Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-dwq4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-28T05:06:50.707Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economic Events, Information Structure, and the Return-Generating Process

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 April 2009

Abstract

The parameters of the return process of a firm are determined by two elements—the natural event structure, i.e., the process by which nature affects the value of the firm, and the information structure, i.e., the process by which information about these events is collected and disseminated to investors. Simple measures of three dimensions of the information structure—the frequency and accuracy of, and the bias in information releases, are derived from the moments of the return distribution.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1985

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

[1]Black, Fischer, and Scholes, Myron. “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities.” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81 (1973), pp. 637654.Google Scholar
[2]Blattberg, R. C., and Gonedes, N. J.. “A Comparison of the Stable and the Student Distribution as Statistical Models for Stock Prices.” Journal of Business, Vol. 42 (04 1974), pp. 244280.Google Scholar
[3]Clark, P.A Subordinated Stochastic Process Model with Finite Variance for Speculative Prices.” Econometrica, Vol. 41 (01 1973), pp. 135155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4]Cox, J. C., and Ross, S. A.. “The Valuation of Options for Alternative Stochastic Processes.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 4 (01/03 1976), pp. 637653.Google Scholar
[5]Damodaran, A.Information Structure and Return Generating Processes: An Empirical Examination.” Working paper, University of California at Berkeley (1985).Google Scholar
[6]Dimson, E.Risk Measurement when Shares Are Subject to Infrequent Trading.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 7 (06 1979), pp. 197226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Fama, E. F.The Behavior of Stock Market Prices.” Journal of Business, Vol. 38 (01 1965), pp. 34105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8]Fama, E. F., and Miller, M.. The Theory of Finance. New York: Holt, Rhinehart and Winston (1972).Google Scholar
[9]Mandlebrot, B., and Taylor, H. M.. “On the Distribution of Stock Price Differences.” Operations Research, Vol. 15 (1112 1967), pp. 10571062.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]Merton, R. C. “On the Mathematics and Economic Assumptions of Continuous-Time Models.” In Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Paul Cootner. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall (1982).Google Scholar
[11]Merton, R. C.. “Option Pricing when Underlying Stock Returns are Discontinuous.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3 (01/03 1976), pp. 125144.Google Scholar
[12]Roll, R.A Possible Explanation of the Small Firm Effect.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 36 (03 1982), pp. 879888.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13]Ross, S. M.Stochastic Processes. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. (1983).Google Scholar
[14]Rubinstein, M. E.A Mean-Variance Synthesis of Corporate Financial Theory.” Journal of Finance, Vol. 28 (03 1973), pp. 167182.Google Scholar
[15]Scholes, M., and Williams, J.. “Estimating Betas from Nonsynchronous Data.” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 5 (12 1977), pp. 309327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar