Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-gvh9x Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-16T10:51:53.894Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The “Alternative” Theories of Knight and Coase, and the Modern Theory of the Firm

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

In his contribution to the 1987 conference that celebrated the fiftieth anniversary of Ronald Coase's “The Nature of the Firm” (1937), Harold Demsetz noted that from the birth of modern economics to 1970, “only two works seem to have been written about the theory of the firm that have altered the perspectives of the profession: Knight's Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit (1921) and Coase's ‘The Nature of the Firm’” (Demsetz 1993, in Williamson and Winter 1993, p. 159). It is easy to feel uncomfortable with this observation. First, Coase's article was ignored for decades. Second, Knight's book did not receive much attention because of its theory of economic organization, but because of its statement of the theory of perfect competition (Stigler 1957; Machovec 1995), its distinction between risk and uncertainty, and its theory of profits (see, e.g., Boulding 1942 and Papandreou 1952).'

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1996

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Alchian, A. A. and Demsetz, H.. 1972. “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization,” in Alchian, A. A., Economic Forces at Work, Liberty Press, Indianapolis, 1977.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. 1987. “Knight's ‘Moral Hazard’ Theory of Organization,” Economic Inquiry, 117–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, K. E. 1942. “The Theory of the Firm in the Last Ten Years,” American Economic Review, 32, 791–802.Google Scholar
Brynjolfsson, E. 1994. “Information Assets, Technology and Organization,” Management Science, 40, 1645–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boudreaux, D. J. and Holcombe, R. G.. 1989. “The Coasian and Knightian Theories of the Firm,” Managerial and Decision Economics, 10, 147–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and di Pierro, A.. 1980. “Cognition, Choice, and Entrepreneurship,” Economic Inquiry, 18, 693–701.Google Scholar
Casson, M. 1982. The Entrepreneur, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Caldwell, B. 1988. “Hayek's Transformation,” History of Political Economy, 20, 513–42.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4, 386–405. Pagination in the text is that of the reprint in Williamson and Winter 1993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1993a. “The Nature of the Firm: Meaning,” in Williamson and Winter 1993.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1993b. “The Nature of the Firm: Influence,” in Williamson and Winter 1993.Google Scholar
Conner, K. R. and Prahalad, C. K.. 1996. “A Resource-Based Theory of the Firm: Knowledge vs. Opportunism,” Organization Science, forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, H. 1988. “Profit as a Functional Return: Reconsidering Knight's View,” in his Ownership, Control, and the Firm, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1988.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. 1993. “The Theory of the Firm Revisited,” in Williamson and Winter 1993.Google Scholar
Dosi, G., Teece, D. J. and Winter, S. G.. 1992. “Towards a Theory of Corporate Coherence,” in Dosi, G., Giannetti, R. and Toninelli, P. A., eds., Technology and Enterprise in a Historical Perspective, Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1992.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. 1993a. “The Theory of the Firm: Contractual and Competence Perspectives,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 5, 127–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. 1993b. “More on Knight and the Theory of the Firm,” Managerial and Decision Economics, 14, 269–76.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. 1994. “The Two Coasian Traditions,” Review of Political Economy, 6, 37–61.Google Scholar
Grossman, S. and Hart, O.. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” Journal of Political Economy, 24, 691–719.Google Scholar
Gunning, J. P. 1993. “Entrepreneurists and Firmists: Knight vs. the Modern Theory of the Firm,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 15, 31–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heiner, R. 1983. “The Origin of Predictable Behavior,” American Economic Review, 73, 560–95.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B. and Tirole, J.. 1989. “The Theory of the Firm,” in Schmalensee, R. and Willig, R. D., eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Kihlstrom, R. E. and Laffont, J. J.. 1979. “A General Equilibrium Entrepreneurial Theory of Firm Formation Based on Risk Aversion,” reprinted in Casson, M., ed., Entrepreneurship, Edward Elgar, Alder-reprinted in Casson, M., ed., Entrepreneurship, Edward Elgar, Aldershot, 1990.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Kirzner, I. M. 1979. Perception, Opportunity, and Profit, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit; reprint, Augustus M. Kelley, New York, 1964.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. 1992. “Transaction Cost Economics in Real Time,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 1, 99–127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, R. N. and Cosgel, M.. 1993. “Frank Knight on Risk, Uncertainty, and the Firm: A New Interpretation,” Economic Inquiry, 31, 456–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LeRoy, S. F. and Singell, L. D.. 1987. “Knight on Risk and Uncertainty,” Journal of Political Economy, 95, 394–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loasby, B. J. 1976. Choice, Complexity, and Ignorance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Machovec, F. M. 1995. Perfect Competition and the Transformation of Economics, Routledge, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKinney, J. 1977. “Frank H. Knight on Uncertainty and Rational Action,” Southern Economic Journal, 43, 1438–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minkler, A. P. 1993. “The Problem with Dispersed Knowledge: Firms in Theory and Practice,” Kyklos, 46, 569–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. G.. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Belknap Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Papandreou, A. G. 1952. “Some Basic Problems in the Theory of the Firm,” in Haley, B. F., ed., A Survey of Contemporary Economics, Richard D. Irwin, Homewood, 1952.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. 1958. Personal Knowledge, Chicago University Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Popper, K. R. 1957. The Poverty of Historicism, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London.Google Scholar
Prahalad, C. K. and Hamel, G.. 1990. “The Core Competence of the Corporation,” Harvard Business Review, 68, 79–91.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. 1972. Epistemics and Economics, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1957. “Perfect Competition, Historically Contemplated”; reprinted in his Essays in the History of Economics, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1965.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies, Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. and Winter, S. G.. 1993. The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar