Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-m9pkr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-10T16:33:23.409Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

No Taxation without Efficiency? Elite Perceptions of Redistribution and Progressivity in Chile

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 October 2022

Jorge Atria*
Affiliation:
Department of Sociology, Universidad Diego Portales / Centre for Social Conflict and Cohesion Studies (COES)
*
*Corresponding author. Email: jorge.atria@mail.udp.cl

Abstract

Even though a vast literature has addressed perceptions and beliefs on taxes, progressivity and redistribution, few studies have specifically studied the perceptions of economic elites in this regard. This group is relevant for its affluence and influence, and therefore elites’ ideas and preferences have a major impact on tax-policy configuration. This study analyses the perceptions of the economic elite on redistribution and progressivity in Chile. Based on in-depth interviews and historical documents, such notions are examined by mixing concrete evaluations of income tax and value-added tax (VAT) and more general attitudes towards the role of the tax system in economic development. Results show that redistribution is negatively evaluated, which coexists with a strong willingness to contribute to poverty relief through social initiatives outside the state. Additionally, progressivity is sidelined while highlighting growth, tax neutrality, and incentives to entrepreneurship as the main priorities of tax design. The historical analysis shows that although the Chilean tax regime has always been based on indirect taxes and levies on natural resources, neoliberal reforms and ideological renovation during the Pinochet dictatorship narrowed the general framework of tax ideas among business and political sectors and reversed progressive advances in inequality reduction and direct taxation that had been made during the previous decades.

¿sin eficiencia no hay impuestos? percepciones de la elite sobre redistribución y progresividad en chile: spanish abstract

¿Sin eficiencia no hay impuestos? Percepciones de la elite sobre redistribución y progresividad en Chile: Spanish abstract

Aun cuando una vasta literatura se ha referido a las percepciones y creencias sobre los impuestos, la progresividad y la redistribución, pocos estudios han analizado específicamente las percepciones de las elites económicas al respecto. Este grupo es relevante por su afluencia e influencia y, por lo tanto, las ideas de las elites y sus preferencias tienen un gran impacto en la configuración de la política tributaria. Este estudio analiza las percepciones de la elite económica sobre redistribución y progresividad en Chile. En base a entrevistas a profundidad y documentos históricos, dichas nociones son examinadas combinando evaluaciones concretas del impuesto sobre la renta y el impuesto sobre el valor añadido (IVA) con actitudes más generales acerca del papel del sistema impositivo en el desarrollo económico. Los resultados muestran que la redistribución es evaluada negativamente, lo que coexiste con un fuerte deseo de contribuir al alivio de la pobreza a través de iniciativas sociales fuera del Estado. Adicionalmente, la progresividad es débilmente considerada mientras se subraya el crecimiento, la neutralidad impositiva y los incentivos a las empresas como las prioridades principales del diseño tributario. El análisis histórico muestra que aunque el régimen impositivo chileno siempre ha estado basado en impuestos indirectos y gravámenes sobre los recursos naturales, las reformas neoliberales y la renovación ideológica durante la dictadura de Pinochet disminuyeron el marco general de ideas sobre impuestos dentro de los sectores empresariales y políticos y revirtieron avances progresistas relacionados con la reducción de desigualdad y el establecimiento de impuestos directos que se habían hecho durante las décadas previas.

Sem eficiência, sem taxação? percepções da elite sobre redistribuição e progressividade no chile: portuguese abstract

Sem eficiência, sem taxação? Percepções da elite sobre redistribuição e progressividade no Chile: Portuguese abstract

Embora uma vasta literatura tenha abordado percepções e crenças sobre impostos, progressividade e redistribuição, poucos estudos estudaram especificamente as percepções das elites econômicas a esse respeito. Esse grupo é relevante por sua afluência e sua influência e, portanto, as ideias e preferências das elites têm grande impacto na configuração da política tributária. Este estudo analisa as percepções da elite econômica sobre redistribuição e progressividade no Chile. Com base em entrevistas em profundidade e documentos históricos, tais noções são examinadas misturando avaliações concretas de imposto de renda e imposto sobre o valor acrescentado (IVA) e atitudes mais gerais em relação ao papel do sistema tributário no desenvolvimento econômico. Os resultados mostram que a redistribuição é avaliada negativamente, o que coexiste com uma forte disposição de contribuir para o alívio da pobreza por meio de iniciativas sociais fora do estado. Além disso, a progressividade é deixada de lado, ao mesmo tempo em que destaca o crescimento, a neutralidade tributária e os incentivos ao empreendedorismo como as principais prioridades do desenho tributário. A análise histórica mostra que, embora o regime tributário chileno sempre tenha sido baseado em impostos indiretos e impostos sobre recursos naturais, as reformas neoliberais e a renovação ideológica durante a ditadura de Pinochet estreitaram o quadro geral de ideias tributárias entre setores empresariais e políticos e reverteram avanços progressivos em redução da desigualdade e tributação direta que haviam sido feitos durante as décadas anteriores.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Murphy, Liam and Nagel, Thomas, The Myth of Ownership: Taxes and Justice (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 In general, this article refers to income and not wealth.

3 The definition of tax progressivity is that the average tax rate paid – total amount of taxes paid divided by total income – increases with income.

4 Steinmo, Sven, ‘The Evolution of Policy Ideas: Tax Policy in the 20th Century’, British Journal of Politics and International Relations, 5: 2 (2003), pp. 206–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 See, for instance, Ondetti, Gabriel, ‘The Roots of Brazil's Heavy Taxation’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 47: 4 (2015), pp. 749–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Weber, Javier Rodríguez, ‘La erosión del poder de la élite en Chile entre 1913 y 1970: Una aproximación desde los ingresos del 1%’, Revista de Historia Económica, 35: 1 (2016), p. 72Google Scholar.

7 Sánchez-Ancochea, Diego, ‘The Political Economy of Inequality at the Top in Contemporary Chile’, in Bértola, Luis and Williamson, Jeffrey (eds.), Has Latin American Inequality Changed Direction? (Cham: Springer, 2017), p. 347Google Scholar.

8 Fairfield, Tasha, ‘Business Power and Tax Reform: Taxing Income and Profits in Chile and Argentina’, Latin American Politics and Society, 52: 2 (2010), pp. 5171CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 Khan, Shamus, ‘The Sociology of Elites’, Annual Review of Sociology, 38: 1 (2012), p. 362Google Scholar.

10 Mills, Charles W., The Power Elite (New York: Oxford University Press, 1980), p. 3Google Scholar.

11 Ibid., pp. 3–9.

12 Savage, Mike and Williams, Karel, ‘Elites: Remembered in Capitalism and Forgotten by Social Sciences’, in Savage, Mike and Williams, Karel (eds.), Remembering Elites (Oxford: Blackwell, 2008), pp. 124Google Scholar.

13 Harrington, Brooke, Capital without Borders: Wealth Management and the One Percent (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2016), pp. 37CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

15 American Political Science Association (APSA), ‘American Democracy in an Age of Rising Inequality’, Perspectives on Politics, 2: 4 (2004), pp. 651–66.

16 Elisa Reis, ‘Poverty in the Eyes of Brazilian Elites’, in Alice Amsden, Alisa Di Caprio and James Robinson (eds.), The Role of Elites in Economic Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2014), pp. 195–6.

17 Andrea Louise Campbell, ‘What Americans Think of Taxes’, in Isaac William Martin, Ajay K. Mehrotra and Monica Prasad (eds.), The New Fiscal Sociology: Taxation in Comparative and Historical Perspective (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009), p. 50.

18 Collier, Ruth, Paths toward Democracy: The Working Class and Elites in Western Europe and South America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999), pp. 1014CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 Dietrich Rueschemeyer, Evelyne Huber Stephens and John D. Stephens, Capitalist Development and Democracy (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1992), pp. 5–7.

20 Göran Therborn, ‘The Travail of Latin American Democracy’, New Left Review, 113–14 (Jan./April 1979), pp. 71–109.

21 Collier, Paths toward Democracy, p. 176.

22 Tasha Fairfield, ‘Structural Power in Comparative Political Economy: Perspectives from Policy Formulation in Latin America’, Business and Politics, 17: 3 (2015), pp. 411–41; Ben R. Schneider, ‘Business Politics in Latin America’, in David Coen, Wyn Grant and Graham Wilson (eds.), Oxford Handbook of Business and Government (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010), pp. 307–29.

23 Alesina, Alberto and Angeletos, George-Marios, ‘Fairness and Redistribution’, American Economic Review, 95: 4 (2005), pp. 960–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

24 Steinmo, ‘The Evolution of Policy Ideas’.

25 Edlund, Jonas, ‘Attitudes towards Taxation: Ignorant and Incoherent?’, Scandinavian Political Studies, 26: 2 (2003), pp. 145–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 Steinmo, Sven, Taxation and Democracy: Swedish, British and American Approaches to Financing the Modern State (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1993), p. 7Google Scholar.

27 Kim, Hansung and Lee, Yushin, ‘Socioeconomic Status, Perceived Inequality of Opportunity, and Attitudes toward Redistribution’, The Social Science Journal, 55: 3 (2018), pp. 300–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Rueda, David and Stegmueller, Daniel, ‘The Externalities of Inequality: Fear of Crime and Preferences for Redistribution in Western Europe’, American Journal of Political Science, 60: 2 (2016), pp. 472–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

29 Kim and Lee, ‘Socioeconomic Status’.

30 Sachweh, Patrick and Sthamer, Evelyn, ‘Why Do the Affluent Find Inequality Increasingly Unjust? Changing Inequality and Justice Perceptions in Germany, 1994–2014’, European Sociological Review, 35: 5 (2019), pp. 651–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Dimick, Matthew, Rueda, David and Stegmueller, Daniel, ‘The Altruistic Rich? Inequality and Other-Regarding Preferences for Redistribution’, Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 11: 4 (2016), pp. 385439CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32 Hennighausen, Tanja and Heinemann, Friedrich, ‘Don't Tax Me? Determinants of Individual Attitudes toward Progressive Taxation’, German Economic Review, 16: 3 (2014), pp. 255–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33 Kim and Lee, ‘Socioeconomic Status’.

34 Sachweh and Sthamer, ‘Why Do the Affluent’.

35 Rueda and Stegmueller, ‘The Externalities of Inequality’.

36 Dimick et al., ‘The Altruistic Rich?’

37 Hennighausen and Heinemann, ‘Don't Tax Me?’, p. 282.

38 Sidney Verba, Steven Kelman, Gary Orren, Ichiro Miyake, Joji Watanuki, Ikuo Kabashima and Donald Ferree, Elites and the Idea of Equality: A Comparison of Japan, Sweden, and the United States (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1987).

39 Benjamin I. Page, Larry M. Bartels and Jason Seawright, ‘Democracy and the Policy Preferences of Wealthy Americans’, Perspectives on Politics, 11: 1 (2013), pp. 51−73.

40 Naomi Hossain and Mick Moore, ‘So Near and yet So Far: Elites and Imagined Poverty in Bangladesh’, in Elisa Reis and Mick Moore (eds.), Elite Perceptions of Poverty and Inequality (London: Zed, 2005), pp. 91–126; Gerard Clark and Marites Sison, ‘Voices from the Top of the Pile: Elite Perceptions of Poverty and the Poor in the Philippines’, in Reis and Moore (eds.), Elite Perceptions, pp. 57–90.

41 Mireille Abelin, ‘Fiscal Sovereignty: Reconfigurations of Value and Citizenship in Post-Financial Crisis Argentina’, PhD diss., Columbia University, New York, 2012.

42 Aaron Schneider, State-Building and Tax Regimes in Central America (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2012).

43 Verba et al., Elites and the Idea of Equality, pp. 76–8; Page et al., ‘Democracy and the Policy Preferences’, pp. 61–2.

44 Elisa Reis and Mick Moore, ‘Elites, Perceptions and Poverties’, in Reis and Moore (eds.), Elite Perceptions, pp. 1–25.

45 Noushin Kalati and James Manor, ‘Elite Perceptions of Poverty and Poor People in South Africa’, in Reis and Moore (eds.), Elite Perceptions, p. 175.

46 Andrea Repetto, ‘Crecimiento, pobreza y desigualdad: La vía chilena’, Economía y Política, 3: 1 (2016), pp. 71−101.

47 Ignacio Flores, Claudia Sanhueza, Jorge Atria and Ricardo Mayer, ‘Top Incomes in Chile: A Historical Perspective on Income Inequality, 1964–2017’, Review of Income and Wealth, 66: 4 (2020), pp. 850–74; Tasha Fairfield and Michel Jorratt, ‘Top Income Shares, Business Profits, and Effective Tax Rates in Contemporary Chile’, Review of Income and Wealth, 62: 1 (2016), pp. 120–44.

48 Barbara Castelletti, ‘How Redistributive is Fiscal Policy in Latin America? The Case of Chile and Mexico’, Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) Development Centre Working Paper No. 318 (2013), p. 25. Fairfield and Jorratt show that average effective rates at the top reach, at most, 17.2 per cent. See Fairfield and Jorratt, ‘Top Income Shares’, p. 22.

49 Andrés Biehl and José Tomás Labarca, ‘Global Uncertainty in the Evolution of Latin American Income Taxes’, in Jorge Atria, Constantin Groll and Maria Valdes (eds.), Rethinking Taxation in Latin America: Reform and Challenges in Times of Uncertainty (Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, 2018), p. 106.

50 Biehl and Labarca, ‘Global Uncertainty’, pp. 106–8.

51 Tomás Undurraga, Divergencias: Trayectorias del neoliberalismo en Argentina y Chile (Santiago: Ediciones UDP, 2014).

52 Mauricio Casanova, ‘La centro-izquierda, el corporativismo empresarial y las contradicciones internas del Estado desarrollista en Chile, 1932–1954’, Izquierdas, 48 (Nov. 2019), p. 191.

53 Manuel Gárate, La revolución capitalista de Chile (1973–2003) (Santiago: Ediciones Universidad Alberto Hurtado, 2012), pp. 128–9.

54 Luis Ortega, ‘Las operaciones ideológicas y políticas en la construcción de un nuevo proyecto económico (y social) para Chile, 1950–1970’, Espacio Regional, 1: 11 (2014), p. 68. All translations by the author, unless otherwise stated.

55 Gárate, La revolución, p. 130.

56 José Tomás Labarca and Andrés Biehl, ‘Sociología fiscal de Chile, 1932–1973’, in Jorge Atria and Cristóbal Otero (eds.), Impuestos justos para el Chile que viene: Diagnósticos y desafíos tributarios para un nuevo pacto fiscal (Santiago: Fondo de Cultura Económica, 2021), pp. 177–202.

57 Cámara de Diputados, Sesión 57, 22 Jan. 1963, p. 4183.

58 Eduardo López, ‘Del malestar a la amenaza: La Sociedad de Fomento Fabril y el populismo ibañista, 1950–1953’, Izquierdas, 36 (Nov. 2017), pp. 28–54.

59 Magdalena Gil and Jorge Atria, ‘Fiscal Aftershocks: Taxes and Catastrophes in Chilean history’, Revista de Historia Económica – Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History, 40: 2 (2022), pp. 273−311.

60 Cámara de Diputados, Sesión 57, 22 Jan. 1963, p. 4189.

61 Andrés Zaldívar, ‘Fundamentos de la Renta Mínima Presunta’, Revista de Derecho Económico, 11–12 (1965), pp. 33–4.

62 Ibid., p. 38.

64 Undurraga, Divergencias, p. 169.

65 The Chicago Boys was a group of economists who introduced and institutionalised neoliberal principles with high levels of influence in state policy-making during the dictatorship. See Ortega, ‘Las operaciones’; Gárate, La revolución, p. 138.

66 Gárate, La revolución; Correa, Sofía, Con las riendas del poder: La derecha chilena en el siglo XX (Santiago: Editorial Sudamericana, 2004)Google Scholar.

67 Gárate, La revolución, p. 95.

68 López, ‘Del malestar a la amenaza’; Ortega, ‘Las operaciones’, p. 68.

69 Nazer, Ricardo, ‘La Corporación de Fomento a [sic] la Producción y la modernización económica de Chile, 1939–1970’, Revista de Gestión Pública, 5: 2 (2016), pp. 283316CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

70 Acuña, Gustavo, ‘Los organismos de planificación en Chile’, Finanzas Públicas, 2: 6 (1958), pp. 1232Google Scholar.

71 Casanova, ‘La centro-izquierda’.

72 Acuña, ‘Los organismos’, pp. 20–1.

73 Ministerio de Economía, Decreto n°1097, 4 Dec. 1946.

74 Labarca and Biehl, ‘Sociología fiscal’, p. 195.

75 Gárate, La revolución, p. 103.

76 Manuel Gárate, ‘La pedagogía monetarista: Difusión y debate de las nuevas ideas económicas en la revista Hoy, 1975–1979’, in José Ossandón and Eugenio Tironi (eds.), Adaptación: La empresa chilena después de Friedman (Santiago: Universidad Diego Portales, 2013); Timothy Clark, ‘The Paradox of the Neoliberal Developmentalist State: Reconstructing the Capitalist Elite in Pinochet's Chile’, in Liisa North and Timothy Clark (eds.), Dominant Elites in Latin America: From Neo-Liberalism to the ‘Pink Tide’ (Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, 2018), pp. 23–56.

77 Clark, ‘The Paradox’, p. 24.

78 Ibid., pp. 26–7.

79 Undurraga, Divergencias, pp. 256–68; Gárate, ‘La pedagogía monetarista’, p. 116.

80 Fourcade, Marion and Babb, Sarah, ‘The Rebirth of the Liberal Creed: Paths to Neoliberalism in Four Countries’, American Journal of Sociology, 108: 3 (2002), pp. 533−79Google Scholar; Undurraga, Tomás, ‘Transformaciones sociales y fuentes de poder del empresariado chileno (1975–2010)’, Ensayos de Economía, 22: 41 (2012), pp. 203–6Google Scholar.

81 Mario Marcel, ‘Diez años del IVA en Chile’, Colección de Estudios CIEPLAN [Corporación de Estudios para Latinoamérica], 19 (June 1986), pp. 83–134.

82 The VAT rate at its introduction was 20 per cent and the main exemptions were for passenger transportation, bank interest, a significant portion of insurance premiums, education, health, arms imports and exports. Although the original VAT established a single general rate, its design included a small set of additional rates and surcharges. See Marcel, ‘Diez años’.

83 Gabriel Palma and Mario Marcel, ‘Kaldor y el discreto encanto de la burguesía chilena’, Colección Estudios CIEPLAN, 28 (June 1990), pp. 85–120.

84 Hernán Cheyre, ‘Análisis de las reformas tributarias en la década 1974–1983’, Estudios Públicos, 21 (Summer 1986), pp. 1–48.

85 Michel Jorratt, ‘La tributación directa en Chile: Equidad y desafíos’, Serie Macroeconomía del Desarrollo CEPAL [Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe], 92 (Sept. 2009).

86 Integration means that corporate income taxes are credited against personal income taxes. The tax base determines when business profits are considered with the aim of paying personal income taxes. With an accrual tax base, business owners pay personal income taxes on all profits, regardless of whether they were distributed. With a distribution tax base, they pay taxes only on profits distributed to the owners. Thus, tax payments can be postponed on profits not distributed only with the latter tax base.

87 Claudio Agostini, Claudia Martínez and Barbara Flores, ‘Distributional Effects of Eliminating the Differential Tax Treatment of Business and Personal Income in Chile’, CEPAL Review, 108 (Dec. 2012), pp. 175–201.

88 Cheyre, ‘Análisis de las reformas’, p. 29.

89 Clark, ‘The Paradox’, p. 37.

90 Fairfield, ‘Business Power and Tax Reform’.

91 Boylan, Delia, ‘Taxation and Transition: The Politics of the 1990 Chilean Tax Reform’, Latin American Research Review, 31: 1 (1996), p. 10CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

92 The corporate tax rose from 20 per cent to either 25 or 27 per cent (two tax regimes were created, and companies had to choose one, with different requirements and benefits) and modified the Fondo Utilidad Tributario, or FUT (retained profits pending personal income taxation), a mechanism to promote business reinvestment. The top marginal income rate lowered from 40 to 35 per cent. See Ministerio de Hacienda, ‘Estudio del Banco Mundial sobre efectos de la Reforma Tributaria en la distribución del ingreso en Chile’, available online at www.hacienda.cl/documentos/reforma-tributaria/estudio-del-banco-mundial-sobre-efectos.html, last access 15 Sept. 2022.

93 Francisco Saffie, ‘¿Por qué fiscalizar la elusión mediante una Cláusula General Antielusión?’, in Jorge Atria and Cristóbal Otero (eds.), Impuestos justos para el Chile que viene: Diagnósticos y desafíos tributarios para un nuevo pacto fiscal (Santiago: Fondo de Cultura Económica, 2021), pp. 253–76.

94 The respondents had to fill out a brief questionnaire that did not include questions of wealth. Thus, this position is only based on income information. Though it is not possible to check under-reporting, previous research has also trusted in respondents’ information. See Berens, Sarah and von Schiller, Armin, ‘Taxing Higher Incomes: What Makes the High-Income Earners Consent to More Progressive Taxation in Latin America’, Political Behavior, 39: 3 (2017), pp. 703–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

95 Rowland Atkinson and John Flint, ‘Accessing Hidden and Hard-to-Reach Populations: Snowball Research Strategies’, Social Research Update, 33 (Summer 2001).

96 Regarding tax perceptions, see Prabhakar, Rajiv, ‘What Do the Public Think of Taxation? Evidence from a Focus Group Study in England’, Journal of European Social Policy, 22: 1 (2012), pp. 7789CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Regarding elites, see Kantola, Anu, ‘Gloomy at the Top: How the Wealthiest 0.1% Feel about the Rest’, Sociology, 54: 5 (2020), pp. 904–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

97 Kantola, ‘Gloomy at the Top’.

98 The EE (‘Economic Elite’) numbers throughout this article refer to the identification number assigned to each interview, as noted in the methodology section.

99 Tasha Fairfield, ‘Going Where the Money Is: Strategies for Taxing Economic Elites in Unequal Democracies’, World Development, 47 (April 2013), p. 45.

100 Kalati and Manor, ‘Elite Perceptions of Poverty’.

101 See, for example, ‘Una reforma tributaria con objetivos políticos’, newspaper editorial, La Tercera, 29 April 2012, p. 39.

102 Friedrich A. Hayek, ‘Los principios de un orden social liberal’, Estudios Públicos, 6 (March 1982), pp. 179–202.

103 Hayek, ‘Los principios’, p. 183.

104 Friedrich A. Hayek, ‘El atavismo de la justicia social’, Estudios Públicos, 36 (Sept. 1989), pp. 181–93.

105 Gárate, La revolución, p. 262.

106 Ibid., p. 263; Clark, ‘The Paradox’.

107 Sloterdijk, Peter, Die nehmende Hand und die gebende Seite (Frankfurt: Suhrkamp, 2010)Google Scholar.

108 See, for instance, Kalati and Manor, ‘Elite Perceptions of Poverty’.

109 McCall, Leslie and Kenworthy, Lane, ‘Americans’ Social Policy Preferences in the Era of Rising Inequality’, Perspectives on Politics, 7: 3 (2009), pp. 459–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

110 Tomás Undurraga, ‘Instrucción, indulgencia y justificación: Los circuitos culturales del capitalismo chileno’, in Ossandón and Tironi (eds.), Adaptación, pp. 135–66.

111 Elisa Reis, ‘Perceptions of Poverty and Inequality among Brazilian Elites’, in Reis and Moore (eds.), Elite Perceptions, p. 45.

112 Angélica Thumala, ‘El error de Milton Friedman: Justificaciones religiosas y morales de la empresa en Chile’, in Ossandón and Tironi (eds.), Adaptación, pp. 223–48.

113 Gárate, La revolución, pp. 493–5.

114 Ibid., p. 502.

115 Claudio Agostini, ‘Una reforma eficiente y equitativa del impuesto al ingreso en Chile’, in José Arellano and Vittorio Corbo (eds.), Tributación para el desarrollo (Santiago: Centro de Estudios Públicos (CEP) / CIEPLAN, 2017), pp. 199–245.

116 That is, a tax that imposes the same relative burden on all taxpayers. See Walter J. Blum and Harry Kalven Jr., ‘The Uneasy Case for Progressive Taxation’, University of Chicago Law Review, 19: 3 (1952), pp. 417–520.

117 Murphy and Nagel, The Myth of Ownership.

118 Undurraga, Divergencias, p. 89.

119 Kato, Junko, Regressive Taxation and the Welfare State: Path Dependence and Policy Diffusion (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

120 Atria, Jorge, ‘Legalism and Creativity: Tax Non-Compliance in the Eyes of the Economic Elite’, International Review of Sociology, 29: 1 (2019), pp. 5879CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

121 The tax policy needs to consider preferences for savings. However, this analysis is beyond the scope of this article and should be addressed in further research.

122 Cheyre, ‘Análisis de las reformas’.

123 Berens and von Schiller, ‘Taxing Higher Incomes’.

124 Jorge Atria, Julius Duran and Simón Ramírez, ‘Business Elite Attitudes toward Taxation and the State: The Case of Chile’, United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD) Occasional Paper No. 13 (Feb. 2021).

125 Fairfield, ‘Going Where the Money Is’, p. 45.

126 See, for instance, María José Pérez, ‘Interview with Mary Anastasia O'Grady’, Pulso newspaper, 6 May 2014, pp. 4–5.

127 Steinmo, ‘The Evolution of Policy Ideas’, p. 229.

128 Marta Lagos, ‘Chile al desnudo’, Latinobarómetro, available online at www.cooperativa.cl/noticias/site/artic/20111028/asocfile/20111028111806/chile_al_desnudo.pdf, last access 15 Sept. 2022.

129 Sánchez-Ancochea, ‘The Political Economy of Inequality’, p. 358.

130 But see Atria, Jorge and Kaltwasser, Cristóbal Rovira, Informe de resultados: Estudio COES de la elite cultural, económica y política en Chile (Santiago: COES, 2021)Google Scholar.