Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-xfwgj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-16T05:14:21.582Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Tasks of Economic History1

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 February 2011

Edwin F. Gay
Affiliation:
Henry E. Huntington Library

Extract

It is a great honor, deeply appreciated, to be chosen first president of the Economic History Association. I cannot pretend to act as spokesman for this newly organized scientific group. I assume that I owe my present honor and responsibility partly to the number of years I have imperfectly taught economic history—and, I hope, stimulated some interest in it—and partly to your recognition of the principle of historical continuity. For I was a student under Schmoller at Berlin; he in turn was a pupil of Roscher (whose last lectures at Leipsic I heard); and Roscher, almost a century ago, was one of the first historical economists and the original formulator of a program for the new “school” of economics. I wish to recall to your attention these beginnings of our discipline in order to emphasize how the subsequent shift in its development has made us economic historians instead of historical economists.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1941

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

2 Knies held that no ends, however beneficial, justify unethical means: “Even if from a sowing of dragon's teeth an armored power arises, it is a power that finds no rest until it destroys itself.” Political Economy from the Standpoint of the Historic Method, 489.

3 Cf. Rogin, Leo, Werner Sotnbart and Transcendentalism, American Economic Review, XXXI, 493512Google Scholar.