentiment indicators form a group of Indexes of “Index Consumer Sentiment” and “Index of Consumer Expectations” by age groups, regions, income and education level, a total of 32 indicators. These data are downloaded from the University of Michigan website.Footnote 13 The latent factors are estimated using the optimization program (47)−(48) presented in Appendix A. Using the information criteria proposed by Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002), one factor is selected, representing 76% of the total variation of the panel of sentiment indicators.

3.3. Description of data on total factor productivity and real capital stock

The optimal consumption path (14) incorporates the marginal product of capital at time $t$ , which depends upon the TFP, $A(t),$ and the capital stock per capita, $K(t)$ .

The capital stock is computed at constant 2005 national prices (in mil. 2005 US $\$ $ ). Capital stock is estimated based on accumulated and depreciated past investments. It includes Structures (residential and nonresidential), Transport equipment, Computers, Communication equipment, Software, and Other machinery and assets.Footnote 14

The TFP is the output less the contribution of capital and labor. The TFP is adjusted for capacity utilization of the capital stock. The computation methodology related to the utilization-adjusted TFP is discussed by Fernald and Matoba (Reference Fernald and Matoba2009); Fernald (Reference Fernald2014), and Basu et al. (Reference Basu, Fernald and Kimball2006).

We compute the monthly equivalent by using an interpolation technique for deriving a monthly series from annual data. A similar frequency conversion technique is used by the Federal Reserve Bank.Footnote 15 For more details about the disaggregation of low frequency data to higher frequency, we refer the reader to the following papers: Boot et al. (Reference Boot, Feibes and Lisman1967); Denton (Reference Denton1971); Chan (Reference Chan1993); Feijoo et al. (Reference Feijoo, Caro and Quintana2003); and Feijoo et al. (Reference Feijoo, Caro and Quintana2003) among others. In our context, the measurement error resulting from frequency conversion of the dependent variable has zero mean and and is uncorrelated with regressors. Thus, we can estimate consistently the parameters in this case. We argue that this is true in our case since the high frequency counterpart is obtained by pure statistical method not involving the regressors which testify that the measurement error is independent of regressors preserving the consistency of the estimator. Of course, the estimates will be less precise than with data without measurement error. The induced inflation in the variance of the estimator will impact the significance of the parameters via lower t-statistics. However, if all p-values are below the significant level then this variance inflation is unimportant (the t-statistics are very conservative toward the null hypothesis).

3.4. Database on the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers’ sentiment

Sentiment factors are derived from the monthly Survey of Consumers by the University of Michigan.Footnote 16 The survey on consumer expectations focuses on consumer’s view prospects for their own financial situation, their prospects about the general economy over the near term, and their prospects about the economy over the long term. The survey contains consumer’s prospects about personal finances, savings and retirement, economic conditions, unemployment, prices, government expectations, household goods buying conditions, vehicle buying conditions, and home buying and selling conditions.Footnote 17

3.5. Calibrated parameters

Some parameters are calibrated to match stylized facts. Following a calibration methodology emphasized by Lucas (Reference Lucas1980) and Kydland and Prescott (Reference Kydland and Prescott1982), the parameter of the production function $\nu$ is set at $0.36$ in line with standard economic research. The subjective discount rate $\beta$ is set at 4% per annum, which is equivalent to 0.33% per month. The capital depreciation rate, $\delta$ , is set at $2.54\%$ per annum, which is equivalent to $0.25\%$ per month.

3.6. Empirical results

The estimation of the parameters related to the optimal consumer path uses an econometric approach that incorporates the latent factor analysis on sentiment indicators. We used the information criteria of Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002) to select the optimal number of fundamental factors governing the sentiment indicators. The criterion selected one factor, denoted hereafter by $F$ without subscript. More detail about the related econometric model is provided in Appendix B.

(20) \begin{align} \frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc &=\frac{1}{1-\gamma }\left [\! \left (\! -\beta (1+\alpha )+\alpha \frac{c^{\gamma }}{\gamma }\left ( e^{\left ( \theta + \phi F (t)\right ) }\right ) ^{\frac{1}{1+\alpha }} \right ) +(\nu AK^{\nu -1}-\delta )+\underbrace{\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }\left (\phi F(t)+\theta \right ) }_{\text{Sentiment}}\right ] \nonumber \\ &\quad +\frac{1}{2}\left \{ \underbrace{(2-\gamma )\sigma _{c}^{2}(t)}_{\text{Short-run risk}}+\underbrace{\frac{\alpha }{(1+\alpha )^{2}(\gamma -1)}\phi ^{2}F^{2}(t)\sigma _F^{2}(t)-\frac{2\alpha }{1+\alpha }\phi F(t)\sigma _{cF}(t)}_{\text{Long-run risk}},\right \} \end{align}

Estimated coefficients of the structural model are reported in Table 1.

Table 1. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20)

All the parameters are statistically different from zero, including the parameter $\alpha$ related to risk attitudes towards long-run uncertainty. A decomposition of consumption variations incorporates multiple component including sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk, as shown in Table 3. To contrast, with a time-additive expected utility, consumption variations are not impacted neither by sentiment component nor by long-run risks.

With a Schroder and Skiadas (Reference Schroder and Skiadas1999) parametric recursive utility, the sign of the product of the parameters $\gamma \alpha$ is important for understanding consumers’ attitudes towards long-run risk associated with future growth prospects. Occurrence of a negative sign for the product of the parameters $\gamma \alpha \lt 0,$ would mean that consumers prefer an early resolution of uncertainty. And therefore, consumers are averse to long-run risks associated with future growth prospects. As shown in Table 7, the product of the estimated parameters $\gamma \alpha$ is negative and the parameters $\alpha$ and $\gamma$ are statistically significant. This suggests that consumers prefer early resolution of uncertainty, and therefore are averse to long-run risk associated with uncertainty shocks to future growth prospects. This underscores the importance of the long-run risk channel for understanding the consumption path. Our results echo Bansal and Yaron (Reference Bansal and Yaron2004) and Sargent (Reference Sargent2007) who emphasize that economic models incorporating long-run risks have the potential to provide additional channel for understanding dynamic consumers’ behavior.

3.7. Descriptive statistics and correlation statistics between sentiment and risk factors

Using the components of the dynamic optimal consumption path (20), we computed the correlations between sentiment, short-run risks, and long-run risks. As shown in Table 2, there is a statistical significant negative correlation between sentiment and long risks.

Table 2. Correlation between sentiment about the future and risk factors

Note: The t-statistics are between brackets.

This suggests that worsening sentiment about future prospects of the economy is linked to growing long-run uncertainty level about the economy. Long-run uncertainty is high when consumers are less confident in the future prospects of the economy. This suggests that ignoring sentiment about future prospects while analyzing long-run risk involved in consumption decisions would not provide the full picture for understanding forces that govern consumption decisions. The statistical significant correlation also suggests a linkage between sentiment about the future and nonindifference towards the temporal resolution of future uncertainty. In Appendix C, Table 10, we have provided additional descriptive statistics related to sentiment and short-run and long-run risk factors.

4. Decomposition of the variance of the consumption growth rate: Impact of sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk

In what follows, we want to compute the contribution of sentiments about the future, short-run risks, and long-run risks in shaping the optimal consumption path. We use the democratic orthogonalization method that was originally developed by Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970) in the Quantum Chemistry literature. The democratic orthogonalization method was recently introduced into the asset pricing and finance literature (Klein and Chow (Reference Klein and Chow2013); Bessler et al. (Reference Bessler, Kurmann and Tom2015)). In this section, we use the democratic orthogonalization method to compute the relative importance of sentiments and risk factors in contributing to variations in consumption.

First, let us rewrite the optimal consumption path equation as follows:

(21) \begin{eqnarray} \underbrace{\frac{1}{c}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc}_{\text{Expected consumption growth}} &=& x_{1,t}+\underbrace{x_{2,t}}_{\text{Sentiment}}+\underbrace{x_{3,t}}_{\text{Long-run risk}}+\underbrace{x_{4,t}}_{\text{Short-run risk}} \end{eqnarray}

where

(22) \begin{align} x_{1,t}&=\frac{1}{1- \gamma }\left [\left (-\beta (1+\alpha )+\alpha \frac{c^{\gamma }}{\gamma }\left (e^{\left ( \theta +\phi F(t)\right )}\right )^{\frac{1}{1+\alpha }}\right )+(\nu AK^{\nu -1}-\delta ) \right ] ;\, \, \, \,t=1,\ldots,T; \end{align}
(23) \begin{align} x_{2,t} &=\frac{1}{1- \gamma }\left [\frac{ \alpha }{1+ \alpha }\right ]\left ( \phi F(t)+ \theta \right ) ;\, \, \, \,t=1,\ldots,T; \end{align}
(24) \begin{align} x_{3,t} &=-\frac{1}{2}\left \{ \frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }F(t)\sigma _{cF(t)}-\frac{\alpha }{(1+\alpha )^{2}(\gamma -1)} \phi ^{2}F^{2}(t)\sigma _{F}^{2}(t)\right \} ;\,\, \, \,t=1,\ldots,T; \end{align}
(25) \begin{align} x_{4,t} =\frac{1}{2}\left \{ (2-\gamma )\sigma _{c}^{2}(t)\right \} ;\, \, \,\,t=1,\ldots,T; \end{align}

Equation (21) shows that the expected consumption growth is explained by the combined effects of the five factors that show up on the right-hand side. We need to isolate the specific contribution of each of these five factors on the expected consumption growth. If the factors explaining the targeted variable are correlated, the total variance cannot be allocated unambiguously among these explanatory variables, except when there is zero multicollinearity between them. While there are various orthogonalization techniques available, the optimal one that produces the appropriate orthogonal proxies of the original variables is the symmetric procedure of Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970) and Schweinler and Wigner (Reference Schweinler and Wigner1970). This approach is called democratic orthogonalization in the sense that it is symmetric and egalitarian instead of sequential and asymmetric.Footnote 18 The democratic approach minimizes the overall difference between the original explanatory variables and their orthogonal counterparts (Schweinler−Wigner basis) as highlighted by Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970) and Srivastava (Reference Srivastava2000). Aiken et al. (Reference Aiken, Erdos and Goldstein1980) argue that the democratic orthogonalization is optimal with respect to all common norms (all the Schatten−von Neumann norms).Footnote 19 Moreover, Aiken et al. (Reference Aiken, Erdos and Goldstein1980) show that the minimum distance, in terms of least squares sense, between the original explanatory variables and their orthogonal counterparts is achieved only for democratic orthogonalization. In addition, if the eigenvalues of the correlation matrix are all distinct then these orthogonalized variables are unique.

4.1. Democratic decomposition of Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970) applied to equation (21)

In a discrete time setting $t=1,\ldots,T$ , the right-hand side components of equation (21) are the columns of the following matrix

(26) \begin{equation} X=\left ( \begin{array}{cccc} x_{1,1} & x_{2,1} & x_{3,1} & x_{4,1} \\ . &. &. &. \\ x_{1,t} & x_{2,t} & x_{3,t} & x_{4,t} \\ . &. &. &. \\ x_{1,T} & x_{2,T} & x_{3,T} & x_{4,T}\end{array}\right ) \quad \end{equation}

If the columns of the matrix $X$ are statistically independent or orthogonal, then the ratio of the variance of the ith column to the sum of all the variances of all columns would capture the contribution of that factor in explaining variations in expected consumption growth. But in general, the columns of the matrix $X$ may not be statistically independent or orthogonal. In this case, it is possible to find an orthogonal equivalent of $X$ whose columns are statistically independent or orthogonal, with the diagonal entries being exactly equal to the variances of the components of the columns of $X_{t}$ . The democratic decomposition method developed by Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970) is a statistical method that allows to transform a matrix of correlated variables into an information-equivalent matrix of variables that are noncorrelated. The democratic decomposition allows to isolate the specific contribution of each component, which is important in light of common variation, permitting a clear interpretation of the individual relationships.Footnote 20 Applied to our economic framework, the democratic decomposition extracts standalone orthogonal components of sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk while maintaining an optimal relationship with the underlining variables. The variances of orthogonal components of sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk emerging from the democratic decomposition are identical to those of the original variables. The democratic decomposition ensures that the orthogonal components of sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk best resemble the original variables. Using this procedure, the orthogonal components are used to compute the relative contribution of sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk in explaining variations in expected consumption growth.

In what follows we give a brief presentation of the democratic orthogonalization method developed by Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970). Let us consider the general case where the components of the vector $X_{t}= ( x_{1,t},x_{2,t},x_{3,t},x_{4,t} ) ^{\prime }$ may display some correlation. In order to analyze the contribution of each component, we need to find an orthogonal equivalent, denoted by $Z_{t}= ( z_{1,t},z_{2,t},z_{3,t},z_{4,t} ) ^{\prime }$ whose associated covariance matrix is diagonal and the diagonal entries are exactly the variances of the components of the vector $X_{t}$ .

(27) \begin{equation} \mathcal{X}=\left ( \begin{array}{cccc} x_{1,1} & x_{2,1} & x_{3,1} & x_{4,1} \\ . &. &. &. \\ x_{1,t} & x_{2,t} & x_{3,t} & x_{4,t} \\ . &. &. &. \\ x_{1,T} & x_{2,T} & x_{3,T} & x_{4,T}\end{array}\right ) -\left ( \begin{array}{cccc} \overline{x}_{1} & \overline{x}_{2} & \overline{x}_{3} & \overline{x}_{4} \\ . &. &. &. \\ \overline{x}_{1} & \overline{x}_{2} & \overline{x}_{3} & \overline{x}_{4} \\ . &. &. &. \\ \overline{x}_{1} & \overline{x}_{2} & \overline{x}_{3} & \overline{x}_{4}\end{array}\right ) \end{equation}

Denote by

\begin{equation*} \widehat {\Omega }=\text{Cov}(\mathcal {X}) \end{equation*}

the sample covariance matrix of the components of $\mathcal{X}$ . It can be factorized as

(28) \begin{align} \widehat{\Omega }=F\Lambda F^{\prime } \end{align}
(29) \begin{align} F^{\prime } F=I \end{align}
(30) \begin{align} \Lambda \,\,\text{is a diagonal matrix}. \end{align}

As shown by Löwdin (Reference Löwdin1970), the democratically orthogonalized components are given by

(31) \begin{equation} \mathcal{Z}=Y\Upsilon. \end{equation}

where

(32) \begin{align} Y=\mathcal{X}F\Lambda ^{-\frac{1}{2}}F^{\prime }, \end{align}
(33) \begin{align} \Upsilon =\text{Diag}(\widehat{\Omega }) \end{align}

To be clear, the matrix $\Upsilon =\text{Diag}(\widehat{\Omega })$ is the diagonal matrix whose main diagonal is equal to the main diagonal of $\widehat{\Omega }$ . Note also that $Y^{\prime }Y=I$ .

The variances of the columns of the matrix (31) resulting from the democratic decomposition

are identical to the variances of the columns of the initial matrix of components $X$ [shown in equation (26)].

To estimate the cross-section variances $(s_{i,t}^{2})_{i=1,2,3,4\,\, t=1.,,,,T}$ related to the entries of $\mathcal{Z}$ , represented by the matrix form as follows

(34) \begin{equation} s^{2}=\left (\begin{array}{c@{\quad}c@{\quad}c@{\quad}c} s_{1,1} ^2 & s_{2,1}^2 & s_{3,1}^2 & s_{4,1}^2 \\ . &. &. &. \\ s_{1,t} ^2 & s_{2,t}^2 & s_{3,t}^2 & s_{4,t}^2 \\ . &. &. &. \\ s_{1,T}^2 & s_{2,T}^2 & s_{3,T}^2 & s_{4,T}^2\end{array}\right ) \end{equation}

we used 200 bootstraped $(\mathcal{Z})_{b=1,\ldots,200}$ samples of $\mathcal{Z}$ . Using this procedure, the estimated cross-section variances of $\mathcal{Z}$ are used to compute the relative contribution of sentiment, short-run risk, and long-run risk in explaining variations in expected consumption growth as follows:

(35) \begin{align} \text{Sentiment impact}=\frac{s_{2,t}^{2}}{s_{1,t}^{2}+s_{2,t}^{2}+s_{3,t}^{2}+s_{4,t}^{2}}\, \, \, \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\, \, \, \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\quad t=1,\ldots,T. \end{align}
(36) \begin{align} \text{Long-run risk impact}=\frac{s_{3,t}^{2}}{s_{1,t}^{2}+s_{2,t}^{2}+s_{3,t}^{2}+s_{4,t}^{2}}\, \, \, \,\,\,\,\,\,\quad t=1,\ldots,T. \end{align}
(37) \begin{align} \text{Short-run risk impact}=\frac{s_{4,t}^{2}}{s_{1,t}^{2}+s_{2,t}^{2}+s_{3,t}^{2}+s_{4,t}^{2}}\, \, \, \,\,\,\,\,\,\quad t=1,\ldots,T. \end{align}
(38) \begin{align} \text{Macro risk impact}=\frac{s_{3,t}^{2}+s_{4,t}^{2}}{s_{1,t}^{2}+s_{2,t}^{2}+s_{3,t}^{2}+s_{4,t}^{2}}\, \, \, \,\,\,\,\,\,\quad \quad \quad t=1,\ldots,T. \end{align}

4.2. Descriptive statistics of impact proportions

Table 3 displays the descriptive statistics of the sentiment impact, the short-run risk, the long-run risk, and the macro-risk impact, which is the sum of the short-run risk and long-run risk impacts. Table 3 shows that on average the sentiment component accounts for 15.33% of variations in consumption while macroeconomic risks component account for 51.39%, of which 16.89% pertains to the short-run risk and 34.51% pertains to the long-run risk.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of the sentiment impact, the short-run risk impact, the long-run risk impact, and the macro-risk impact

Figure 2 displays the estimations of the contribution of the sentiment variations to changes in the variation of the expected consumption from 1980 to 2014.

Figure 2. Sentiment impacts from 1980 to 2014.

The graphic analysis of Figure 2 shows that after economic crises (darker shaded areas) the sentiment impact experiences increases or bumps. The highest bump in sentiment impact occurs after early 1990s economic crisis in the USA while the highest bump in the macro risk occurs after the early 1980s recession. The sentiment impacts from financial crisis (light shaded areas) appear to be lower than the ones that occur during or after nonfinancial crises (dark-shaded areas). Sentiment contributions appear to be high during NBER recessions and low during financial crises.

Figure 3 displays the estimations of the Macroeconomic risk impacts from 1980 to 2014. The macroeconomic risk impact varies over time but stays more often greater than 48%. Some bumps in the impact of macroeconomic risk are observed after the early 1980s crises, east Asian crisis (1997), stock market downturn of 2002, and during of after 2007–2009 crises 2009.

Figure 3. Macroeconomic risk impacts from 1980 to 2014.

Figure 4 displays the estimations of the long-run risk impacts from 1980 to 2014. The long-run risk is the dominant component of the macroeconomic risk impact in consumption, staying more often above 30%. The long-risk impact follows a similar pattern as the macroeconomic risk. One important fact to be hilighlighted from the graph is that the long-run risk impacts appear to be leading indicators of NBER recessions and financial crises. That is, the long-run impacts start increasing a few years before crises. Bumps in the long-run risk impacts are observed during the following periods: early 1998s crisis, 1991–1992, financial crash of 1987, the east Asian crisis (1997)

Figure 4 Long-run risk impacts from 1980 to 2014.

Figure 5 below displays the estimations of the short-run risk impacts from 1980 to 2014. The short-run risk impact represents on average 15% of changes in consumption. The short-run risk impact displays bumps after most of the crises.

Figure 5. Short-run risk impacts from 1980 to 2014.

Figures 4 and 5 show that the long-run risk proportion is higher at the start of recession periods while the short-run risk proportion decreases at the start of recession periods. This fact is related to the consumer behavior, as consumer tends to be more pessimistic at the beginning of the recession periods and becomes more worried about the long-run impact of the crisis driving him/her to increase heavily his/her precautionary saving and reduce his/her consumption. At the end of the crisis, the conditions become more stable and the consumer becomes more optimistic and the short-run risk becomes more of a concern leading to a decrease in the long-run risk and an increase of the importance of the short-run risk.

4.3. Comparison with a time-additive expected utility model

This section provides an empirical comparison of the recursive utility model with sentiments and that of the time-additive utility without sentiments. Say another way, we address the question of how well the recursive utility model explains data relative to competing for time-additive utility specification. To rank the two competing models, we use the statistical criterion proposed by Akaike (Reference Akaike1974), also known as the Akaike information criterion (AIC). The AIC is grounded in information theory. It quantifies the information loss when the true model of the data is not selected.

With a time additive expected utility, which corresponds to the aggregator $f(c,J)=U(c)-\beta J$ , where $U(c)=\frac{c^{\gamma }}{\gamma }$ , (which corresponds to the case $\alpha =0$ ), the problem of the representative agent is written as

(39) \begin{equation} \max _{\{c(t):\,t\geq 0\}}E_{0}\Big [\int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-\beta t}U(c(t))dt\Big ], \end{equation}

subject to:

(40) \begin{align} dK(t) =\Big [F(K(t))-c(t)-\delta K(t)\Big ]dt+\sigma (K(t))dB(t), \end{align}
(41) \begin{align} c(t)\geq 0, \end{align}
(42) \begin{align} K(t)\geq 0, \end{align}
(43) \begin{align} K(0)=K_{0}\gt 0. \end{align}

and the optimal consumption path should follow the following rule

(44) \begin{equation} \frac{1}{c(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc(t)=\left ( \frac{-c(t)u_{cc}(t)}{u_{c}(t)}\right ) ^{-1}[(F_{K}(t)-\delta )-\beta ]-\frac{1}{2}\left [ -\frac{c^{2}(t)u_{ccc}(t)}{c(t)u_{cc}(t)}\right ] \sigma _{c}^{2}(t), \end{equation}

which reduces to

(45) \begin{equation} \frac{1}{c(t)}\frac{1}{dt}E_{t}dc(t)=\left ( 1-\gamma \right ) ^{-1}[F_{K}(t)-\delta -\beta ]-\frac{1}{2}\left [ 1-\gamma \right ] \sigma _{c}^{2}(t), \end{equation}

The parameter estimates and statistical tests of the time-additive model are reported in Table 4. For the time-additive utility and recursive models, the parameter of the production function $\nu$ is set at $0.36$ in line with standard economic research. The subjective discount rate $\beta$ is set at 4% per annum, which is equivalent to 0.33% per month. The capital depreciation rate, $\delta$ , is set at $2.54\%$ per annum, which is equivalent to $0.25\%$ per month. As shown in Table 4, the time-additive expected utility model yields an implausibly large value of $1-\gamma =4.09$ for the risk-aversion parameter. The latter issue is related to the so-called Equity Premium Puzzle, a term coined by Mehra and Prescott (Reference Mehra and Prescott1985) to describe the improbably high-risk aversion one must have, in the context of standard time additive expected utility, to own risk-free bonds given the immense equity return premium offered by equity markets.

Table 4. Parameters estimation with the standard time-additive expected utility model

Table 5 reports the measure of specification error given by the AIC information criterion for the recursive utility and the time-additive utility models discussed above. The AIC information criterion can be used to establish the quality of a statistical model for a given set of data (Akaike (Reference Akaike1974)). The AIC information criterion then allows models to be compared, with the having the lowest value being preferable for a given set of data.

Table 5. Akaike (1974) information criterion (AIC) for recursive utility and time-additive utiliy

We can see that the estimated recursive utility model always displays a smaller AIC value than the time-separable CRRA model. The AIC value for the recursive utility specification is $8.6E+06$ , about 94% smaller than that of the time-separable CRRA model.

4.4. Robustness

In this section, we perform a robustness check (sensitivity analysis) by estimating all the parameters except the depreciation rate of capital which is calibrated to different values. The reason behind the calibration of the depreciation rate of capital instead of estimating it is that the discount rate and the depreciation rate of capital are not simultaneously identifiable as can be easily seen from equation (20). Therefore, we choose to calibrate the depreciation rate of capital. We followed the literature to calibrate this rate. This includes Kydland and Prescott (Reference Kydland and Prescott1982) and Greenwood et al. (Reference Greenwood, Hercowitz and Huffman1988) who used a depreciation rate of 0.1 while Dejong et al. (Reference Dejong, Ingram and Whiteman2000) used a depreciation rate ranging from 0.03 and 0.17 and Gomme and Rupert (Reference Gomme and Rupert2007) used a rate of 0.0391. For the sake of robustness in our analysis, we used the minimum and the maximum of the above rates as well as the median. Hence, the depreciation rate is set to 0.03, 0.17, and 0.1 per annum. Tables 68 below give the estimation of the other parameters for the three values of the depreciation rate. We notice from the three tables (Tables 68) that the estimates of the other parameters and their significance are barely sensitive to the depreciation rate changes.

4.4.1. Tests of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45)(standard time-additive utility)

To test whether the model with recursive utility is still quantitatively different from the one with time additive utility even if the parameter $\alpha$ looks small in the aggregator, we computed the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility) and conducted the t-test for the equality of the means, the Wilcoxon/Mann–Whitney test for the equality of the medians and the F-test for equality of variances.

Table 9 shows that the three tests strongly reject the null hypothesis as the p-values are below any conventional significance level.

Table 6. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20) when $\delta =0.17$

Table 7. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20) when $\delta =0.1$

Table 8. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20) when $\delta =0.03$

Table 9. Tests of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.03$

This result is enforced by the kernel nonparametric density estimation (Figure 6) of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility).

Figure 6. Density distribution of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.03$ . For two other alternative values, see Figures 7 and 8.

Figure 7. Density distribution of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.1$ .

Figure 8. Density distribution of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.17$ .

If there were no difference between the two models, the density would be degenerate at zero, with the entire mass concentrated at zero. On the contrary, the graph shows that the density is not degenerate and most of the mass is located away from zero. The results displayed in Appendix D (Tables 11 and 12) show that for two other calibrated values of the depreciation rate, $\delta =0.1$ and $\delta =0.17$ , a similar feature is obtained.

5. Concluding remarks

In this paper, we have applied a latent factor method on a database of consumer sentiment and expectation indicators and a democratic decomposition technique to quantify the effects of both sentiment about the future and long-run risk in shaping optimal consumption decisions in a dynamic recursive utility framework in assessing investor strategies in a data-rich environment. The latent factor method seizes, in one common factor, the most relevant information on both deterministic and stochastic changes available in a large number of sentiment and expectations indicators. Therefore, the time series of one estimated latent factor are an approximative representation of current and future expected changes in the state of the economy. This economic factor contains useful information for the sentiment about the future and long-run risks components of the future consumption path. We find that sentiment about the future, short-run risk and long-run risk have a significant impact on optimal consumption decisions over time, whilst with a standard time additive utility neither sentiment nor long-run risk have an impact. In a recursive utility framework, we are able to find empirical support that endogenous consumption variations are driven by a multi-component mechanism, where on average the sentiment component accounts for 15.33%, the short-run risk accounts for 16.89%, and the long-run risk pertains to 34.51%. Estimation of risk preference parameters reveals that consumers prefer early resolution of uncertainty, and therefore are averse to long-run risks associated with uncertainty shocks to future growth prospects. This underscores the importance of the long-run risk channel for understanding the consumption path. Our results echo Bansal and Yaron (Reference Bansal and Yaron2004); Sargent (Reference Sargent2007) who emphasize that economic models incorporating long-run risks have the potential to provide additional channel for understanding dynamic consumers’ behavior. This evidence is encouraging and shows the usefulness and importance of using recursive utility frameworks for improving our understanding of the different channels that are underlying shapers of consumption decisions at the macroeconomics aggregate level.

The sentiment and risk decomposition of the consumption decisions and the empirical techniques used in this model more generally are potentially useful for other macroeconomic dynamic models with recursive utility function focusing on fiscal or monetary policy issues. In addition to long-run risks, accounting for sentiment about the future as a driver of economic decisions is consistent with forward-looking behavior (Acemoglu and Scott (Reference Acemoglu and Scott1994)). Future developments of the role played by sentiments and long-run risk could include the situation of heterogeneous agent models with regards to both risk attitudes and sentiment about the future.

Appendix A: Sentiment latent factor optimization problem

The basic factor model can be expressed in a matrix form as

(A1) \begin{equation} Z=F\Lambda ^{\prime }+E, \end{equation}

where $Z$ denotes the observed matrix of time series, $F$ is a $T\times r$ matrix of $r$ unobservable common factors, $\Lambda$ is a $N\times r$ matrix of factor loadings and $E$ is $T\times N$ matrix of idiosyncratic errors that are uncorrelated with the components of $F$ .

We particularly focus on the case where a high-dimensional panel of $N$ time series depends on a relatively small number of $r$ common latent factors. The estimates of the latent factors are obtained by solving the following minimization program

(A2) \begin{equation} \underset{F,\Lambda }{\min }\text{Trace}\frac{(Z-F\Lambda ^{\prime })(Z-F\Lambda ^{\prime })^{\prime }}{NT} \end{equation}

subject to

(A3) \begin{equation} \frac{F^{^{\prime }}F}{T}=I_{r}, \end{equation}

where $I_{r}$ is $r$ a dimensional identity matrix. Because $F\Lambda ^{\prime }=FAA^{-1}\Lambda ^{\prime }=F^{\ast }\Lambda ^{\ast \prime }$ for any invertible $r\times r$ matrix $A$ , the factors and the factor loadings are not jointly identified. Thus, the normalization (48) is an identification constraint. It can be shown that each estimated factors $\widetilde{F}$ are the eigenvectors (multiplied by $\sqrt{T}$ ) associated with the largest eigenvalues of the matrix $\frac{ZZ^{^{\prime }}}{TN}$ . A convergence result by Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002) says that as both $T$ and $N$ grow to infinity, the estimated latent variables $(\widetilde{F})$ converge to their true scaled counterpart $(F)$ .

To select the number of factors, we use the following criterion (see Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002))

\begin{equation*} IC_{p2}(r)=\ln \left ( \frac {\text{trace}\left ( \widehat {E}\widehat {E}^{\prime }\right ) }{NT}\right ) +r\frac {N+T}{NT}\ln \left ( C_{NT}^{2}\right ) \end{equation*}

where $\hat{E}$ is the matrix of errors in the sentiment factor model and $C_{NT}=\min \!( \sqrt{N},\sqrt{T} )$ and $\widehat{E}=Z-\widehat{F}\widehat{\Lambda }^{\prime }$ .

Appendix B: The estimation of the model parameters

Our approach uses a latent factor approximation of the value function which takes the following functional form.

(B1) \begin{equation} J(t)=e^{\left ( \theta +\sum _{i=1}^{L}\phi _{i}F_{i}(t)\right ) }. \end{equation}

The econometric model for estimating equation (20) is given by

(B2) \begin{align} \frac{\Delta c_{t}}{c_{t}} & =\frac{1}{1-\gamma }\left [ \left ( -\beta\! \left ( 1+\alpha \right ) +\alpha \frac{c_{t-1}}{\gamma }\left ( e^{\phi F_{t}+\theta }\right ) ^{\frac{1}{1+\alpha }}\right ) +\left ( vA_{t-1}K_{t-1}^{v-1}-\delta \right ) \right. \nonumber\\&\quad \left.+\frac{\alpha }{1+\alpha }\left ( \underset{i=1}{\overset{L}{{ \sum } }}\phi _{i}F_{i,t}+\theta \right ) \right ] \nonumber \\ &\quad +\frac{1}{2}\left [ \left ( 2+\gamma \right ) \sigma _{c,t}^{2}+\frac{\alpha }{\left ( 1+\alpha \right ) ^{2}\left ( \gamma -1\right ) }\underset{i=1}{\overset{L}{{ \sum }}}\phi _{i}^{2}\sigma _{F_{i},t}^{2}-\frac{2\alpha }{1+\alpha }\underset{i=1}{\overset{L}{{ \sum } }}\phi _{i}\sigma _{cF_{i},t}\right ] +\varepsilon _{c,t} \end{align}

where $\varepsilon _{c,t}$ is the regression error term or the unexpected consumption growth. We used the information criteria of Bai and Ng (Reference Bai and Ng2002) to select the optimal number of fundamental factors governing the sentiment indicators. The criterion selected one factor (see Appendix A for details).

The conditional mean of the factor $F_{t}$ is modeled as an ARMA( $p,q$ ). That is

(B3) \begin{equation} F_{t}=\tau +\overset{p}{\underset{j=1}{\sum }}\psi _{j}F_{t-j}+\sum _{k=1}^{q}\rho _{k}\varepsilon _{_{F,t-k}}+\varepsilon _{_{F,t}} \end{equation}

where $\varepsilon _{_{F,t}}$ is the regression error term or the unexpected part of the sentiment factor. Following the literature in time series, we optimaly selected the lags $p$ and $q$ using the Schwart criterion.

The variance–covariance matrix of the regression errors is given by

\begin{equation*} \Omega _{t}=\left ( \begin {array}{cc}\sigma _{c,t}^{2} & \sigma _{cF,t}\\ \\[-8pt] \sigma _{cF_{i},t} & \sigma _{F,t}^{2}\end {array} \right ) \end{equation*}

We follow Bollerslev et al. (Reference Bollerslev, Engle and Wooldridge1988) who proposed a general model for estimating the conditional covariance matrix $\Omega _{t}$ termed VEC model. The VEC(1,1) model is given by

\begin{equation*} h_{t}=\Gamma +A\xi _{t-1}+Bh_{t-1}\end{equation*}

where

\begin{equation*} h_{t}=\text{vech}\!\left ( \Omega _{t}\right ) =\left ( \begin {array} [c]{c}\sigma _{c,t}^{2}\\ \\[-8pt] \sigma _{cF,t}\\ \\[-8pt] \sigma _{F,t}^{2}\end {array} \right ), \end{equation*}
\begin{equation*} \xi _{t}=\text{vech}\!\left ( \varepsilon _{t}\varepsilon _{t}^{\prime }\right ), \end{equation*}

where $\varepsilon _{t}= ( \varepsilon _{_{c,t}},\varepsilon _{_{F,t}} ) ^{\prime }$ , $\text{vech} (. )$ is an operator that that stacks the lower triangular part of a $N\times N$ matrix, and the sizes of $\Gamma$ , $A$ and $B$ are $\frac{N\left ( N+1\right ) }{2}$ dimensional constant vectors. The total number of parameters is $2\left ( \frac{N\left ( N+1\right ) }{2}\right ) ^{2}+\frac{N\left ( N+1\right ) }{2}$ . In our case with $N=2$ , the total number of parameters is $21$ .

To reduce the number of parameters in the VEC model, Bollerslev et al. (Reference Bollerslev, Engle and Wooldridge1988) suggest the diagonal VEC (DVEC) model where $A$ and $B$ are restricted to be diagonal matrices. The resulting restricted model comprehend $\frac{3N\left ( N+1\right ) }{2}$ parameters. That is for $N=2$ , the total number of parameters is $9$ .

The DVEC model can be rewritten as

\begin{equation*} \Omega _{t}=\overline {\Gamma }+\overline {A}\odot \left ( \varepsilon _{t-1}\varepsilon _{t-1}^{\prime }\right ) +\overline {B}\odot \Omega _{t-1}\end{equation*}

where $\odot$ is the Hadamard product (element by element product) and $\overline{\Gamma },\overline{A}$ and $\overline{B}$ are $N\times N$ matrices given by

\begin{align*} \Gamma & =\text{diag}(\text{vech}\!\left ( \overline{\Gamma }\right )\!),\\ \\[-8pt] A & =\text{diag}(\text{vech}\!\left ( \overline{A}\right ) \!),\\ \\[-8pt] B & =\text{diag}(\text{vech}\!\left ( \overline{B}\right )\! ), \end{align*}

where $\overline{A}$ and $\overline{B}$ are diagonal matrices.

We estimate the model by quasi-maximum likelihood estimator. We use bootstrapped t-statistics and p-values for coefficients significance.

Appendix C: Descriptive statistics of sentiment and risk factors

Table 10. Descriptive statistics of sentiment and risk factors

Appendix D: Robustness tests for calibrated depreciation rates: $\delta =0.1$ OR $\delta =0.17$

Table 11. Tests of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.1$

Table 12. Tests of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.17$

Footnotes

We appreciate helpful comments from Nina Boyarchenko, Walter Pohl, Guihai Zhao, Leonidas Zelmanovitz, Kenneth L. Judd, the seminar participants at the Stanford University SITE workshop, the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, the Conference on Behavioral Aspects of Macroeconomics, the House of Finance, Frankfurt am Main, the annual meetings of the Society of Economics of the Household, and the Southern Economic Association Conference. All remaining errors are our own.

1 Other indicators include the Bank of England Systematic Risk Survey and The Bloomberg Consumer Comfort Index.

2 Other papers that have incorporated the role of sentiment in a recursive utility framework include Hansen (Reference Hansen2010, Reference Hansen2012).

3 On a different note, there is an alternative strand of literature that looks at sentiments in frameworks that do not incorporate recursive preferences in optimal decisions or issues related to long-run risks (Bloom (Reference Bloom2009); Angeletos and La’O (Reference Angeletos and La’O2013); Miao et al. (Reference Miao, Wang and Xu2015); Milani (Reference Milani2017)).

4 A decision maker may prefer a late resolution of uncertainty or an earlier resolution of uncertainty as a result of his/her attitudes towards the correlation of payoffs across periods—long-run uncertainty (Duffie and Epstein (Reference Duffie and Epstein1992)).

5 This statistical technique was first used in the Quantum Chemistry literature, and recently it has found application in asset pricing and finance (Klein and Chow (Reference Klein and Chow2013); Bessler et al. (Reference Bessler, Kurmann and Tom2015)).

6 It is worth noting that the rate of time preference is constant, that is $-f_{J}(c,J)=\beta .$

7 When $\gamma =0$, this aggregator becomes $f(x,J)=(1+\alpha J)\left [ log(x)-\frac{\beta }{\alpha }log(1+\alpha J)\right ]$.

8 There is a connection between preferences for the timing of resolution of uncertainty and preferences for information (Skiadas (Reference Skiadas1998)).

9 The estimated factors are mutually orthogonal by construction.

10 To be clear, we use a two-step method of estimation. In the first step, we estimate the factors (sentiment factors). In the second and final step, the latent factor variables are fixed at their estimated values from the first step, so that only the preferences parameters and value function of the structural model are estimated in the second step. In doing so the value function is endogenously estimated as a function of latent factors.

11 Data on real personal consumption expenditures of services and nondurable goods are from St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank website: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/PCESC96 https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/PCENDC96 https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/RKNANPUSA666NRUG

12 Data on civilian population are from St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank website: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/CNP16OV

14 See For more information, see Penn World Table 8.1 at https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/productivity/pwt/pwt-releases/pwt8.1?lang=en

16 The database is available at: https://data.sca.isr.umich.edu/subset/subset.php

17 In estimating the latent factors, we used an index instead of one subindex for sentiment because the latter will represent only a subgroup of elements affecting the consumer sentiment. In the survey, there are indicators related to consumer perceptions about his/her financial conditions and indicators related to consumer perceptions about the global business conditions in the country and the world. Furthermore, there are also perception indicators about the business conditions in the short and long run. All these indicators, when taken separately, affect sentiment differently. Considering a subindex may miss some essential features affecting sentiment about future prospects of the economy. Estimating a common factor that combines all these indicators is the only fundamental that better captures the actual state of the consumer sentiment.

18 The sequential approach assumes some (arbitrary) ordering of the explanatory variables where the first variable remains unchanged, and the remaining variables are selected sequentially. In contrast, the democratic orthogonalization approach treats all variables symmetrically.

19 The Frobenius norm is an example of these norms.

20 The democratic decomposition in contrasts to the sequential orthogonalization approach is independent of the ordering of the variables. It considers the entire set of vector data in one go.

References

Acemoglu, D. and Scott, A. (1994) Consumer confidence and rational expectations: Are agents’ beliefs consistent with the theory? Economic Journal 104(422), 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aiken, J., Erdos, J. and Goldstein, J. (1980) On Löwdin orthogonalization. International Journal of Quantum Chemistry 18(4), 11011108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akaike, H. (1974) A new look at the statistical model identification. IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control 19(6), 716723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angeletos, G.-M. and La’O, J. (2013) Sentiments. Econometrica 81(2), 739779.Google Scholar
Bai, J. and Ng, S. (2002) Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Econometrica 70(1), 191222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bali, T. and Engle, R. (2010) The intertemporal capital asset pricing model with dynamic conditional correlations. Journal of Monetary Economics 57(4), 377390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bansal, R. and Yaron, A. (2004) Risks for the long run: A potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. The Journal of Finance 59(4), 14811509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. (1994) What the fed can’t do. The Wall Street Journal. http://marshallinside.usc.edu/joines/549/articles_pdf/wsj940819.txt.pdf.Google Scholar
Basu, S., Fernald, J. and Kimball, M. (2006) Are technology improvements contractionary? American Economic Review 96(5), 14181448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, J. and Spiegel, M. (2018) Sentiments and economic activity: Evidence from US states. The Economic Journal 129(618), 715733.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, A. (1983) Gaussian estimation of structural parameters in higher-order continuous time dynamic models. Econometrica 51(1), 117152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, B. S. and Boivin, J. (2003) Monetary policy in a data rich environment. Journal of Monetary Economics 50(3), 525546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, S., Boivin, J. and Eliasz, P. (2005) Measuring the effects of monetary policy: A factor-augmented vector autoregressive (FAVAR) approach. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, 387422.Google Scholar
Bessler, W., Kurmann, P., Tom, T. and Nohel (2015) Time-varying systematic and idiosyncratic risk exposures of {US} bank holding companies. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 35, 4568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biolsi, C. and Du, B. (2020) Do shocks to animal spirits cause output fluctuations? Southern Economic Journal 87(1), 331368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, N. (2009) The impact of uncertainty shocks. Econometrica 77(3), 623685.Google Scholar
Boivin, J. and Giannoni, M. (2006) DSGE Models in a Data-Rich Environment. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 12772.Google Scholar
Bollerslev, T., Engle, R. and Wooldridge, J. (1988) A capital asset pricing model with time-varying covariances. Journal of Political Economy 96(1), 116131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boot, J., Feibes, W. and Lisman, J. (1967) Further methods of derivation of quarterly figures from annual data. Applied Statistics 16(1), 6575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouaddi, M. and Taamouti, A. (2012) Portfolio risk management in a data-rich environment. Financial Markets and Portfolio Management 26(4), 469494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouaddi, M. and Taamouti, A. (2013) Portfolio selection in a data-rich environment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(12), 29432962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bram, J. and Ludvigson, S. (1998) Does consumer confidence forecast household expenditure? A sentiment index horse race. Economic Policy Review 4, 5978.Google Scholar
Chan, W. (1993) Disaggregation of annual time-series data to quarterly figures: A comparative study. Journal of Forecasting 12, 677688.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, X., Favilukis, J. and Ludvigson, S. (2013) An estimation of economic models with recursive preferences. Quantitative Economics 4(1), 3983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochrane, J. (2005) Financial Markets and the Real Economy. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., NBER Working Papers 11193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochrane, J. (2017) Macro-finance. Review of Finance 21(3), 945985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Curtin, R. (2007) Consumer sentiment surveys: Worldwide review and assessment. Journal of Business Cycle Measurement and Analysis 7, 20072042.Google Scholar
Dejong, D., Ingram, B. and Whiteman, C. (2000) Keynesian impulses versus solow residuals: Identifying sources of business cycle fluctuations. Journal of Applied Econometrics 15, 311329.3.0.CO;2-L>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denton, F. T. (1971) Adjustment of monthly or quarterly series to annual totals: An approach based on quadratic minimization. Journal of the American Statistical Association 66(333), 99102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dominitz, J. and Manski, F. (2004) How should we measure consumer confidence? Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2), 5166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Driscoll, J. and Holden, S. (2014) Behavioral economics and macroeconomic models. Journal of Macroeconomics 41, 133147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffie, D. and Epstein, L. (1992) Stochastic differential utility. Econometrica 60(2), 353394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engle, R. (2002) Dynamic conditional correlation: A simple class of multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20(3), 339350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, L., Farhi, E. and Strzalecki, T. (2014) How much would you pay to resolve long-run risk? American Economic Review 104(9), 26802697.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, L. and Zin, S. (1989) Substitution, risk aversion and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: A theoretical framework. Econometrica 57(4), 937969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ericson, K. and Fuster, A. (2011) Expectations as endowments: Reference-dependent preferences and exchange behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(4), 18791907.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Favero, C., Marcellino, M. and Neglia, F. (2005) Principal components at work: The empirical analysis of monetary policy with large data sets. Journal of Applied Econometrics 20, 603620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feijoo, S., Caro, A. and Quintana, D. (2003) Methods for quarterly disaggregation without indicators; A comparative study using simulation. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis 43(1), 6378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernald, J. (2014). A Quarterly, Utilization-Adjusted Series on Total Factor Productivity. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Working Paper Series 2012-19.Google Scholar
Fernald, J. and Matoba, K. (2009) Growth accounting, potential output, and the current recession. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Letter, 2009--26. Below is the link to the article. https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2009/august/growth-accounting-output-recession/.Google Scholar
Forni, M., Giannone, D., Lippi, M. and Reichlin, L. (2009) Opening the black box: Structural factor models with large cross sections. Econometric Theory 25(5), 13191347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gomme, P. and Rupert, P. (2007) Theory, measurement and calibration of macroeconomic models. Journal of Monetary Economics 54(2), 460497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z. and Huffman, G. (1988) Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle. The American Economic Review 78, 402417.Google Scholar
Hansen, L. (2010). Recursive Valuation and Sentiments, Bendheim lectures, Princeton University, princeton Bendheim Lectures in Finance: Exploring Links Between Asset Pricing and Macroeconomic Modeling. http://home.uchicago.edu/lhansen/princeton1.pdf.Google Scholar
Hansen, L. (2012) Dynamic valuation decomposition within stochastic economies. Econometrica 80(3), 911967.Google Scholar
Hansen, L., Heaton, J. and Li, N. (2008) Consumption strikes back? Measuring long-run risk. Journal of Political Economy 116(2), 260302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kakeu, J. and Bouaddi, M. (2017) Empirical evidence of news about future prospects in the risk-pricing of oil assets. Energy Economics 64, 458468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kakeu, J. and Byron, S. (2016) Optimistic about the future? How uncertainty and expectations about future consumption prospects affect optimal consumer behavior. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 16, 171192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaltenbrunner, G. and Lochstoer, L. (2010) Long-run risk through consumption smoothing. Review of Financial Studies 23(8), 31903224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, R. and Chow, V. (2013) Orthogonalized factors and systematic risk decomposition. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 53(2), 175187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koopmans, T. (1960) Stationary ordinal utility and impatience. Econometrica 28(2), 287309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. and Porteus, E. (1978) Temporal resolution of uncertainty and dynamic choice theory. Econometrica 46(1), 185200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydland, F. and Prescott, E. (1982) Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50(6), 13451370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lau, S. and Ng, P. (2007) Loglinear approximate solutions to real-business-cycle models: Some observations. The Journal of Economic Education 38(2), 194207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ljungqvist, L. and Sargent, T. (2004) Recursive Macroeconomic Theory. 2nd edition, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Löwdin, P. (1970) On the nonorthogonality problem. Advances in Quantum Chemistry 5, 185199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R. (1980) Methods and problems in business cycle theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 12, 696715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ludvigson, S. (2004) Consumer confidence and consumer spending. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(2), 2950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ludvigson, S. and Ng, S. (2009) Macro factors in bond risk premia. Review of Financial Studies 22(12), 50275067.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehra, R. and Prescott, E. (1985) The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics 15(2), 145161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miao, J., Wang, P. and Xu, Z. (2015) A Bayesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of stock market bubbles and business cycles. Quantitative Economics 6(3), 599635.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milani, F. (2017) Sentiment and the U.S. business cycle. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 82, 289311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowman, K. (1997) Gaussian estimation of single-factor continuous time models of the term structure of interest rates. The Journal of Finance 52(4), 16951706.Google Scholar
Pan, W. (2020) How does the macroeconomy respond to stock market fluctuations? The role of sentiment. Macroeconomic Dynamics 24(2), 421446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. (1927) Industrial Fluctuations. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Restoy, F. and Weil, P. (2011) Approximate equilibrium asset prices. Review of Finance 15(1), 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salamaliki, P. and Venetis, I. (2019) Transmission chains of economic uncertainty on macroeconomic activity: New empirical evidence. Macroeconomic Dynamics 23(8), 33553385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sargent, T. (2007) Long-run risks and financial markets. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 89, 301304.Google Scholar
Schroder, M. and Skiadas, C. (1999) Optimal consumption and portfolio selection with stochastic differential utility. Journal of Economic Theory 89(1), 68126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schweinler, H. and Wigner, E. (1970) Orthogonalization methods. Journal of Mathematical Physics 11(5), 16931694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skiadas, C. (1998) Recursive utility and preferences for information. Journal Economic Theory 12(2), 293312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skiadas, C. (2007) Chapter 19 dynamic portfolio choice and risk aversion. In: John R. Birge and V. Linetsky (eds.), Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, vol. 15, pp. 789–843. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Srivastava, V. (2000) A unified view of the orthogonalization methods. Journal of Physics A: Mathematical and General 33(35), 62196222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strzalecki, T. (2013) Temporal resolution of uncertainty and recursive models of ambiguity aversion. Econometrica 81(3), 10391074.Google Scholar
Swanson, E. (2012) Risk aversion and the labor margin in dynamic equilibrium models. American Economic Review 102(4), 16631691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thimme, J. (2017) Intertemporal substitution in consumption: A literature review. Journal of Economic Surveys 31(1), 226257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhao, G. (2017) Confidence, bond risks, and equity returns. Journal of Financial Economics 126(3), 668688.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Consumption per capita growth rate.

Figure 1

Table 1. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20)

Figure 2

Table 2. Correlation between sentiment about the future and risk factors

Figure 3

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of the sentiment impact, the short-run risk impact, the long-run risk impact, and the macro-risk impact

Figure 4

Figure 2. Sentiment impacts from 1980 to 2014.

Figure 5

Figure 3. Macroeconomic risk impacts from 1980 to 2014.

Figure 6

Figure 4 Long-run risk impacts from 1980 to 2014.

Figure 7

Figure 5. Short-run risk impacts from 1980 to 2014.

Figure 8

Table 4. Parameters estimation with the standard time-additive expected utility model

Figure 9

Table 5. Akaike (1974) information criterion (AIC) for recursive utility and time-additive utiliy

Figure 10

Table 6. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20) when $\delta =0.17$

Figure 11

Table 7. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20) when $\delta =0.1$

Figure 12

Table 8. Estimation of preference parameters of the model equation (20) when $\delta =0.03$

Figure 13

Table 9. Tests of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.03$

Figure 14

Figure 6. Density distribution of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.03$. For two other alternative values, see Figures 7 and 8.

Figure 15

Figure 7. Density distribution of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.1$.

Figure 16

Figure 8. Density distribution of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.17$.

Figure 17

Table 10. Descriptive statistics of sentiment and risk factors

Figure 18

Table 11. Tests of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.1$

Figure 19

Table 12. Tests of the difference between the consumption growth rate implied by equation (20) (recursive utility) and the one implied by equation (45) (time additive utility), when $\delta =0.17$