Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T00:41:58.660Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Uncertainty and the Formal Theory of Political Campaigns*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

John A. Ferejohn
Affiliation:
California Institute of Technology
Roger G. Noll
Affiliation:
California Institute of Technology

Abstract

Many empirical investigations indicate that information is scarce and therefore costly to holders and seekers of public office. Indeed, some studies suggest that imperfect information may account for important aspects of the behavior of politicians. Nevertheless, there is as yet no theoretical investigation of political decision making that illustrates the impact of costly information or behavior.

In this paper the authors develop a model of electoral competition in which the candidates are only imperfectly aware of public preferences over issues and in which they may have the opportunity to increase the amount of information they hold at some cost. It turns out that the absence of perfect information profoundly affects the strategic structure of candidate competition. If information is costless, two-party electoral contests are naturally modeled as symmetric two-person zero-sum games. However, if candidates have distinct beliefs about voter behavior, the natural game-theoretic representation becomes a non-zero-sum game. This article is concerned mostly with analyzing the consequences of this transformation.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1978

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 1974 Mathematical Social Science Board Workshop on “Uncertainty, Political Processes and Public Policy.” We are grateful for the comments and encouragement provided by Morris Fiorina, David Grether, Melvin Hinich, Richard McKelvey, Charles Plott, William Riker, Norman Schofield, Kenneth Shepsle, and an anonymous referee. We are also grateful to John Allen and Barry Weingast for research assistance.

References

Bauer, Raymond A., Pool, Ithiel de Sola, and Dexter, Lewis Anthony (1972). American Business and Public Policy; the Politics of Foreign Trade, 2nd ed. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.Google Scholar
Davis, Otto A., and Hinich, Melvin J. (1967). “Some Results Related to a Mathematical Model of Policy Formation in a Democratic Society.” In Bernd, Joseph L. (ed.), Mathematical Applications in Political Science, Vol. 3. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press.Google Scholar
DeMeyer, Frank, and Plott, Charles R. (1970). “The Probability of a Cyclical Majority.” Econometrica 38:345–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, Anthony (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. (1968). Candidates for Office: Beliefs and Strategies. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. (1973). “On a Class of Equilibrium Conditions for Majority Rule.” Econometrica 41:285–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, Robert Duncan, and Raiffa, Howard H. (1957). Games and Decisions. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. (1967). “A Notion of Equilibrium and Its Possibility under Majority Rule.” American Economic Review 57:787806.Google Scholar
Riker, William H., and Ordeshook, Peter C. (1973). An Introduction to Positive Political Theory. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. (1972). “The Strategy of Ambiguity: Uncertainty and Electoral Competition.” American Political Science Review 66:555–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar