Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-r5zm4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-20T01:49:50.985Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Nuclear Deterrence, Counterforce Strategies, and the Incentive to Strike First

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

R. Harrison Wagner
Affiliation:
University of Texas Austin

Abstract

I use the theory of games to investigate issues about how to understand the use of nuclear counterforce strategies by the United States and the Soviet Union during the Cold War. The function of the counterforce strategies I model is not to enable a state confidently to launch a nuclear attack but to convince its adversary that the probability that it might do so as a last resort is greater than zero. The models allow one to investigate rational behavior when information is incomplete and there is an incentive to strike first, and therefore provide a way to explore controversies about the effect of counterforce strategies on both the credibility of extended deterrence and the possibility of inadvertent nuclear war. The models suggest, contrary to the claims of a number of writers, that the use of nuclear counterforce strategies is not necessarily inconsistent with rational behavior and provide some insight into the relation between counterforce strategies and brinkmanship models of deterrence.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Betts, Richard K. 1987. Nuclear Blackmail and Nuclear Balance. Washington: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Eden, Lynn, and Miller, Steven E. 1989. Nuclear Arguments: Understanding the Strategic Nuclear Arms and Arms Control Debates. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Freedman, Lawrence. 1981. The Evolution of Nuclear Strategy. New York: St. Martin's.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert. 1984. The Illogic of American Nuclear Strategy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Kull, Steven. 1988. Minds at War: Nuclear Reality and the Inner Conflicts of Defense Policymakers. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
McGinnis, Michael. 1988. “The Delicate Balance of Analysis: Crisis Stability As an Ambiguous Symbol.” Presented at the annual meeting of the International Studies Association (Midwest), Columbus, OH.Google Scholar
Nalebuff, Barry. 1986. “Brinkmanship and Nuclear Deterrence: The Neutrality of Escalation.Conflict Management and Peace Science 9:1930.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posen, Barry R. 1982. “Inadvertent Nuclear War? Escalation and NATO's Northern Flank.International Security 7:2854.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1987. “Crisis Bargaining, Escalation, and MAD.American Political Science Review 81:717–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1988. “Nuclear Brinkmanship with Two-Sided Incomplete Information.American Political Science Review 82:155–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1989a. “Crisis Stability in the Nuclear Age.American Political Science Review 83:6276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1989b. “Nuclear Deterrence and the Strategy of Limited Retaliation.American Political Science Review 83:503–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sabin, Philip A. G. 1987. “Shadow or Substance? Perceptions and Symbolism in Nuclear Force Planning.” Adelphi Paper No. 222. International Institute for Strategic Studies, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1966. Arms and Influence. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Steinbruner, John. 1984. “Launch under Attack.Scientific American 250:3747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.