Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-7drxs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-18T01:35:04.532Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Relevance for Present Economic Theory of Economic Theory Written in the Past

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

In order that this essay may be clear to the reader, some understandings about terminology must be established. First, if we speak of “theories that were formulated in the past,” ordinarily we mean to leave open the question of whether they are still valid, and if we speak of “past theories,” ordinarily we imply that they have been discarded and that implies that they were defective and were supplanted by current theories. Nevertheless, in this essay the latter term, used for the sake of brevity, will have the same meaning as the former expression. If a past theory is considered to be invalid, that will be staled explicitly.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1999

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Arrow, Kenneth J. and Gerard, Debreu. 1954. “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy.” Econometrica 22: 256–90.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Hahn, F. H.. 1971. General Competitive Analysis. San Francisco and Edinburgh: Holden-Day and Oliver and Boyd.Google Scholar
Barnett, William A., ed. 1977. Macroeconomic Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von. 1884. Capital and Interest, vol. 1: History and Critique of Interest Theories, translated by Huncke, George D. and Sennholz, Hans F.. South Holland, IL: Libertarian Press, 1959.Google Scholar
Caldwell, Bruce. 1997. “Hayek and Socialism.” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (12): 1856–90.Google Scholar
Caravale, Giovanni. 1991. “On the Role of Demand in Ricardo and Marshall.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 13 (Fall): 175–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caravale, Giovanni, ed. 1994. Equilibrio e Theoria Economica. Rome: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Cesarano, F. 1983. “On the Role of the History of Economic Analysis.” History of Political Economy 15: 63–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamberlin, E. H. 1933. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chamberlin, E. H. 1953. “The Product as an Economic Variable.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 67 (02): 1–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clower, Robert W. and Peter, Howitt. 1966. “Taking Markets Seriously: Groundwork for a Post Walrasian Macroeconomics.” In David, Colander, ed., Beyond Microfoundations: Post Walrasian Macroeconomics. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 21–38.Google Scholar
Cournot, Antoine-Augustin. 1838. Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses. Paris: Hachette.Google Scholar
Dimand, Robert. 1998. “The Fall and Rise of Irving Fisher's Macroeconomics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20 (06): 191–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. 1891. “The Objects and Methods of Political Economy.” Reprinted in his Papers Relating to Political Economy, 1. New York: Burt Franklin, 3–12.Google Scholar
Fetter, Frank. 1965. “The Relation of the History of Economic Thought to Economic History.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 55 (05): 137–42.Google Scholar
Fisher, Franklin. 1983. Disequilibrium Foundations of Equilibrium Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1932. Booms and Depressions. New York: Adelphi.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1936. “The Depression, Its Causes and Cures.” Abstracts of Papers Presented at the Research Conference on Economics and Statistics Held by the Cowles Commission Research in Economics. Colorado College Publication, General Series no. 28, Study Series no. 21, Colorado College, Colorado Springs, 104–20.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1990. “Sraffa: Classical versus Marginalist Analysis.” In Bharadwaj, K. and Schefold, B., eds., Essays on Piero Sraffa. London: Unwin Hyman, 112–44.Google Scholar
Gordon, Donald F. 1965. “The Role of the History of Economic Thought in the Understanding of Modern Economic Theory.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 55 (05): 119–27.Google Scholar
Haberler, Gottfried. 1937. Prosperity and Depression: A Theoretical Analysis of Cyclical Movements, 3rd ed. Lake Success, New York: United Nations, 1946.Google Scholar
Hahn, Frank H. and Takashi, Negishi. 1962. “A Theorem on Non-Tâtonnement Stability.” Econometrica 30: 463–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1937a. Letter to Keynes, J. M., 04 9. In The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, 14. London and Basingstoke: Macmillan, St. Martin's Press for the Royal Economic Society, 1973.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1937b. “Mr. Keynes and the ‘Classics’; A Suggested Interpretation.” Econometrica 5 (04): 147–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1939. Value and Capital. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1976. “‘Revolutions’ in Economics.” In Latsis, S., ed., Method and Appraisal in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hildenbrand, W. and Kirman, A. P.. 1988. Equilibrium Analysis: Variations on Themes by Edgeworth and Walras. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. 1953. A Review of Economic Doctrines. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hynes, J. Allan. 1998. “The Emergence of the Neoclassical Consumption Function: The Formative Years, 1940–1952.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20 (Spring): 25–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1930. A Treatise on Money, vol 1: The Pure Theory of Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1922/1933. “Robert Malthus, 1766–1835, the First of the Cambridge Economists.” In Keynes 1933; and with the title “Thomas Robert Malthus” in Keynes 1972, 10, 71–103.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1933. Essays in Biography. Reprinted with additional biographies in 1951, in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, 10. London and Basingstoke: Macmillan, St. Martin's Press for the Royal Economic Society, 1972.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1937. “The General Theory of Employment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 51 (02): 209–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Lawrence R. 1947. The Keynesian Revolution. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1937. “Unemployment: And Mr. Keynes's Revolution in Economic Theory.” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 3 (02): 100–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leijonhufvud, Axel. 1997. “The Wicksellian Heritage.” Economic Notes 26(1): 1–9.Google Scholar
Lerner, Abba. 1940. “Some Swedish Stepping Stones in Economic Theory.” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 6 (11): 574–91.Google Scholar
Lewin, Shira B. 1996. “Economics and Psychology: Lessons for Our Own Day from the Early Twentieth Century.” Journal of Economic Literature 34 (09): 1293–323.Google Scholar
Magnusson, Lars, ed. 1993. Mercantilist Economics. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Marget, Arthur W. 1938–1942. The Theory of Prices. A Re-Examination of the Central Problems of Monetary Theory, 2 vols. Reprint, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1966.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. London and New York: Macmillan and Co.; 8th ed., New York: Macmillan Company, 1920.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
McCulloch, John R. 1845. The Literature of Political Economy, A Classified Catalogue of Select Publications in the Different Departments of that Science. London: Longman, Brown, Green, and Longmans.Google Scholar
Modigliani, Franco. 1944. “Liquidity Preference and the Theory of Interest and Money.” Econometrica 12 (01): 45–88.Google Scholar
Pack, Spencer J. 1997. “Adam Smith on the Virtues: A Partial Resolution of the Adam Smith Problem.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19 (Spring): 127–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1896/1897. Cours d'économie politique, 2 vols., RougeLausanne, F. Lausanne, F.; edited by Bousquet, G.-H. and Busino, G.. Geneva: Librairie Droz, 1964.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo. 1909. Manuel d'économie politique. Paris: V. Giard and E. Brière.Google Scholar
Prychitko, David L., ed. 1977. Why Economists Disagree: An Introduction to the Alternative Schools of Thought. Ithaca: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Robertson, Dennis H. 1926. Banking Policy and the Price Level. London: P. S. King and Son.Google Scholar
Robertson, Dennis H. 1935. Letter to J. M. Keynes, February 3. In The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, 13. London and Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Robinson, Joan. 1933. The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, Alessandro. 1996. “Why Should Economists Study the History of Economic Thought?” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 3 (Summer): 296–309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sabooglu, Müfit. 1996. “Hayek and Spontaneous Orders.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 18: 347–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. 1988. “Schumpeter's Treatment of Samuelson.” History of Economics Society Bulletin 10 (Spring): 25–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1987. “Out of the Closet: A Program for the Whig History of Economic Science.” History of Economic Society Bulletin 9 (Fall): 51–60.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Spray, David E., ed. 1964. The Principal Stock Exchanges of the World; Their Operation, Structure and Development. Washington, DC: International Economic Publishers.Google Scholar
Stern, Steven. 1997. “Simulation-Based Estimation.” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (12): 2 006–39.Google Scholar
Swartz, Thomas R. and Bonello, Frank J.. 1997. Taking Sides. Clashing Views on Controversial Economic Issues, 8th ed. Guilford, CT: Dushkin/McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Walker, Donald A. 1986. “Keynes as a Historian of Economic Thought: The Perspectives of the General Theory.” Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 4: 1–36.Google Scholar
Walker, Donald A. 1988. “Ten Major Problems in the Study of the History of Economic Thought.” History of Economics Society Bulletin 10 (Fall): 99–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, Donald A. 1997. Advances in General Equilibrium Theory. Cheltenham, UK and Lyme, US: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1874. Eléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale, L. Corbaz, Lausanne; Guillaumin, Paris; Georg, Bâle.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1881. “Théorie mathématique du bimétallisme.” Journal des Economistes, Revue de la Science Economique et de la Statistique, 4th series, 14 (no. 41, 05): 189–99.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1889. Eléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale, 2d ed., F. Rouge, Lausanne; Guillaumin, Paris; Dunker & Humbolt, Leipzig.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1900. Eléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale, 4th ed. Lausanne and Paris: F. Rouge and R. Pichon.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1905. “Cournot et l'économie mathématique.” Gazette de Lausanne, 13 07, and in Walras 1987, pp. 461–66.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1965. Correspondence of Léon Walras and Related Papers, 3 vols., edited by William, Jaffé. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1987. Mélanges d'économie politique et sociale, in Auguste and Léon Walras, Œuvres économique complètes, 7, prepared by Claude Hébert and Jean-Pierre Potier. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1988. Eléments d'économie politique pure ou Théorie de la richesse sociale, comparative edition prepared by Claude Mouchot, in Auguste and Léon Walras, Œuvres économiques complètes, 8, Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. 1898. Geldzins und Güterpreise: Eine Studie über die den Tauschwert des Geldes Bestimmenden Urasachen. Jena: Gustave Fischer Verlag.Google Scholar