Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vvkck Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T04:18:17.041Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Policy Motivation and Party Differences in a Dynamic Spatial Model of Party Competition

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Henry W. Chappell Jr.
Affiliation:
University of South Carolina
William R. Keech
Affiliation:
University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill

Abstract

We present a model of party competition that produces more realistic patterns of results than those often emphasized in the literature. Reversing Downs (1957), we assume that parties win elections in order to formulate policies, rather than formulate policies in order to win elections. Voters are modeled first as having perfect information about candidate positions, and then under conditions of uncertainty. In simulation experiments we show that policy motivation and voter uncertainty can bring about persistent and predictable party differences in sequential majority rule elections. As the degree of voter certainty decreases, parties diverge towards their optima, whereas increases in voter certainty draw parties towards cycles in which party positions vary, but predictable issue stances are maintained on the average.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramowitz, Alan I., and Stone, Walter J.. 1984. Nomination Politics: Party Activists and Presidential Choice. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Aldrich, John H. 1983a. A Downsian Spatial Model with Party Activism. American Political Science Review, 77:974–90.Google Scholar
Aldrich, John H. 1983b. A Spatial Model with Party Activists: Implications for Electoral Dynamics. Public Choice, 41:63100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aranson, Peter H., and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1972. Spatial Strategies for Sequential Elections. In Niemi, Richard G. and Weisberg, Herbert F., eds.. Probability Models of Collective Decision Making. Columbus, OH: Charles E. Merrill.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel. 1982. Parties, Administrations, and American Macroeconomic Outcomes. American Political Science Review, 76:8393.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1985. Robustness of the Multidimensional Voting Model: Candidate Motivations, Uncertainty and Convergence. American Journal of Political Science, 29:6995.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1971. Internal Processes Governing Party Positions in Elections. Public Choice, 11:3560.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1972. The Positions of Political Parties in Elections. In Niemi, Richard G. and Weisberg, Herbert F., eds., Probability Models of Collective Decision Making. Columbus, OH: Charles E. Merrill.Google Scholar
Cramér, Harald. 1946. Mathematical Methods of Statistics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Enelow, James M., and Hinich, Melvin J.. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hansson, Ingemar, and Stuart, Charles. 1984. Voting Competitions with Interested Politicians: Platforms Do Not Converge to the Preferences of the Median Voter. Public Choice, 44:431–41.Google Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas A. Jr., 1977. Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. American Political Science Review, 71:1467–87.Google Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. 1977. A Dynamical Model of Political Equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory, 16:310–44.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1976. Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control. Journal of Economic Theory, 12:472–82.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1976. Symmetric Spatial Games without Majority Rule Equilibria. American Political Science Review, 70:1172–84.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., Ordeshook, Peter C., and Winer, Mark D.. 1978. The Competitive Solution for N-Person Games without Transferable Utility, with an Application to Committee Games. American Political Science Review, 72:599615.Google Scholar
Miller, Gary J. 1980. Experimental Results in Two-Party Agenda Setting: What's It Worth To Be a Party? Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Miller, Nicholas R. 1983. Pluralism and Social Choice. American Political Science Review, 77: 734-47.Google Scholar
Page, Benjamin I. 1978. Choices and Echoes in Presidential Elections: Rational Man and Electoral Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Petry, Francois. 1982. Vote-Maximizing versus Utility-Maximizing Candidates: Comparing Dynamic Models of Bi-Party Competition. Quality and Quantity, 16:507–26.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. 1967. A Notion of Equilibrium and Its Possibility under Majority Rule. American Economic Review, 57:787806.Google Scholar
Rabinowitz, George. 1978. On the Nature of Political Issues: Insights from a Spatial Analysis. American Journal of Political Science, 22: 793817.Google Scholar
Riker, William H., and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1968. A Theory of the Calculus of Voting. American Political Science Review, 62:2543.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1984. Voting Models and Empirical Evidence. American Scientist. 72:465–73.Google Scholar
Schlesinger, Joseph A. 1975. The Primary Goals of Political Parties: A Clarification of Positive Theory. American Political Science Review, 69: 840–49.Google Scholar
Tufte, Edward R. 1978. Political Control of the Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1964. The General Irrelevance of the General Impossibility Theorem. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 81:256–70.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. 1973. Parties as Utility Maximizers. American Political Science Review, 67: 490–98.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. 1977. Candidates with Policy Preferences: A Dynamic Model. Journal of Economic Theory, 14:180–89.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. 1983. Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternative Theories. American Political Science Review, 77:142–57.Google Scholar