Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-13T09:01:45.645Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

British-French Technology Transfer from the Revolution to Louis Philippe (1791–1844): Evidence from Patent Data

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 July 2023

Alessandro Nuvolari*
Affiliation:
Professor of Economic History, Sant’Anna School of Advanced Studies, Piazza Martiri della Libertà, 33, 56127 Pisa PI, Italy.
Gaspare Tortorici
Affiliation:
Research Associate Luxembourg Institute of Socio-Economic Research (LISER), Porte des Sciences·11·Maison des Sciences Humaines·Esch-sur-Alzette/Belval·Luxembourg. E-mail: gaspare.tortorici@liser.lu.
Michelangelo Vasta
Affiliation:
Professor of Economic History, University of Siena, Piazza San Francesco 7, 53100 Siena, Italy. E-mail: vasta@unisi.it.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper examines the patterns of technology transfer from Britain to France during the early phases of industrializing using a dataset comprising all patents granted in France in the period 1791–1844. Exploiting the peculiarities of French legislation, we construct an array of patent quality indicators and investigate their determinants. We find that patents filed by British inventors or French inventors with personal connections to British inventors were of relatively higher quality. Overall, our results show that the French innovation system was capable of attracting and effectively absorbing key technologies from Britain.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association

A key ingredient of the industrialization process is the accumulation of scientific and technological capabilities (Mokyr Reference Mokyr1990). This typically leads to the emergence of a “technology gap” between the leading country and its followers, ultimately shaping the patterns of economic growth (Gerschenkron Reference Gerschenkron1962; Abramovitz Reference Abramovitz1986). Abramovitz (Reference Abramovitz1986) suggested that successful catching up is the combination of three factors: (i) the technology flows from the leading economy (“interaction between followers and leaders”); (ii) the “social capabilities” of the receiving economy; and (iii) the “congruity” between the technology of the leader and the resource endowment of the follower.

These insights represent a useful framework to study how the rest of Europe caught up with Britain in terms of industrialization. In fact, the early phases of French industrialization are extremely interesting, with French science being prominent internationally during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. This prominence underscores the significant influence of French scientific advancements on technological developments during that period (Fox Reference Fox2012). Belhoste (Reference Belhoste2011) provides a compelling account of the rise and consolidation of Paris as a “European capital of science” throughout the eighteenth century. However, success in terms of scientific discoveries and inventions does not automatically translate into the adoption and diffusion of innovations. Mokyr (Reference Mokyr1990) notes that England’s technological leadership in this period was not so much in science, but rather in effectively combining scientific knowledge and engineering capabilities.Footnote 1

Whether French scientific achievements played a significant role in the assimilation and adaptation of British technologies is thus an interesting question. In fact, there is a general consensus that the technological transfer from Britain represented a critical source of innovation during the early phases of French industrialization.Footnote 2 Crouzet (Reference Crouzet2003) describes the French industrial revolution as a “foreign transplant” that rapidly becomes “naturalized.” For instance, Henderson (Reference Henderson1972) and Crouzet (Reference Crouzet, Teich and Porter1996) studied several revealing instances of the successful importation of technology from Britain to France.Footnote 3

Crucial innovations of the Industrial Revolution, such as textile, steam power, and iron-making techniques, were transferred from Britain to France using patent protection. In most cases, technology transfer occurred as a result of British citizens relocating to France and establishing companies and production facilities there.Footnote 4 In other cases, French entrepreneurs acquired technological experience from England in various ways and adapted it to the French context.Footnote 5

The main goal of this paper is to provide a quantitative assessment of the patterns of technology transfer from Britain to France adopting the framework introduced by Abramovitz, explicitly considering the role of social capabilities and the “congruity” of the French economy. To this aim, we measure inventive activities using patent data.Footnote 6

Our dataset of French historical patents represents a unique opportunity to provide a detailed account of the technology transfer from Britain to France by identifying all the British patents granted in France, evaluating their quality, and looking at how involvement with British inventors impacted the quality of French patents themselves.

Our results show that, in this key historical phase, technology transfer from Britain represented a key source of technical progress for France. In a broader perspective, our results also highlight how French inventors and entrepreneurs successfully adapted British technology to the French context.

This paper also contributes to the debate on the performance of French industrialization, which can be broadly characterized in terms of two opposing views.Footnote 7 On the one hand, the “pessimist” perspective of Khan (Reference Khan2020), who, following the traditional account by Landes (Reference Landes1949, Reference Landes1969), suggests that the French innovation system was excessively dominated by the role of the State with detrimental effects on inventive activities. In contrast, the more “optimist” interpretation of French industrialization by O’Brien and Keyder (Reference O’Brien and Keyder1978, p. 21) highlights how particular the French path to industrialization was since “it took place in a different legal, political and cultural tradition.”Footnote 8 Indeed, when these contextual specificities are fully taken into account, the French economic performance compares quite well with that of Britain (Crafts Reference Crafts1984).Footnote 9 Our findings suggest that, at least from this technological standpoint, pessimistic accounts of French industrial retardation seem wide off the mark.

THE FRENCH PATENT SYSTEM

During the Ancien Regime, France encouraged both inventive activities and the transfer of technologies from abroad through a rather complicated system of “exclusive privileges.” Requests for privileges had to endure a taxing examination process led by the Bureau du Commerce in collaboration with other institutions such as the Académie des Sciences or artisans from specific guilds (Hilaire-Perez Reference Hilaire-Perez2000; Baudry Reference Baudry2020). The function of this examination process, which led to its approval by the Parlement, was to ascertain the genuine utility of each invention from the point of view of the French state. This institutional configuration made the granting of privileges uncertain and highly discretionary.

The aim of the 1791 patent law was to introduce a radically new approach.Footnote 10 The philosophical underpinning was the “natural right” of inventors to enjoy the fruits of their ingenuity. Accordingly, the first objective was to create a system not subject to the discretionary power of the state. In this respect, the inspiration was the English system, where, since the early eighteenth century, patents were liberally granted without examination (Bottomley Reference Bottomley2014).Footnote 11

The law contemplated three main types of patents: (i) patents for invention (brevets d’invention), covering “every new discovery or invention” (art. 1, Law 7th January); (ii) patents for improvement (perfectionnement), covering improvements of existing technologies (art. 2, Law 7th January); and (iii) patents of importation (brevets d’importation), covering the first introduction in France of foreign discoveries (art. 3, Law 7th January). Footnote 12 The law established that patents had a duration of 5, 10, or 15 years (art. 8, Law 7th January), according to the fee paid by the inventor upfront. The fee structure (which was the same for all types of patents) was the following: 300, 800, and 1,500 francs for patents with a 5, 10, and 15-year duration, respectively (titre 3, n. IV, Law 25th May).Footnote 13 The granting of each patent also involved the payment of an additional administrative fee amounting to 50 francs. Upon request, the law offered the possibility of paying the fee in two installments: about half of the amount when the patent was granted and the second half after six months (Perpigna Reference Perpigna1832, p. 57). It was also possible to introduce improvements (certificats d’addition) to an already existing patent by paying a fee amounting to 24 francs (titre 3, n. IV, Law 25th May). The patenting of these “improvements” did not alter the expiration date of the original patent. Finally, the law gave the possibility to extend an already existing patent by paying a costly fee equal to 600 francs plus 12 francs for the registration (titre 3, n. IV, Law 25th May). Despite being technically possible, these extensions were only granted in very special cases and had to undergo a very demanding examination by the government.Footnote 14 The 1791 laws defined the legal framework pertaining to patenting activity in France until they were replaced by a law passed on 5 July 1844; in fact, only minor changes were made in the period 1791–1844. Of these changes, it is worth noting that, in 1806, the prohibition for joint stock companies to register a patent was removed (Empotz and Marchal Reference Empotz and Marchal2002, pp. 202–203; Baudry Reference Baudry2019).

The level and structure of patent fees were key parameters regulating the accessibility of a patent system. According to Khan (Reference Khan2005, pp. 43–44), the relatively high level of French patent fees severely limited access to patent protection for ordinary inventors. As a result, she argues that, even if the system was rhetorically founded on the notion of the “natural right” of the inventors, in practice it granted the opportunity to patent inventions only to a restricted number of individuals. The assessment of the French patent system by Baudry (Reference Baudry2020) is more nuanced. In the absence of a stringent examination, the level of patent fees aimed to discourage inventors from patenting trivial inventions, making the entire system self-regulatory without further governmental or administrative interventions: “In the 1791 law, the patent tax worked as an apparatus designed to incentivize the inventor into becoming a good calculator of his own interest, which was subsequently turned into the general public interest, into the common good” (Baudry Reference Baudry2020, p. 16).Footnote 15

Figure 1 compares French patent fees with those prevailing in England and the United States according to different measures in the period 1825–30. It examines the costs for the maximum possible patent duration within each system, that is, 15 years in France and 14 years in both England and the United States. The histograms on the left-hand side provide a comparison by means of a simple conversion of the fees of each country in U.S. dollars, while those in the middle and on the right-hand side express fees in terms of the prevailing daily wages of skilled workers (respectively a mechanic and a mason). Two points deserve attention: first, the extremely low level of U.S. patent fees corroborates the idea that the U.S. patent system was widely accessible and “democratic” (Khan Reference Khan2005). Second, French fees are significantly lower than the English ones—almost half when considering dollar conversions and between 30 and 45 percent according to wage-related computations. Thus, although Khan (Reference Khan2020, p. 164) considers both the English and French systems as biased against inventors with limited financial resources, this evidence suggests that the 1791 French law, despite having been inspired by English practice, introduced a significantly lower bar for accessing patent protection.

Figure 1 COST OF PATENTING BY COUNTRY, CIRCA 1825–30

Notes: The figure reports the cost—in U.S. dollars and in working days—for a patent granted for 15 years in France and for 14 years in England and the United States.

Sources: The cost for a patent in England and the United States is from Khan (Reference Khan2005), while for France it is based on the 25 May 1791 patent law. The conversion rate in dollars is based on Rosenberg (Reference Rosenberg1967). The wages of a mechanic are from Rosenberg (Reference Rosenberg1967). The wage of masons in England (London) and in France (Paris) are from Allen (https://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/people/sites/allen-research-pages/), while for the United States (Philadelphia) are from Adams (Reference Adams1968).

The law also provided for the withdrawal of granted patents (art. 16, Law 7th January). The most obvious case pertained to patents that were not actually new but were deemed so by a court trial. Similarly, patents could be revoked if their specifications were found to be obscure or incomplete in court judgments. Should a patentee fail to pay the second installment of the initial fee, a patent would also be revoked. Finally, the law contemplated a working clause of two yearsFootnote 16 : if the patentee had not put the invention into practice within this term, the patent could be annulled. Importantly, the failure to put the invention into practice also had to be established formally in court (Perpigna Reference Perpigna1832, pp. 62–81).Footnote 17

PATENTING ACTIVITY IN FRANCE

Since the seminal contribution by Schmookler (Reference Schmookler1966),Footnote 18 patents have become one of the preferred sources used to investigate inventive activities.Footnote 19 However, patent data have two well-known limitations: (i) not all inventions are patented, and (ii) patents differ considerably in quality, ranging from small improvements to major radical innovations (Streb Reference Streb, Diebolt and Haupert2016). In relation to the issue that not all inventions are necessarily patented, datasets comprising both patented and non-patented inventions, such as those constructed using international exhibition catalogues (Moser Reference Moser2005), are currently lacking for the specific period under examination in this paper.Footnote 20 Regarding quality differences, we have developed a number of patent quality indicators so that we can reconstruct the impact of technology transfer from Britain to France by means of a systematic comparison between the quality of patents of British origin and domestic ones.

Historical Sources

Our paper is based on a digitized dataset covering all the patents deposited and granted in France from 1791 to 1844.Footnote 21 The dataset was compiled by the Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (hereafter INPI) and comprises 12,575 patents containing fully detailed information on patent and patentee characteristics. Footnote 22 Although it has been used in some important contributions (Galvez-Behar Reference Galvez-Behar2008, Reference Galvez-Behar2019; Baudry 2014; Khan Reference Khan2016), this source still remains largely unexplored.

The dataset allows us to trace the exact date on which a patent was deposited, granted and withdrawn, how long each patent was initially filed for (5, 10, or 15 years), the total number of subsequent additions to the original invention, and a detailed description of the patent itself. A preliminary industry classification of each patent is also available. The name, surname, residence address, and occupation of the patentees are also available. While about a sixth of all patents were deposited by groups of (up to six) individuals, single-patentee inventions are by far the most common. Companies were also permitted to patent inventions, which represented 6 percent of the observations.Footnote 23 Crucially, the data uncover historical evidence on patent agents, that is, intermediaries that handled the bureaucratic procedures on behalf of the patentees themselves. We substantially complemented these data by: (i) geo-referencing each patent and assigning it to a historical department in France; (ii) singling out foreign inventors (and their country of residence); (iii) reclassifying occupations for each patentee; and (iv) categorizing all patents according to the 1853 technological classification (Empotz and Marchal Reference Empotz and Marchal2002, p. 70). We also introduced three different measures of patent quality. Finally, we corrected some data errors by looking at the original source and amending the number of additions, residences of patent agents, and company names.Footnote 24 The analysis is organized around the following periodization, which reflects the main institutional changes of the period: 1791–1815, from the founding of the French patent system to the end of the Napoleonic wars; 1816–1830, from the Congress of Vienna to the 1830 July Revolution (Révolution de Juillet) with Louis Philippe ascending the throne; 1831–1844, throughout the reign of Louis Philippe and until the patent system was drastically reformed in 1844, a few years before the 1848 Revolution.

A Preliminary Snapshot

Between 1791 and 1844, patenting activity in France was quite intense; 12,575 patents were registered. To put this figure into perspective, within the same timeframe in the United States, although registration was much cheaper, 13,833 patents were granted (Khan Reference Khan and Whaples2008). On the other hand, in England, where the system was comparatively more expensive, 8,663 patents were registered (Woodcroft Reference Woodcroft1854).Footnote 25

Table 1 shows the number of patents granted in France between 1791–1844 based on patentee residences at the time of the deposit.Footnote 26 In cases where a patent was deposited by individuals who were resident in different countries, we assigned a fractional number to each one: for instance, whenever a patent was associated with two people residing in different countries, each was given a value of 0.5.

Table 1 DISTRIBUTION OF PATENTS BY COUNTRY AND SUB-PERIODS

Notes: We use fractional numbers to take into account when a patent was assigned to two or more patentees resident in different countries. For Belgium, Germany, Ireland, Italy, and The Netherlands, we consider current borders.

Source: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset.

Table 1 offers two main takeaways. First, patentees who were residents of France account for about 90 percent of the total. Second, among foreigners, patentees who were residents of Britain represented the bulk of the contribution, totaling over 70 percent of foreign patents. Clearly, the flow of technologies from Britain embodied in patents overwhelmingly took place after the end of the Revolutionary and Napoleonic wars. Until 1843, the technology transfer between England and France was still severely disrupted by British legislation, which prohibited the export of machinery and the emigration of skilled workers (Jeremy Reference Jeremy1977).

We assigned a latitude-longitude pair to each location associated with a patent. Footnote 27 We then allocated these places to French historical departments by plotting their coordinates over the 1830 French administrative map. Footnote 28 Figure 2 shows the geographical distribution by departments using the periodization previously introduced.Footnote 29 The three maps suggest that French patenting activity was always concentrated around a single hub: Paris.Footnote 30 Considering the entire period, the Seine department (in red) Footnote 31 was by far the most active, since 6,363.5 (50.6 percent) patents were granted to individuals or companies residing there—excluding Seine-Inférieure, Seine-et-Oise, and Seine-et-Marne, which together amounted to an additional 4.2 percent of the total.Footnote 32

Figure 2 NUMBER OF PATENTS GRANTED IN FRANCE BY DEPARTMENT (1791–1844)

Notes: Darker areas indicate a higher number of patents. The maps also report the Rouen-Geneva line.

Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents and http://www.datavis.ca/gallery/guerry/maps.html for the map of France Department boundaries of 1830.

Other departments show much lower numbers—for example, the Rhône comes in second with only 533 patents (4.2 percent); the Gironde is the fourth most active department with 271 patents (2.2 percent). The geographical distribution is therefore very skewed. Footnote 33 Another interesting feature of the maps in Figure 2 is the concentration of patenting activity in the North-Eastern regions of the country. This is consistent with the idea of a regional divide in the French economic and social geography along the notional line, traced in black in the figure, running from Rouen to Geneva, as suggested by Braudel (Reference Braudel1984, pp. 337–43) and other scholars.Footnote 34

In order to analyze the distribution of patenting across technological fields, we expanded the original version of the INPI data by assigning each patent to a homogeneous technological classification for the entire period (1791–1844). We used a total of 20 technological classes according to the pre-1853 coeval classification reported by INPI (see Online Appendix Figures A3 and A4, which present the disaggregation of technological classes by countries and periods, respectively).

Figure 3 NUMBER OF PATENTS GRANTED IN FRANCE BY PATENTEES’ OCCUPATION (1791–1844)

Notes: The occupational HISCO categories and ownership status are the following: 0_1 = small proprietor; 0_2 = large proprietor; 1 = higher manager; 2 = higher professionals; 3 = lower manager; 4 = lower professionals, and clerical and sales personnel; 5 = lower clerical and sales personnel; 6 = foremen (artisans); 7 = medium skilled workers; 8 = farmers and fishermen; 9 = lower skilled workers; 10 = lower skilled farm workers; 11 = unskilled workers.

Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents and Van Leeuwen, Maas, and Miles (Reference Van Leeuwen, Maas and Miles2002) for HISCO occupations.

Figure 4 SHARE OF “ONE-OFF” PATENTEES OVER TOTAL PATENTS BY COUNTRIES (1791–1842)

Notes: Data for France and England consist of the total number of patents granted in the period 1791–1844. Instead, data for the United States consist of patents granted from 1790 to 1846. Sources: Our own elaboration of the Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for France and Woodcroft (Reference Woodcroft1854) for England. Sokoloff and Khan (1990, table 1) for the United States.

Finally, to assess the social background of the patentees, we classified the patentees’ occupations and, indirectly, their social class.Footnote 35 We adopted the Historical International Classification of Occupations (HISCO) (Van Leeuwen, Maas, and Miles Reference Van Leeuwen, Maas and Miles2002, p. 57), which classifies occupations according to the manual/non-manual skill level (high, medium, low, and unskilled), supervision (yes or no), and sector (primary or other).Footnote 36 Since, the original source contains titles such as proprietaire, negociant, fabricant, and so on, we complemented the original 11 classes by adding a marker of ownership, distinguishing between small (0_1) and large proprietors (0_2).Footnote 37

Figure 3 shows that four occupations account for more than three-quarters of the total in all the sub-periods. The most represented class is always that of the “large proprietor” (0_2), while the others are: “higher professional” (2), which includes engineers and other individuals with formal scientific or technical education; foremen (artisans) (6), which comprises skilled workers for key technologies in the eighteenth–nineteenth centuries; and “medium skilled workers” (7).Footnote 38 Notably, the share of artisans and low-skilled/unskilled workers amounts to 34.8 percent of the total number of patents. This value is large and much higher than the 18.8 percent estimated by Khan (Reference Khan2020, p. 165) for artisans with a reduced sample of 849 patents for 1791–1855.

In the case of the United States, Sokoloff and Khan (1990) interpreted the share of patentees with only one career patent as an indicator of the accessibility (“democratization”) of the patent system, with the intuition being that a system widely open to “one off” patentees did not have significant barriers to entry.

Figure 4 compares the shares of patentees with only one career patent for France, England, and the United States, using the same sub-periods as Sokoloff and Khan (see Table A3 in the Online Appendix for the full comparative data). When considering this indicator of accessibility, France seems remarkably similar to the United States across all sub-periods.Footnote 39 This characterization is also in contrast with Khan (Reference Khan2020), who painted an essentially elitist picture of the French patent system, claiming that it was only accessible to the wealthy classes. In this respect, our findings cast the functioning of the French patent system in a much more favorable light.

Overall, the occupational disaggregation of patentees and their long-term commitment to patenting suggest that the accessibility of the French patent system was significantly wider than previously suggested by Khan (Reference Khan2005, Reference Khan2020).

DATA AND METHODS

This section provides a discussion of our dataset and the methodology used in the econometrics exercises. Notwithstanding the large success of patents as a measure of inventive activities, one of their most notable shortcomings is that “[…] the inventions that are patented differ greatly in quality” (Griliches Reference Griliches1990, p. 1669). Accordingly, simple patent counting might provide a misleading picture of the intensity of innovative activities. In this paper, we tackle this issue, by developing sophisticated quality measures capturing the “magnitude of inventive output” for each patent (Griliches Reference Griliches1990, p. 1669).

Patent Quality

Economic historians have constructed patent quality indicators by implementing two main strategies (for two useful surveys, see Streb Reference Streb, Diebolt and Haupert2016, Reference Streb2023). Mainly inspired by the American system, which prescribed the documentation of “prior art” by means of citations, the first approach adopts the number of citations received by a patent as a measure of its relative significance; important inventions are likely to attract the interest of many follow-up inventors (Nicholas Reference Nicholas2010).Footnote 40 The second approach exploits renewal data and draws on the idea that inventors will pay renewal fees only as long as the economic returns of the patent exceed the cost of maintaining it in force (Streb, Baten, and Yin Reference Streb, Baten and Yin2006).

In our context, neither approach is feasible: French patents were not yet systematically cited in the United States and, as mentioned previously, renewals were not contemplated by the law. However, following Nuvolari and Vasta (Reference Nuvolari and Vasta2015, Reference Nuvolari and Vasta2017), we maintain that patent duration can still be used as an informative proxy for its value, which is similar to the intuition of the use of renewal data (Schankerman and Pakes Reference Schankerman and Pakes1986). In this case, we assume that ground-breaking inventions are more likely to be associated with longer and more costly patents than more limited contributions.

As previously mentioned, each patentee—or team of patentees—was required to declare upfront how long they wished to secure the legal protection related to the patenting of their inventions. According to the legal framework, they could only choose among three patent durations: 5, 10, or 15 years. We therefore argue that duration is a good approximation of patent quality because it is likely to reflect the expected economic value of the patent for the inventor at the time of the application.Footnote 41 Thus, we develop three measures based on patent duration, considering both improvements introduced by the inventors and withdrawals.

First, we simply classify patents with respect to their duration and assign a progressive quality score from 1 to 3 to each observation, proportional to patent duration: 5, 10, and 15 years. Table 2, panel on the left, summarizes the distribution of this variable: more than half of all the patents were originally filed for 5 years; 27.2 percent were filed for 10 years; while the remaining one-fifth (20.8 percent) was supposed to last 15 years.

Table 2 DISTRIBUTION OF DIFFERENT PATENT QUALITY INDICATORS (1791–1844)

Source: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset.

Second, we exploit the steep fee structure of the French patent system and introduce a monetary measure of patent quality. As already noticed, patentees who wished to register 5-, 10-, or 15-year patents incurred an initial cost of 300, 800, or 1500 francs, respectively. After the initial deposit (handled by the patent administration for 50 francs), inventors could file additions against the payment of a moderate fee (24 francs); most patents do not have any additions (the median is 0, the mean is 0.42, and the maximum is 23). Taken together, this evidence enabled us to assign a total monetary value to each patent: for example, a 5-year patent with 5 additions would have a monetary value of 470 francs (50 + 300 + 24 * 5); a 10-year patent with only one addition would have a monetary value of 874 francs (50 + 800 + 24). Table 2, the panel in the center, bins observations into four classes: 0–350 francs, capturing 5-year patents with no additions; 351–849 francs, capturing 5-year patents with additions up to (but excluding) 10-year patents with no additions; 850–1,549 francs, capturing 10-year patents with additions up to (but excluding) 15-year patents with no additions; 1,550–2,102 francs, capturing 15-year patents with additions. The distribution of this variable largely retraces that in the left panel and confirms that 5-year patents, with or without additions, accounted for about half the total number.

Third, we consider the number of days in which each patent was actually in force, taking into account information on withdrawals.Footnote 42 For example, a 5-year patent is associated with a value of 1,825 days Footnote 43 ; should the same 5-year patent be withdrawn after a year from its grant date, its value would then become 365 days. Following Nuvolari and Vasta (Reference Nuvolari and Vasta2015, Reference Nuvolari and Vasta2017), this indicator captures the “real” duration of a patent since it considers its genuine life-time, defined as the temporal difference between the granting date and the precise moment in which it ceased to be legally binding, whatever the actual reason (expiration or an early withdrawal). Thus, this indicator is our favorite measure—that is, the baseline of our econometric exercise.

Table 2, the panel on the right, gathers observations into four bins, considering their duration measured in days. Compared with the other panels, it reveals that considering withdrawn patents considerably increases the variability, contributing to a more nuanced view of the patent value as patents could be withdrawn independently of their initial duration. Finally, Table 3 breaks down the distribution of the patent’s “real duration” by patentees’ residence. Interestingly, foreign patents and, in particular, British patents are concentrated in the longest-duration classes.

Table 3 DISTRIBUTION OF REAL DURATION (DAYS) BY PATENTEES’ RESIDENCE (1791–1844)

Source: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset.

Figure 5 shows three panels where we plot the frequency of actual patent durations within each patent class. Footnote 44 The highest bars relate to the natural expiration date of each patent: 1,825, 3,650, and 5,475 days, respectively. Shorter bars on the leftmost part of the figure show the distribution of withdrawn patents. Although they are most represented in the 5-year class, withdrawals are not uncommon among 10- and 15-year patents either. This suggests that our preferred indicator (“real” duration) offers a more precise assessment of patent quality than the 5-10-15 year disaggregation.

Figure 5 REAL DURATION (DAYS) FOR DIFFERENT TYPES OF PATENTS (5, 10, AND 15 YEARS)

Notes: The figure reports the distribution of patents “real” duration (in log) by three permitted levels of initial duration (5, 10, and 15 years).

Source: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents.

Figure 6 maps the geographical distribution of high-quality patents, defined as those that have been active for more than 4,000 days. In addition to the stylized facts already noted in Figure 2—that is, the Seine department being a clear hub and the existence of a regional divide marked by the Rouen-Geneva line—these maps also reveal that high-value patents were deposited where the innovative activity was most intensive, as charted in Figure 2. While the number of departments without high-quality patents decreases over time, not all of France was covered by 1844, suggesting that certain departments experienced an agglomeration in terms of both quantity and quality.

Figure 6 NUMBER OF “HIGH QUALITY” PATENTS GRANTED IN FRANCE BY DEPARTMENT (1791–1844)

Notes: Darker areas indicate a higher number of patents. “High quality” patents are those with real duration (days) greater than 4,000. The maps also report the Rouen-Geneva line.

Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents and http://www.datavis.ca/gallery/guerry/maps.html for the map of France department boundaries of 1830.

The “real” duration measure of patent quality is based on the idea that the choice of patentees in terms of patent duration was not affected by their financial resources, but was related to the intrinsic quality of the invention. Reassuringly, the distribution of patent durations registered by the whole population of patentees and that of individuals of a high social class (identified using the HISCO classification) are very similar. The same pattern is also visible for withdrawn patents (see Online Appendix Figures A5, A6, and A7).

Figure 7 SHARE OF WORLD IMPORTANT SCIENTIFIC DISCOVERIES AND INVENTIONS BY COUNTRIES (1700–1900)

Sources: Sorokin (Reference Sorokin1937, vol. II, p. 150) lines and authors’ elaborations from Streit (Reference Streit1954, annex I, table I) bars.

In order to further validate our quality indicator, we cross-matched our data with four recently compiled datasets that seek to identify the most important figures in human history, including inventors. Footnote 45 Pioneered by Khan and Sokoloff (1993) in the context of U.S. patents, this approach employs independent compilations or lists of “famous inventors” as an indicator of patent quality. We used the following sources: Pantheon (Yu et al. Reference Yu, Shahar Ronen, Lu and Hidalgo2016); Notable people dataset (Gergaud, Louenan, and Wasmer Reference Gergaud, Louenan and Wasmer2016); the Human accomplishment dataset (Murray Reference Murray2003); and the Notable individuals dataset (Schich et al. Reference Schich, Chaoming Song, Alexander Mirsky, Barabási and Helbing2014). Table 4 summarizes the most important characteristics of these sources.

Table 4 BIOGRAPHICAL SOURCES USED TO IDENTIFY HISTORICALLY RENOWNED PATENTEES

We identified historically renowned patentees in our data and ranked them according to a 0 to 4 scale, depending on how many times they appear in the previously mentioned sources. We then evaluated whether patents by the most renowned patentees were of higher quality—in terms of our own measures—with respect to the rest of the sample.

Table 5 shows comforting results. The leftmost column specifies how many biographical datasets contain information on a given patentee. The average and median duration of patents deposited by historically renowned patentees are much higher, suggesting that our approach captures patent quality reasonably well. With the exception of a handful of patents with a value of 3, the ordinal fame index increases hand in hand with the average and median patent duration.

Table 5 REAL DURATION (DAYS) FOR PATENTS GRANTED TO FAMOUS AND AWARDED INVENTORS

Notes: The table was constructed by matching the names of patentees contained in the INPI dataset with the lists of famous inventors included in the sources of Table 4 and the list of awards granted in the period 1801–1844 by the Société d’encouragement pour l’Industrie Nationale.

Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents. Murray (Reference Murray2003), Schich et al. (Reference Schich, Chaoming Song, Alexander Mirsky, Barabási and Helbing2014), Gergaud, Louenan, and Wasmer (Reference Gergaud, Louenan and Wasmer2016), and Yu et al. (Reference Yu, Shahar Ronen, Lu and Hidalgo2016) for famous inventors and Annuarie de la Société d’encouragement pour l’Industrie Nationale (1852) for awards.

Lastly, following Moser (Reference Moser2012), who used prizes as quality indicators, in order to perform an additional test of patent quality, we digitized the information contained in the Annuarie de la Société d’encouragement pour l’Industrie Nationale (1852).Footnote 46 This publication contains detailed information on all the French inventors who were granted a monetary prize or a medal (bronze, silver, and gold) for a particularly ground-breaking invention. We also cross-matched our data with this information. In the bottom part of Table 2, we split the sample according to whether a patentee received any sort of prize and computed the same statistics as before. The results of this exercise were again in line with our expectations: whenever patents were filed by (a posteriori) more successful inventors, the average and median patent duration were definitively higher.

Empirical Strategy

For our empirical analysis, we first explored the impact of different determinants on patent quality by performing some econometric exercises. Second, we examined the issue of technological congruity by studying the similarities and differences in the patenting activities in France and Britain using a measure of technological distance.

Our econometric exercise is designed to systematically compare the quality of patents with different characteristics. We thus ran a set of regressions, modeling the mean value of patent quality as a function of a number of observables. The aim of this was to assess the role of technology transfer, both via social contact or geographical proximity, as well as social capabilities and other factors. We estimated the following equation:

$${q_i} = \alpha + \beta \cdot B{O_i} + \gamma \cdot B{C_i} + \delta \cdot S{C_i} + {\rm{\zeta }} \cdot GE{O_i} + {\rm{\;\eta }} \cdot {\rm{\;}}{X_i} + {\varepsilon _i}$$

where q i is the quality of patent i measured using its real duration, BO i indicates a patent of British origin, BC i indicates a patent granted to a French inventor with British contacts, both representing our measure of technology flows, SC i is a vector of variables capturing social capabilities, in particular various forms of education and skills, GEO i represents a geographical control, and X i is a vector of control variables portraying further characteristics of the patent, while ε i is the error term. We include period and technological class fixed effects in all specifications and present results that both include and exclude department fixed effects.Footnote 47 In the following, we present the construction of the model covariates.Footnote 48

TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER

British Origins (BO): this variable is a dummy indicating either that the patentee has British residence or that the patentee (of whatever nationality) had taken an English patent for the period 1791–1852, before or within five years of the granting of the French patent in question. This is done in order to identify those inventors who were more likely to be in close contact with the techniques developed in Britain.Footnote 49

To provide a clearer understanding of the notion of BO patent, we report some examples. The first, the case of a British inventor patenting in France, is represented by the patent for “perfectionnements apportés dans la construction des locomotives” granted (via the patent agent Antoine Perpigna) on 5 October 1843 to James Nasmyth, the Scottish inventor of the steam hammer.Footnote 50 The second example, concerning a foreign inventor patenting both in Britain and in France, is epitomized by the patent granted to the American Robert Fulton, the inventor of the steam boat, on 17 February 1798 for the “canaux navigables sans écluses, au moyen de plans inclinés et de petits bateaux de forme nouvelle.” Indeed, Fulton was awarded an English patent (in this particular case, for a similar invention) in 1794. He actually worked in England between 1786–1797 and in France from 1797 to 1804.Footnote 51

British connection (BC): this variable is a dummy indicating, in the case of all patents not of British origin, that the patentee was a French resident who had already been involved in a patent with British origin, either collaborating with the inventors of the BO patent or via a patent agent involved in a BO patent. Considering the patent agent as a possible channel of technology transfer is fully in line with accounts of French industrialization, which have stressed their critical role as technology brokers in this period. Footnote 52 For example, the variable includes the patent granted on 12 May 1842 for the “perfectionnements apportés aux machines à vapeur fixes ou locomotives” granted to Benoit Fourneyron, the famous inventor of a successful hydraulic turbine. By that time, Fourneyron had already taken several patents via the mediation of the patent agent, Antoine Perpigna, who, in turn, had been involved in several BO patents. On the other hand, the famous patent on the hydraulic turbine (“roue à pression universelle et continue, ou turbine hydraulique de Fourneyron”) granted to Fourneyron on 24 October 1832 is not considered a BC patent, because it was taken before this inventor had had any contact with Antoine Perpigna.Footnote 53

SOCIAL CAPABILITIES

Engineer/Scientist: this is a dummy variable that indicates whether at least one patentee was an engineer or a similar professional (HISCO class 2). In this period, the profession of engineer was already characterized by a formal education. There were two main types of engineering education in France: the famous grandes écoles that supplied engineers mostly for the army and other state departments, and the écoles d’arts et métiers (introduced in 1803), which were more focused on the training of engineers who would be employed in the private sector (Day Reference Day1978). In both schools, the curricula were closely supervised by the State and consisted of highly intensive theoretical training. In contrast, Britain did not set up a formal national system of engineering education, and the training mainly took place by means of on-the-job apprenticeships (Hanlon Reference Hanlon2021).

Skilled worker: this is a dummy variable that indicates whether a patentee was a foreman, an artisan, or a similarly skilled worker (HISCO class 6). In the English context, a significant stream of literature has emphasized the critical role played by artisans in developing incremental inventions with a large productivity impact (Kelly, Mokyr, and O’Grada Reference Kelly, Mokyr, O’Grada, Bruland, Gerritsen, Hudson and Riello2020). In contrast, in France, there are no quantitative analyses of the contribution of skilled workers to inventive activities.

Literacy rates: this variable considers the possible effect of the diffusion of basic education on inventive activity. It is measured as grooms’ literacy rates in 1790, taken from the Maggiolo Inquiry.Footnote 54 The variable is constructed at the department level, since we assign the corresponding literacy rate to all patents registered in a given department. In the case of multiple inventors, we considered the department with the highest literacy rate.

GEOGRAPHY

Rouen-Geneva line: this variable, which was designed to capture the effect of geographical proximity to England, has a value of 1 when at least one of the patentees was resident north of the Rouen-Geneva line.

Port distance: this variable, which again was designed to capture the effect of geographical proximity to England, measures the distance from the residence of patentees to the nearest major Atlantic port (Brest, Calais, Cherbourg, Le Havre, and Saint Malo).Footnote 55 In the case of multiple inventors, we considered the shortest distance.

These two variables are meant to assess whether the geographical proximity to Britain played a determinant role in the technology transfer process.

FURTHER CONTROLS

Number of patentees: this variable denotes the number of patentees who registered a given patent. The aim is to capture the possible influence of scale effects on the inventors’ team.

Experience: this variable measures the number of patents taken by the patentee before the patent in question. In the case of multiple patentees, this variable takes the value of the patentee with the maximum experience.

Famous inventor: this variable measures the “historical significance” of the patentee, ranging between 0 to 4 as explained in the previous section. Again, in the case of multiple patentees, the variable captures the highest score.

High tech sector: this is a dummy that indicates whether the patent belongs to sectors characterized by rapid rates of technical progress, namely steam engines and engines (class 3), textile machines and fabrics (class 4), navigation (class 6), and metallurgy (class 8).

Award: this variable is a dummy that considers whether the patentee received an award from the Societe d’Encouragement pour l’Industrie Nationale.

After having characterized the main determinants of technology transfer by means of our econometric exercise, we explore the process of adaptation of British technologies to the French context by assessing the technological congruity between the two countries. To this aim, we used the indicator of technological distance introduced by Bar and Leiponen (Reference Bar and Leiponen2012). This indicator measures the distance between two patent “portfolios” distributed over K different industries. It is computed as follows:

$$T{D_{ij}} = 1 - \sum\limits_{k = 1}^K {\min ({p_{i,k}}{p_{j,k}})}$$

where TD ij denotes the technological distance between the patent portfolios i and j, while p i,k and p j,k indicate the share of patents in industry k in portfolios i and j, respectively. The indicator is equal to 0 when the sectoral distribution of the patent portfolio is perfectly equal, while it is equal to 1 (which is the maximum distance) when there is no overlap in the sectoral distribution of the two patent portfolios.

RESULTS

Table 6 presents a number of regressions in which the dependent variable is the real duration (measured in days) of a patent. Columns (4) and (8) contain regressions that do not include withdrawn patents (in this case, the sample amounts to 9,698 patents instead of 12,573 in the total sample). Columns (5), (6), (7), and (8) contain specifications controlling for department-fixed effects absorbing all unobserved characteristics that do not vary over time.

Table 6 DETERMINANTS OF PATENT QUALITY IN FRANCE

Notes: Dependent variable is “real” patent duration in days. OLS regressions with robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Models (4) and (8) do not include withdrawn patents.

Source: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset.

The results show that British origins (BO) are significant and positive in all specifications. The estimated effect ranges between 747 and 1,204 days. This intensive technology transfer from Britain took place by virtue of the activities of patent agents: 80 percent of the patents with British Origins featured the active involvement of a patent agent; thus, for domestic patents, the share is limited to 20 percent. The coefficient of the variable British connection (BC) is also positive and significant in all the specifications. In this latter case, the estimated effect ranges between 352 and 537 days, highlighting the very sizeable impact of British connections on patent quality—albeit lower than in the BO case.Footnote 56

Concerning the other co-variates, we find that the size of the team that registered a patent (number of patentees) is generally not a significant predictor of patent quality. This is in line with the findings of Nuvolari and Tartari (Reference Nuvolari and Tartari2011) on English patents in the same period. The coefficient of the variable experience is positive and significant, although this result does not seem very robust, and the effect is relatively small. The coefficient of the variable famous inventor is positive and significant, and relatively robust across specifications, with a sizable effect—between 320 and 380 days. This result, obtained with a multivariate regression, confirms the descriptive statistics reported in Table 5, further corroborating our indicator of patent quality. The coefficient of the variable engineer/scientist is positive and significant, indicating an important role for relatively sophisticated engineering competences in the development of high-quality innovations. On the other hand, the coefficient of the variable skilled worker is negative and significant, which may suggest a scarcity of skilled workers acquainted with the implementation of modern industrial machinery, as also testified by the intense migration flows of high-quality craftsmen from Britain to France.Footnote 57 This picture is also consistent with the view that the crucial needs of modern manufacturing, even before the rise of the science-based sectors in the second half of the nineteenth century, were met more by a growing science-oriented and highly educated elite than through more traditional models of apprenticeship (Fox Reference Fox2012). The coefficient of the variable high-tech sectors is positive and significant, as expected. Footnote 58

Table 7 presents a number of regressions in which the sample includes only patents granted to at least one French resident (i.e., it excludes patents taken exclusively by foreign residence patentees). In general, all the results presented in Table 6 carry through in this setting. The coefficient of award is positive and significant in all specifications, confirming, in a multivariate framework, the positive relation between award and patent quality emerging from Table 5. Somewhat surprisingly, the coefficient of literacy rates has a small impact on patent quality: an increase of 1 percentage point in literacy rates results in a reduction of 1–2 days in terms of patent duration. Notably, while remaining relatively small, this effect becomes positive when the sample excludes withdrawn patents. A possible interpretation could be that patenting activity was relatively more dynamic in departments where basic education was more widespread. In these locations, competition was also fiercer, possibly leading to a higher rate of withdrawn patents due to more intense litigation. A similar pattern is also visible for the two geographical covariates (Rouen-Geneva line and Port distance). Both coefficients point to a positive effect only in settings without withdrawn patents.

Table 7 DETERMINANTS OF PATENT QUALITY IN FRANCE (ONLY DOMESTIC PATENTS)

Notes: Dependent variable is “real” patent duration in days. OLS regressions with robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Models (4) and (8) do not include withdrawn patents.

Source: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset.

The limited impact and instability of the coefficients of these two latter variables, when compared to the magnitude and robust significant effect of British Connection (BC), suggest the prominent role played in technology transfers by direct social contacts rather than geographical proximity.

As a general robustness check for our analysis, Online Appendix Table A8 presents a number of regressions that use alternative indicators of patent quality as dependent variables. The results confirm our findings in terms of the significance and magnitude of the estimated effects of our two key explanatory variables, British Origins (BO) and British Connection (BC).

The literature on French industrialization (Crouzet Reference Crouzet, Teich and Porter1996) has pointed out that before being adopted in France, British technologies had to be tailored and non-trivially modified because factor endowments differed in the two countries. We thus provide new insights regarding this issue by studying the relationship between the distribution of patents across technologies in the “exporting” country (Britain) and that in the “receiving” country (France). Table 8 reports the Bar-Leiponen measure of technological distance between all patents granted in Britain to: (i) patents granted in France with British origin (BO); (ii) patents granted in France with British connections (BC); and (iii) domestic French patents.

Table 8 BAR-LEIPONEN MEASURE OF TECHNOLOGY DISTANCE

Notes: The table reports the Bar-Leiponen measure of technological distance between the sets of patents listed in the first column. See the main text for full details.

Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for French patents and Nuvolari and Tartari (Reference Nuvolari and Tartari2011) for British ones.

In the upper panel of Table 8, a 17-industry classification enables us to match the 21-industry classification for English patents constructed by Nuvolari and Tartari (Reference Nuvolari and Tartari2011) with the 20-industry classification for French patents adopted in this paper. The matching is not perfect because the criteria used to allocate patents in the different classes reflect the features of the original sources.Footnote 59 Even with this caveat, the results are interesting. Indeed, the technological distance is minimal between the English technological frontier (represented by all English patents) and British origins (BO) patents in France; it is intermediate between the English technological frontier and the British connections (BC) patents; and it is maximum between the English technological frontier and the entire distribution of domestic patents in France. The lower panel of Table 8 shows a study of technological distance using only the French patent sample (organized into 20 patent classes). In this case, given that the criteria for allocating patents to different classes are homogeneous, the results might be more accurate. The reference point from which the distance is computed is the entire French patent sample. Reassuringly, the results reported in the upper and lower panels of Table 8 are consistent. Indeed, the lower panel shows that the distance between the entire French patent sample and British connection (BC) patents is minimal and that between the entire French patent sample and British origin (BO) patents it is much higher. Furthermore, the distance between the entire French patent sample and that of foreign (non-British) patents is the maximum. In general, these findings hold when breaking down the sample according to different patent quality levels.

A possible interpretation of Table 8 is that patents of British origin mirrored the sectoral distribution of the English technological frontier, and, for this reason, they were probably an attempt to directly transfer British inventions to France. Instead, British connection patents, in terms of sectoral distribution, had an intermediate position between the English technological frontier and French patenting overall. This suggests that British-connected inventors were actually involved in attempts to adapt British technologies to local conditions. For example, several French inventors focused on the improvements and development of water-power technologies, expanding on the work carried out by John Smeaton and John Rennie during the eighteenth century in England. These efforts culminated in the development of the water turbine by Benoit Fourneyron in 1837, which provided an effective alternative solution to steam power in coal-expensive regions such as France and New England (Mokyr Reference Mokyr1990, pp. 90–92). Even in the case of an iconic British technology such as the steam engine, French inventors made significant improvements that enhanced the fit of this technology to the French context. In the first half of the nineteenth century, the most common engine in French mills was the high-pressure Woolf compound engine, which was imported from England by Humphrey Edwards with a French patent of importation granted on 17 May 1815. In comparison with Watt’s low-pressure engine—which remained the standard technology in British manufacturing districts until the 1840s—the Woolf engine permitted substantial fuel savings. By 1824, some 300 Edwards-Woolf engines had already been installed in France. This design was further improved during the 1820s and 1830s (Nuvolari Reference Nuvolari2010). It is also interesting to note that, according to Fox (Reference Fox and Carnot1986), the adaptation of British technology to the French context stimulated major scientific developments such as Carnot’s theorem of thermodynamics. A similar pattern of rapid introduction followed by streams of domestic improvements characterized the importation into France of steel-making technologies based on coke. In this case, the patent of importation granted to James Jackson on 26 January 1819 was flanked by a special grant from the government. According to Horn (Reference Horn2006, p. 256), the investment “paid impressive dividends for national industrial performance and international competitiveness.”

DISCUSSION

Overall, our analysis of French patenting activity highlights the effectiveness of the French national innovation system, which was characterized by intense flows of technology from the leading country (Britain), coupled with a robust capacity to absorb innovations and adapt them to the domestic context. This picture is consistent with other measures of innovative performance not based on patents. Indeed, Figure 7 provides an exploratory sketch of the evolution of scientific and technological capabilities in Britain, France, and the United States using two sources containing lists of major scientific discoveries and inventions (Sorokin Reference Sorokin1937, p. 150; Streit Reference Streit1954, p. 239 ff.). Interestingly, although constructed independently, the two sources offer similar results. Looking at Sorokin’s data, represented by lines in the figure, France is never far from the English level over the entire period considered. Streit’s data, represented in bars, show a somewhat larger gap between England and France; however, France performs notably and visibly better than the United States, at least from the mid-nineteenth century.Footnote 60

Further evidence of a creditable French technological performance is also provided by Moser (Reference Moser2002), who shows that France outperformed all other visiting countries in terms of number of medals per capita at the Crystal Palace Exhibition in 1851. At the same Exhibition, as far as the high-tech industry of scientific instruments is concerned, France was the leading country after Britain (Brenni Reference Brenni2010).Footnote 61 Relatedly, trade data indicate that France was the largest importer of machinery from Britain in the early 1840s, confirming that by that period, France had managed to adopt and use sophisticated industrial technologies initially engineered abroad (Bruland Reference Bruland1989, p. 149).

CONCLUSIONS

In this paper, we have provided fresh evidence that corroborates a more optimistic view of French industrialization. In particular, we have examined a crucial aspect of the catching-up process of a follower country, which is the capability to absorb and adapt technologies developed by the leaders. Our study of French patent activity reveals the existence of a significant volume of high-quality British inventions imported into France. We have also shown that the French inventors who engaged with these technology flows were also capable, in turn, of developing significant innovations.

Overall, this assessment confirms the conjecture by Crouzet (Reference Crouzet2003, p. 234), who noted that “The French managed to learn British technology and adapt it to local conditions; […] so that French scientists and engineers made a considerable contribution in this field and France became at mid-century [1850] a center of invention and diffusion for modern technologies.” From a broader perspective, according to Mokyr (Reference Mokyr2021, p. 241), England and France embodied two different traditions of knowledge generation within the Industrial Enlightenment. The English were more specialized in tacit knowledge, empirical skills, and learning-by-doing, while the French were mainly oriented towards codified knowledge and theoretical understanding. In line with this conjecture, we offer a positive assessment of the French accumulation of social capabilities by means of investments in scientific and engineering education (Fox Reference Fox2012).Footnote 62 Indeed, our results show that inventors with this formalized educational background were more likely to produce valuable patents than artisans or skilled workers. In this respect, Mokyr (2019) argues that upper-tail human capital consisted of a tiny elite of two overlapping groups: “intellectuals” and “top-rated artisans.” Our results reveal that in France, the former played a predominant role in fostering innovative activities during a period of rapid expansion of the technological frontier.Footnote 63

Our study also shows that French inventors who had personal contacts with their British counterparts developed innovations that were close to the technological frontier, notwithstanding the different resource endowments. At the same time, these inventors also successfully adapted British technologies to local conditions.

Our analysis also contributes to the debate on the comparative performance of patent systems in their early phases of development (MacLeod and Nuvolari Reference MacLeod and Nuvolari2016). In the case of the industrialization of the United States, several papers have emphasized the role of discriminatory clauses against foreign inventors, while American inventors were incentivized to patent small adaptations and modifications of British technologies (Mowery Reference Mowery, Odagiri, Goto, Sunami and Nelson2010).Footnote 64 Rather than adopting discriminatory clauses, France’s policy was to try and foster technology inflows by granting complete access to the patent system to foreign inventors. Our results indicate that this strategy was effective since France was able to import high-quality technologies from Britain through this non-discriminatory approach.Footnote 65

This is not a trivial finding since, in the same period, foreign technologies imported into Britain, where access to the patent system was much more expensive and selective, were of lower quality than domestic inventions (Nuvolari and Tartari Reference Nuvolari and Tartari2011). This evidence also suggests the general attractiveness of the French context, which was characterized by both the crucial role of patent agents—who selected valuable technologies and helped foreign inventors effectively navigate the patent system—and the ability of French engineers to put foreign technologies into practice.

Although our findings support a more optimistic view of French industrialization, further research is needed to reassess this issue. First, a comprehensive investigation of the effectiveness of interventionist policies à la Chaptal adopted by the French state is still lacking. Second, a quantitative analysis of the French patent system in the second half of the nineteenth century could lead to a broader understanding of French technological performance in the long run.

Footnotes

We are particularly grateful to Steeve Gallizia for granting access to the Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset and for his insightful comments on the data and their historical context. We would like to thank Julio Garbers for his outstanding research assistance, Olivier Gergaud, Morgane Louenan, and Etienne Wasmer for sharing their data on historically notable inventors, and Michel Serafinelli for useful advice on historical biographic databases. We also thank Pierre Alexandre Balland, Jérôme Baudry, Gabriele Cappelli, Alexander Donges, Bart Los, Adrien Montalbo, Leonardo Ridolfi, Felix Selgert, Jochen Streb, Mara Squicciarini, Nico Voigtländer, and participants to the Economic History Society (virtual annual conference 2021), to seminars at the University of Utrecht, the University of Mannheim, University of Oxford and the University of Lund for helpful suggestions. The comments of three anonymous referees and the editor (Dan Bogart) are also gratefully acknowledged. Michelangelo Vasta wishes to thank Université Paris 1 – Panthéon-Sorbonne for financial support during his visiting period.

1 Mokyr (Reference Mokyr1990, p. 240) cites, approvingly, this statement of a Swiss calico printer, Jean Ryhiner, who, in 1766, characterized French and English technological capabilities as: “They [the British] cannot boast of many inventions but only of having perfected the inventions of others; whence comes to the proverb that for a thing to be perfect it must be invented in France and worked out in England.” Originally cited by Wadsworth and Mann (1931, p. 413).

2 For useful discussions of technology transfer from a historical perspective, see Wilkins (Reference Wilkins1974) and Rosenberg (Reference Rosenberg1976).

3 For an appraisal of technology transfer between Britain and France during the eighteenth century, see Harris (Reference Harris1998).

4 See the cases of Humphrey Edwards for steam power (Nuvolari Reference Nuvolari2010), James Jackson for iron making (Horn Reference Horn2006, pp. 245–248; Belhoste and Woronoff Reference Belhoste, Woronoff, Evans and Rydén2005), and for an overview of textile technologies, see Henderson (Reference Henderson1972, pp. 10–36).

5 In the case of steam power technology, see the importation of Watt’s steam engine by the Périer brothers (Payen Reference Payen1969).

6 Generally, patents provide an incentive to foreign inventors to develop and transfer technology to a foreign market, but at the same time, they can be used strategically to block imitations by domestic inventors. From the point of view of the latter, the disclosure effect of the patent may represent a further incentive for imitation. Saiz (Reference Saiz2014) on Spain and Donges and Selgert (Reference Donges and Selgert2019) on Germany have studied patterns of technology transfer using patent data.

7 For a thorough survey of the historiography of French economic growth during the nineteenth century, see Crouzet (Reference Crouzet2003).

8 In the same vein, Horn (Reference Horn2006) claimed that, since the Congress of Vienna up to the mid-nineteenth century, French industry grew rapidly, though not as fast as in Britain. Horn also provides a decidedly favorable picture of the industrial and innovation policies adopted by the French state. This revisionist perspective also emerges in the study by Juhasz (Reference Juhasz2018), who reports a positive impact of the Napoleonic Blockade, enacted in 1806, on the expansion of mechanized cotton spinning. A favorable impression of French industrial modernization also emerges from a micro-level study by Juhasz, Squicciarini, and Voigtländer (Reference Juhasz, Squicciarini and Voigtländer2020). Finally, Hallmann, Rosenberger, and Yavuz (Reference Hallmann, Rosenberger and Yavuz2021) used patent data to reveal the creditable innovative performance of France. Their study highlighted France’s prominent position in water-intensive technologies, while emphasizing the leadership of the United Kingdom in coal-intensive industries.

9 The most recent estimates of French GDP per capita show stagnation during the eighteenth century and relatively rapid growth in the first half of the nineteenth century, with an annual growth of GDP per capita of 0.86 percent (1800–1850). In contrast, in the same period, Britain had a growth rate of 0.21 percent; see Ridolfi and Nuvolari (Reference Ridolfi and Nuvolari2021) and Broadberry et al. (Reference Broadberry, Bruce Campbell, Overton and van Leeuwen2015).

10 The issuing of patents was regulated by two different laws, both promulgated in 1791. The first, approved on 7 January, outlined the general principles concerning the rights of the patentees and the validity of the patents, while the second, approved on 25 May, set out the detailed rules for the application and granting of the patents. Hereafter, these two pieces of legislation are referred to as the 1791 Law.

11 Baudry (Reference Baudry2019) has shown that an unofficial examination process, entrusted to the Comité consultatif des arts e métiers, was reinstated just a few years after the enactment of the 1791 law. However, the inventor was allowed to register his patent despite the negative assessment of the Comité. In any case, the evidence unearthed by Baudry suggests that this examination was not perfunctory. About 20 percent of patent applications were withdrawn after the assessment of the Comité (Baudry Reference Baudry2019, p. 72).

12 In other words, foreign inventors could take patents in France (i.e., there was no discrimination against foreign inventors) and French patentees could import technologies developed in other countries.

13 Initially, the fees were for the same amounts in livres tournois. They were converted into francs in 1795 (Galvez-Behar Reference Galvez-Behar2019, p. 36). Baudry (Reference Baudry2020) notices that the structure of the fees shows that the intention of the legislator was to limit the duration of patent protection since a 10-year patent costs more than two 5-year patents and a 15-year patent costs more than the sum of a 10-year and 5-year patent. This might suggest that the legislation was conceived to explicitly limit long-lasting monopolies and stimulate competition.

14 This fee was relatively expensive since it exceeded the fee required to take out a new 5-year patent and it covered only 5-year extensions. As far as 15-year patents are concerned, only the Royal Court could decide whether they could be further extended. According to Perpigna (Reference Perpigna1832, pp. 87–88), from 1791 to 1832, only 20 patents were prolonged. Unfortunately, Perpigna does not provide a complete list of these prolongations.

15 For a similar interpretation, see also Galvez-Behar (Reference Galvez-Behar2019).

16 In addition to patent fees, Khan (Reference Khan2005, pp. 43–44) also refers to the working clause as a factor limiting the effective use of the patent system for ordinary inventors.

17 In addition to the previously mentioned cases, a peculiarity of the 1791 French law was that it also established that a patent was withdrawn if a patentee took out a patent for the same invention in a foreign country. The rationale for this provision is not entirely clear. In any case, it is doubtful that it had practical relevance in terms of the number of patents withdrawn (Perpigna Reference Perpigna1832, p. 76).

18 The early use of patent statistics as indicators of patenting activity can be ascribed to the contributions by Kuznets (Reference Kuznets1930, p. 54 ff.), Merton (Reference Merton1935), and Sorokin (Reference Sorokin1937, p. 162 ff.).

19 As pointed out by Griliches (Reference Griliches1990, p. 1661): “In this desert of [innovation] data, patent statistics loom up as a mirage of wonderful plentitude and objectivity.” Following the pioneering contributions of Dutton (Reference Dutton1984) and Sokoloff (Reference Sokoloff1988), the use of patents as innovation indicators has developed into a consolidated research tradition in economic history. For a survey of this stream of literature, see Moser (Reference Moser2016).

20 In the period in question, there were several exhibitions and trade fairs showcasing developments in industrial technology, such as the Exposition des produits de l’industrie française (Horn Reference Horn2006, pp. 186–205). These sources have not yet been explored using a quantitative approach and have not been systematically compared with patent records.

21 The dataset contains all patents granted according to the 1791 laws. Thus, with very few exceptions, 1844 ended with patents deposited in October 1844 and granted by the end of the same month.

22 The documentation is publicly accessible online (http://bases-brevets19e.inpi.fr/index.asp) and allows users to browse through the original files.

23 The identification of company patents was carried out by INPI.

24 The dataset and replication files of this paper are available as Nuvolari, Tortorici, and Vasta (2022).

25 Normalizing for population (Maddison Reference Maddison2003), in the 1820s, France granted 8.3 patents per million inhabitants, the United States 23.1, and England 6.4. Remarkably, from 1837 to 1843, France granted 31.8 patents per million inhabitants, the United States 26.6, and England 14.6.

26 Online Appendix Figure A1 shows the evolution of the patents granted in France from 1791–1844.

27 We automated this process through an ad-hoc script that searches single municipality strings within the OpenStreetMap database and geocodes them. This approach minimizes the impact of minor and infrequent spelling mistakes; slight toponym changes are easily accounted for by a system of suggestions à la Google Spell Checker. Unmatched municipalities were manually double-checked so that each location could be identified correctly.

28 The shapefile of the map we used is available at http://www.datavis.ca/gallery/guerry/maps.html. We applied an intuitive approach: a purposely coded script assigned each location to one of the 89 French departments. While included in the econometric analysis, all the maps in the paper exclude the following four departments: Territoire de Belfort, Savoie, Haute-Savoie, and Alpes-Maritimes since they are not included in the 1830 shapefile.

29 Online Appendix Figure A2 shows the distribution of patents granted by municipalities.

30 It is likely that the figures for Paris are overestimated since many non-Parisians went to the capital to register their inventions.

31 Note that this department was excluded from the computation of the scale as it would have made the whole map hard to interpret.

32 According to Braudel (Reference Braudel1984, pp. 337), the “supremacy” of Paris in French economic life dates to the end of the seventeenth century.

33 In the results section, we address this concern by excluding the Seine department from the main econometric specifications.

34 In the literature, there are three characterizations of the North-South divide in France. The original one is by Dupin (1826) and posits a notional line from St. Malo to Geneva; Braudel (Reference Braudel1984) suggests a Rouen-Geneva line, while Crouzet (Reference Crouzet, Teich and Porter1996) argues for a Le-Havre-Marseilles one. We decided to use the Braudel line because it is probably the most well-known. In any case, for our purposes, the differences are minimal.

35 The database contains 15,038 inventors, with 24.1 percent missing values for the occupation field.

36 A similar exercise using the HISCO classification for British patents has been recently carried out by Billington (Reference Billington2021).

37 We differentiated between “small” and “large” proprietors considering the most likely size of the activity. For instance, the string negociant was classified as “small proprietor,” fabricant as “large proprietor.”

38 See Table A2 in the Online Appendix for a list of the most represented professions within each class.

39 The results for England are based on the total number of patents granted. Despite this, the results are consistent with those obtained by Khan, who used a sample of 319 patentees (2005, table 4.1).

40 A related approach is based on the use of information on patent visibility in the relevant engineering and legal literature. See Nuvolari and Tartari (Reference Nuvolari and Tartari2011) for an example of English patents.

41 Admittedly, in the case of highly uncertain innovations, the expectations formulated by the inventor might have been more of a fuzzy guess than a precise assessment.

42 The dataset contains 2,875 withdrawn patents—over a grand total of 12,575—however, we cannot, unfortunately, disentangle the reasons for each individual withdrawal. Hallmann, Rosenberger, and Yavuz (Reference Hallmann, Rosenberger and Yavuz2021) suggest that most of the patents were withdrawn for defaulting on the payment of the second installment fee.

43 While not mentioned in this example, we have considered leap years.

44 Frequency, on the y-axis, is reported in logs because it helps in visualizing the distribution.

45 The matching is mostly based on a string consisting of names and surnames. In order to minimize false positives, we restricted the timeframe of reference to individuals born or active after 1750, depending on what information was available. We also limited the geographical scope of the search.

46 The Société was founded in 1801 with the aim of promoting the modernization of French industry by supporting inventors with prizes and fostering the diffusion of technical knowledge. Jean-Antoine Chaptal (1756–1832), the most influential actor in French industrial policies of the time, played a crucial role in the formation of the Société. According to Horn (Reference Horn2006, p. 203): “The Society contributed to a number of French technological advances and improved techniques with signal successes in the perfection of the Jacquard loom for silks in 1808 and the naturalization of the sugar beet.” For a significantly less positive view of the role of the Société, see Khan (Reference Khan2020, pp. 152–58).

47 When considering the department fixed effects, we also constructed an additional dummy variable comprising all foreign patents.

48 The summary statistics of the variables are presented in Table A4 in the Online Appendix.

49 In order to establish whether the inventor in question had taken an English patent in the period 1791–1852, we carried out a comprehensive matching between all the patentees in our French sample and Woodcroft’s Alphabetical Index (1854).

50 In his autobiography, Nasmyth (Reference Nasmyth1883) describes several trips and interactions with the French business world (in particular with the ironworks of Le Creusot).

51 The total number of BO patents is 1,095, which is broken down into 867 for patentees with a British address, and 228 for those who had filed a patent in Britain within five years before the granting of the French patent.

52 Galvez-Behar (Reference Galvez-Behar2008) shows that in the first decades of the nineteenth century, very few French inventors used patent agents. The most important patent agents involved in the importation of foreign technologies in this period were Charles and Jacques-Eugène Armengaud, Antoine Perpigna, and Louis H. J. Truffaut. For a compact description of their activities, see Peyre (Reference Peyre1994). On the role of patent agents, see also Cotte (Reference Cotte2010). In 1839, Perpigna published an alluring volume illustrating the most important inventions patented abroad (Perpigna Reference Perpigna1839).

53 The total number of BC patents is 412, which is broken down into 365 patents featuring a patent agent previously involved in British technology transfer and 47 patents granted by individuals that had previous patent experience with a British inventor.

54 For Louis Maggiolo’s research, see Fleury and Valmary (Reference Fleury and Valmary1957). For the Seine department, whose data is missing due to the fire of the Paris municipality in 1871 (Furet and Ozouf Reference Furet and Ozouf1977), we proxied the 1790 literacy rate by using the following method. First, we ran a regression, for all French departments apart from the one, between the groom’s literacy rates in 1790 and the literacy (individuals who can read and write plus individuals who can only read) of the military conscripts in 1827–1829, obtaining a coefficient that enabled us to predict the missing values. Then, we applied this coefficient to the literacy rate of the military conscripts of the 12 urban Paris’ arrondissment. Finally, considering that, following the 1801 Census data (Béaur and Marin Reference Béaur and Marin2011, accessed 22 August 2021), the Seine department had a share of urban population of 87 percent and a rural population of 13 percent, we used a weighted average by assigning the new estimate for urban population and the Seine et Oise department value for rural areas of the Seine department. We thus obtained an estimate of the 1790 literacy rate for the Seine department of 79.76 percent.

55 We also estimated specifications, including a measure of distance from London as the crow flies, obtaining very similar results.

56 In Table A5 in the Online Appendix, we separately consider the effect of the two types of BO patents (patentees with and without British residence) on patent quality. The size of the coefficients of the two variables is quite similar. Online Appendix Table A5 also shows similar results for BC patents. Table A6 in the Online Appendix examines the impact on patent quality of foreign non-British patentees. In this case, the coefficients are lower than those of BO and BC patentees.

57 As noted by Kelly, Mokyr, and O’Grada (Reference Kelly, Mokyr and O’Grada2014, p. 376), French workers, thanks to their direct contact with British immigrants, were quick to develop the skills to manage modern technologies. For an assessment of the migration of British workers to France in the nineteenth century, see Bensimon (Reference Bensimon2011).

58 In Table A7 in the Online Appendix, we run the same regressions excluding the Seine department. Results hold, mostly unchanged in their substance.

59 The 1853 French technological classification is mainly based on a sector-of-use approach, while the English classification adopts a combination of sector-of-use and industry-of-manufacture approaches. For a discussion of this issue, see Nuvolari and Vasta (Reference Nuvolari and Vasta2020).

60 Using alternative sources, Grinin and Korotayev (Reference Grinin and Korotayev2015, p. 170 ff.) showed that in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, France was just behind Britain in terms of major technological inventions.

61 The French instrument industry was still severely backward at the end of the eighteenth century (Kelly and O’Grada Reference Kelly and O’Grada2022), while it experienced rapid growth, both in production and in competitiveness, during the first half of the nineteenth century (Turner Reference Turner1989).

62 Similar results are presented by Hanlon (Reference Hanlon2021) and Nuvolari, Tartari, and Tranchero (Reference Nuvolari, Tartari and Tranchero2021) for England.

63 Squicciarini and Voigtländer (Reference Squicciarini and Voigtländer2015) show the critical role of “enlightened elites” in France using Encyclopedie subscriptions as a synthetic indicator of upper-tail human capital.

64 Another interesting case of the successful use of discriminatory measures against foreign inventors in the first half of the nineteenth century is the German state of Wuerttemberg (Lehmann-Hasemeyer and Streb Reference Lehmann-Hasemeyer and Streb2020).

65 In a broader perspective, this finding suggests that national patent laws alone do not directly determine innovation performance. Instead, their impact is always intertwined with other countries’ characteristics such as resource endowments, human capital, size of the economy, etc. (Streb Reference Streb2023).

References

REFERENCES

Abramovitz, Moses. “Catching Up, Forging Ahead and Falling Behind.” Journal of Economic History 46, no. 2 (1986): 385406.10.1017/S0022050700046209CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, Donald. “Wage Rates in the Early National Period: Philadelphia, 1785–1830.” Journal of Economic History 28, no. 3 (1968): 404–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bar, Talia, and Leiponen, Aija. “A Measure of Technological Distance.” Economics Letters 116 (2012): 457–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baudry, Jérôme. “Une histoire de la propriété intellectuelle. Les brevets d’invention en France, 1791–1844: Acteurs, catégories, pratiques.” Ph.D. thesis, École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Paris, 2014.Google Scholar
Baudry, Jérôme. “Examining Inventions, Shaping Property: The Savants and the French Patent System.” History of Science 57, no. 1 (2019): 6280.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baudry, Jérôme. “A Politics of Intellectual Property: The French Revolution and the Creation of a Patent System.” Technology and Culture 61, no. 4 (2020): 1017–44.10.1353/tech.2020.0109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Béaur, Gérard, and Marin, Béatrice. “La Statistique Générale de la France – Présentation’, L’Atelier du Centre de recherches historiques [online], La Statistique Générale de la France,” 2011. Available at http://journals.openedition.org/acrh/2891.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belhoste, Bruno. Paris Savant. Capital of Science in the Age of Enlightenment. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Belhoste, Jean-François, and Woronoff, Denis. “The French Iron and Steel Industry during the Industrial Revolution.” In The Industrial Revolution in Iron: The Impact of British Coal Technology in Nineteenth-Century Europe, edited by Evans, Chris and Rydén, Göran, 7594. Aldershot: Ashgate, 2005.Google Scholar
Bensimon, Fabrice. “British Workers in France, 1815–1848.” Past and Present 213 (2011): 147–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Billington, Stephen D.What Explains Patenting Behaviour during Britain’s Industrial Revolution.” Explorations in Economic History 82 (2021): 101426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bottomley, Sean. The British Patent System during the Industrial Revolution, 1700–1852. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braudel, Fernand. The Perspective of the World. Civilization and Capitalism 15 th –18 th Century. London: Phoenix Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Brenni, Paolo. “La science française au Crystal Palace.” Documents pour l’histoire des techniques 19, no. 2 (2010): 255–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, Stephen, Bruce Campbell, Alexander Klein, Overton, Mark, and van Leeuwen, Bas. British Economic Growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015.Google Scholar
Bruland, Kristine. British Technology and European Industrialization. The Norwegian Textile Industry in the Mid Nineteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cotte, Michel. “La diffusion des techniques pendant la ‘revolution industrielle’. Les comportements de veille et le role des échanges intenatiounaux.” Traverse: Zeitschrift fur Geschichte 17 (2010): 2136.Google Scholar
Crafts, N. F. R.Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1830–1910. A Review of the Evidence.” Journal of Economic History 44, no. 1 (1984): 4967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crouzet, François. “France.” In The Industrial Revolution in National Context, edited by Teich, Mikulas and Porter, Roy, 3663. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996.Google Scholar
Crouzet, François. “The Historiography of French Economic Growth in the Nineteenth Century.” Economic History Review 56, no. 2 (2003): 215–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, C. R.The Making of Mechanical Engineers in France: The Ecoles d’Arts et Métiers, 1803–1914.” French Historical Studies 10, no. 3 (1978): 439–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donges, Alexander, and Selgert, Felix. “Technology Transfer via Foreign Patents in Germany, 1843–1877.” Economic History Review 72, no. 1 (2019): 182208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charles, Dupin. Effets de l’enseignement populaire de la lecture, de l’écriture et de l’arithmétique, de la géométrie et de la méchanique, appliquées aux arts, sur les prospérités de la France, discours prononcé dans la séance d’ouverture du cours normal de géométrie et de mécanique appliquées, le 29 novembre 1826, au Conservatoire des arts et métiers. Paris: Bachelier, 1826.Google Scholar
Dutton, H. I. The Patent System and Inventive Activity during the Industrial Revolution, 1750–1852. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Empotz, Gérard, and Marchal, Valérie. Aux sources de la propriété industrielle: Guides des archives de I’INPI. Paris: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle, 2002.Google Scholar
Fleury, Michel, and Valmary, Pierre. “Les Progres de l’Instruction Elementaire de Louis XIV a Napoleon III d’apres l’Enquete de L. Maggiolo (I877–79).” Population XII (1957): 71–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, Robert. “Introduction.” In Reflextions on the Motive Power of Fire. A Critical Edition with the Surviving Scientific Manuscripts, edited by Carnot, Sadi, 157. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Fox, Robert. The Savant and the State. Science and Cultural Politics in Nineteenth France. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press, 2012. Google Scholar
Furet, François, and Ozouf, Jacques. Lire et écrire. L’alphabètisation des Francais de Calvin à Jules Ferry. Paris: Le Editions de Minuit, 1977.Google Scholar
Galvez-Behar, Gabriel. La République des inventeurs. Propriété et organization de l’innovation en France (1791–1922). Rennes: Presses Universitaires de Rennes, 2008.Google Scholar
Galvez-Behar, Gabriel. “The Patent System during the French Industrial Revolution: Institutional Change and Economic Effects.” Jahrbuch fur Wirtschaftsgeschichte 60, no. 1 (2019): 3156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gergaud, Olivier, Louenan, Morgane, and Wasmer, Etienne. “A Brief History of Human Time. Exploring a Database of ‘Notable People’ (3000BCE–2015AD) Version 1.0.1.” Sciences Po Economics Discussion Papers no. 2016-03, SciencesPo, Paris, France, 2016.Google Scholar
Gerschenkron, Alexander. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1962.Google Scholar
Griliches, Zvi. “Patent Statistics as Economic Indicator: A Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 28, no. 4 (1990): 1661–707.Google Scholar
Grinin, Leonid, and Korotayev, Andrey. Great Divergence and Great Convergence. A Global Perspective. Heidelberg: Springer, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hallmann, Carl, Rosenberger, Lukas, and Yavuz, Emre E.. “Invention and Technological Leadership during the Industrial Revolution.” Mimeo, 2021.Google Scholar
Hanlon, W. Walker. “The Rise of the Engineer: Inventing the Professional Inventor during the Industrial Revolution.” Mimeo, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, John R. Industrial Espionage and Technology Transfer. Britain and France in the Eighteenth Century. London: Routledge, 1998.Google Scholar
Henderson, W. O. Britain and Industrial Europe, 1750–1870. Leicester: Leicester University Press, 1972.Google Scholar
Hilaire-Perez, Liliane. L’invention technique aux siècle des Lumieres. Paris: Albin Michel, 2000.Google Scholar
Horn, Jeff. The Path Not Taken. French Industrialization in the Age of Revolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Jeremy, D. J.Damning the Flood: British Government Efforts to Check the Outflow of Technicians and Machinery, 1780–1843.” Business History 51, no. 1 (1977): 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Juhasz, Réka. “Temporary Protection and Technology Adoption: Evidence from the Napoleonic Blockade.” American Economic Review 108, no. 11 (2018): 3339–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Juhasz, Réka, Squicciarini, Mara, and Voigtländer, Nico. “Technology Adoption and Productivity Growth: Evidence from Industrialization in France.” NBER Working Paper No. 27503, Cambridge, MA, July 2020.Google Scholar
Kelly, Morgan, Mokyr, Joel, and O’Grada, Cormac. “Precociuos Albion: A New Interpretation of the British Industrial Revolution.” Annual Review of Economics 6 (2014): 363–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelly, Morgan, Mokyr, Joel, and O’Grada, Cormac. “Could Artisans Have Caused the Industrial Revolution?” In Reinventing the Economic History of Industrialization, edited by Bruland, Kristine, Gerritsen, Anne, Hudson, Pat, and Riello, Giorgio, 2543. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 2020.Google Scholar
Kelly, Morgan, and O’Grada, Cormac. “Connecting the Scientific and Industrial Revolutions: The Role of Practical Mathematics.” Journal of Economic History 82, no. 3 (2022): 841–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khan, B. Zorina. The Democratization of Invention: Patents and Copyrights in American Economic Development, 1790–1920. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Khan, B. Zorina. “An Economic History of Patent Institutions.” In EH.Net Encyclopedia, edited by Whaples, R., 2008. Available at http://eh.net/encyclopedia/an-economic-history-of-patent-institutions/.Google Scholar
Khan, B. Zorina. “Invisible Women: Entrepreneurship, Innovation, and Family Firms in Nineteenth France.” Journal of Economic History 76, no. 1 (2016): 163–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khan, B. Zorina. Inventing Ideas: Patents, Prizes and the Knowledge Economy. New York: Oxford University Press, 2020.10.1093/oso/9780190936075.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zorina, Khan, B., and Sokoloff, Kenneth. “ ‘Schemes of Practical Utility’: Entrepreneurship and Innovation among ‘Great Inventors’ in the United States, 1790–1865.” Journal of Economic History 53, no. 1 (1993): 289307.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. Secular Movements in Production and Prices. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin, 1930.Google Scholar
Landes, David S.French Entrepreneurship and Industrial Growth in the Nineteenth Century.” Journal of Economic History 9, no. 1 (1949): 4561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, David S. The Unbound Prometheus. Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Lehmann-Hasemeyer, Sibylle, and Streb, Jochen. “Discrimination against Foreigners: The Wuerttemberg Patent Law in Administrative Practice.” Journal of Economic History 80, no. 4 (2020): 1071–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacLeod, Christine, and Nuvolari, Alessandro. “Inventive Activities, Patents and Early Industrialisation: A Synthesis of Research Issues.” Rivista di Storia Economica 32, no. 1 (2016): 77107.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus. The World Economy: Historical Economics. Paris: OECD, 2003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, Robert K.Fluctuations in the Rate of Industrial Invention.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 49, no. 1 (1935): 454–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. The Lever of Riches. Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. New York-Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. “‘The Holy Land of Industrialism’: Rethinking the Industrial Revolution.” Journal of the British Academy 9 (2021): 223–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, Petra. “The Determinants of Innovation. New Evidence from Nineteenth-Century World Fairs.” Ph.D. thesis, University of California, Berkeley, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, Petra. “How Do Patents Laws Influence Innovation? Evidence from Nineteenth-Century World’s Fairs.” American Economic Review 95, no. 4 (2005): 1214–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, Petra. “Innovation without Patents: Evidence from World’s Fairs.” Journal of Law and Economics 55, no. 1 (2012): 4374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, Petra. “Patents and Innovation in Economic History.” Annual Review of Economics 8 (2016): 241–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mowery, David. “IPR and US Economic Catch-up.” In Intellectual Property Rights, Development and Catch-Up. An International Comparative Study, edited by Odagiri, Hiroyuki, Goto, Akira, Sunami, Atsushi, and Nelson, Richard, 3162. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murray, Charles. Human Accomplishment. The Pursuit of Excellence in the Arts and Sciences, 800 B.C. to 1950. New York: Harper and Collins, 2003.Google Scholar
Nasmyth, James. James Nasmyth Engineer. An Autobiography. London: John Murray, 1883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicholas, Tom. “The Role of Independent Invention in U.S. Technological Development, 1880–1930.” Journal of Economic History 70, no. 1 (2010): 5782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nuvolari, Alessandro. “The Theory and Practice of Steam Engineering in Britain and in France, 1800–1850.” Documents pour l’histoire des techniques 19, no. 2 (2010): 177–85.Google Scholar
Nuvolari, Alessandro, and Tartari, Valentina. “Bennet Woodcroft and the Value of English Patents, 1617–1841.” Explorations in Economic History 48, no. 1 (2011): 97115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nuvolari, Alessandro, Tartari, Valentina, and Tranchero, Matteo. “Patterns of Innovation during the Industrial Revolution: A Reappraisal Using a Composite Indicator of Patent Quality.” Explorations in Economic History 82 (2021): 101419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nuvolari, Alessandro, Tortorici, Gaspare, and Vasta, Michelangelo. “British-French Technology Transfer from the Revolution to Louis Philippe (1791–1844): Evidence from Patent Data.” Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2022-08-24. https://doi.org/10.3886/E178661V2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nuvolari, Alessandro, and Vasta, Michelangelo. “Independent Invention in Italy during the Liberal Age, 1861–1913.” Economic History Review 68, no. 3 (2015): 858–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nuvolari, Alessandro, and Vasta, Michelangelo. “The Geography of Innovation in Italy, 1861–1913: Evidence from Patent Data.” European Review of Economic History 21, no. 3 (2017): 326–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nuvolari, Alessandro, and Vasta, Michelangelo. “Pavitt’s Taxonomy in Historical Perspective: Evidence from Italian Industrialization, 1861–1936.” Mimeo, 2020.Google Scholar
O’Brien, Patrick, and Keyder, Caglar. Economic Growth in Britain and France 1780–1914. Two Paths to the Twentieth Century. London: Allen & Unwin, 1978.Google Scholar
Payen, Jacques. Capital et machine a vapeur au XVIIIe Siecle. Les freres Perier et l’introduction en France de la machine a vapeur de Watt. Paris: Mouton, 1969.Google Scholar
Perpigna, A. The French Law and Practice of Patents for Inventions, Improvements and Importations. London: Newton & Berry, 1832.Google Scholar
Perpigna, A. Repertoire de l’Industrie Etrangere ou Dessins et Descriptions des Machines le plus importantes brevetees a l’etranger. Paris: Alphonse Monginot, 1839.Google Scholar
Peyre, P.Les Armengaud, la ‘petite ecole’ et le developpement de l’innovation.” Les Cahiers de l’Histoire du CNAM 4 (1994): 93142.Google Scholar
Ridolfi, Leonardo, and Nuvolari, Alessandro. “ L’histoire immobile? A Reappraisal of French Economic Growth Using the Demand-Side Approach, 1280–1850.” European Review of Economic History 25, no. 3 (2021): 405–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. “Anglo-American Wage Differences in the 1820s.” Journal of Economic History 27, no. 2 (1967): 221–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. Perspectives on Technology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1976.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saiz, Patricio. “Did Patents of Introduction Encourage Technology Transfer? Long-Term Evidence from the Spanish Innovation System.” Cliometrica 8, no. 1 (2014): 3959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schankerman, Mark, and Pakes, Ariel. “Estimates of the Value of Patent Rights in European Countries during the Post-1950 Period.” Economic Journal 96 (1986): 1052–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schich, Maximilian, Chaoming Song, Yong-Yeol Ahn, Alexander Mirsky, Mauro Martino, Barabási, Albert-László, and Helbing, Dirk. “A Network Framework of Cultural History.” Science 345 (2014): 558–62.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schmookler, Jacob. Invention and Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, 1966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sokoloff, Kenneth. “Inventive Activity in Early Industrial America: Evidence from Patent Records, 1791–1846.” Journal of Economic History 48, no. 4 (1988): 813–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sokoloff, Kenneth, and Zorina Khan, B.. “The Democratization of Invention during Early Industrialization: Evidence from the United States, 1790–1846.” Journal of Economic History 50, no. 2 (1990): 363–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sorokin, Pitirim A. Social and Cultural Dynamics. Fluctuations of System of Truth, Ethics, and Law, vol. 2. New York: American Book Company, 1937.Google Scholar
Squicciarini, Mara, and Voigtländer, Nico. “Human Capital and Industrialization: Evidence from the Age of the Enlightenment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 130, no. 4 (2015): 1825–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Streb, Jochen. “The Cliometric Study of Innovations.” In Handbook of Cliometrics, edited by Diebolt, Claude and Haupert, Michael, 446–68. Berlin-Heidelberg: Springer, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Streb, Jochen. “Patent Law and Economic Performance.” Rivista di Storia Economica/Italian Review of Economic History 39, no. 1 (2023): 326.Google Scholar
Streb, Jochen, Baten, Joerg, and Yin, Shuxi. “Technological and Geographical Knowledge Spillover in the German Empire, 1877–1918.” Economic History Review 59, no. 2 (2006): 347–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Streit, Clarence K. Freedom Against Itself. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1954.Google Scholar
Turner, A. J. From Pleasure and Profit to Science and Security: Etienne Lenoir and the Transformation of Precision Instrument Making in France 1760–1830. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Van Leeuwen, Marco, Maas, Ineke, and Miles, Andrew. Hisco-Historical Standard Classification of Occupations. Leiden: Leiden University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Wadsworth, Alfred P., and De Lacy Mann, Julia. The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1931.Google Scholar
Wilkins, Mira. “The Role of Private Business in the International Diffusion of Technology.” Journal of Economic History 34, no. 1 (1974): 166–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodcroft, B. Alphabetical Index of Patentees of Inventions. London: G. E. Eyre and W. Spottiswoode, 1854.Google Scholar
Yu, Amy Z., Shahar Ronen, Kevin Hu, Lu, Tiffany, and Hidalgo, César A.. “Pantheon 1.0, A Manually Verified Dataset of Globally Famous Biographies.” Scientific data 3 (2016): 150075.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figure 0

Figure 1 COST OF PATENTING BY COUNTRY, CIRCA 1825–30Notes: The figure reports the cost—in U.S. dollars and in working days—for a patent granted for 15 years in France and for 14 years in England and the United States.Sources: The cost for a patent in England and the United States is from Khan (2005), while for France it is based on the 25 May 1791 patent law. The conversion rate in dollars is based on Rosenberg (1967). The wages of a mechanic are from Rosenberg (1967). The wage of masons in England (London) and in France (Paris) are from Allen (https://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/people/sites/allen-research-pages/), while for the United States (Philadelphia) are from Adams (1968).

Figure 1

Table 1 DISTRIBUTION OF PATENTS BY COUNTRY AND SUB-PERIODS

Figure 2

Figure 2 NUMBER OF PATENTS GRANTED IN FRANCE BY DEPARTMENT (1791–1844)Notes: Darker areas indicate a higher number of patents. The maps also report the Rouen-Geneva line.Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents and http://www.datavis.ca/gallery/guerry/maps.html for the map of France Department boundaries of 1830.

Figure 3

Figure 3 NUMBER OF PATENTS GRANTED IN FRANCE BY PATENTEES’ OCCUPATION (1791–1844)Notes: The occupational HISCO categories and ownership status are the following: 0_1 = small proprietor; 0_2 = large proprietor; 1 = higher manager; 2 = higher professionals; 3 = lower manager; 4 = lower professionals, and clerical and sales personnel; 5 = lower clerical and sales personnel; 6 = foremen (artisans); 7 = medium skilled workers; 8 = farmers and fishermen; 9 = lower skilled workers; 10 = lower skilled farm workers; 11 = unskilled workers.Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents and Van Leeuwen, Maas, and Miles (2002) for HISCO occupations.

Figure 4

Figure 4 SHARE OF “ONE-OFF” PATENTEES OVER TOTAL PATENTS BY COUNTRIES (1791–1842)Notes: Data for France and England consist of the total number of patents granted in the period 1791–1844. Instead, data for the United States consist of patents granted from 1790 to 1846. Sources: Our own elaboration of the Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for France and Woodcroft (1854) for England. Sokoloff and Khan (1990, table 1) for the United States.

Figure 5

Table 2 DISTRIBUTION OF DIFFERENT PATENT QUALITY INDICATORS (1791–1844)

Figure 6

Table 3 DISTRIBUTION OF REAL DURATION (DAYS) BY PATENTEES’ RESIDENCE (1791–1844)

Figure 7

Figure 5 REAL DURATION (DAYS) FOR DIFFERENT TYPES OF PATENTS (5, 10, AND 15 YEARS)Notes: The figure reports the distribution of patents “real” duration (in log) by three permitted levels of initial duration (5, 10, and 15 years).Source: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents.

Figure 8

Figure 6 NUMBER OF “HIGH QUALITY” PATENTS GRANTED IN FRANCE BY DEPARTMENT (1791–1844)Notes: Darker areas indicate a higher number of patents. “High quality” patents are those with real duration (days) greater than 4,000. The maps also report the Rouen-Geneva line.Sources: Institut National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) dataset for patents and http://www.datavis.ca/gallery/guerry/maps.html for the map of France department boundaries of 1830.

Figure 9

Figure 7 SHARE OF WORLD IMPORTANT SCIENTIFIC DISCOVERIES AND INVENTIONS BY COUNTRIES (1700–1900)Sources: Sorokin (1937, vol. II, p. 150) lines and authors’ elaborations from Streit (1954, annex I, table I) bars.

Figure 10

Table 4 BIOGRAPHICAL SOURCES USED TO IDENTIFY HISTORICALLY RENOWNED PATENTEES

Figure 11

Table 5 REAL DURATION (DAYS) FOR PATENTS GRANTED TO FAMOUS AND AWARDED INVENTORS

Figure 12

Table 6 DETERMINANTS OF PATENT QUALITY IN FRANCE

Figure 13

Table 7 DETERMINANTS OF PATENT QUALITY IN FRANCE (ONLY DOMESTIC PATENTS)

Figure 14

Table 8 BAR-LEIPONEN MEASURE OF TECHNOLOGY DISTANCE

Supplementary material: File

Nuvolari et al. supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Nuvolari et al. supplementary material(File)
File 671.3 KB