Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-qsmjn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T03:39:42.579Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Minority Representation in Multimember Districts

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Elisabeth R. Gerber
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
Rebecca B. Morton
Affiliation:
University of Iowa
Thomas A. Rietz
Affiliation:
University of Iowa

Abstract

Given the recent court rulings against racial gerrymandering, the effect of multimember district elections on minority representation is an important issue. We present a model of voting in double-member district elections with two majority candidates and one minority candidate and consider the voting equilibria under straight and cumulative voting. In straight voting, while an equilibrium always exists in which the two majority candidates are expected to win the two seats, minority candidates may be elected. In cumulative voting, minority candidate wins are also possible in equilibrium but are less likely when minority voters prefer one majority candidate over another. We then present experimental evidence showing that minority candidates win significantly more seats in cumulative than in straight voting elections. When minority voters perceive a substantial difference between the majority candidates, however, they are more likely to split their votes between the minority and majority candidates, winning fewer seats.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Adams, Greg D. 1996. “Legislative Effects of Single-Member Vs. Multi-Member Districts.” American Journal of Political Science 40(02):129–44.Google Scholar
Allen v. State Board of Elections. 1969. 393 U.S. 544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bott, Alexander J. 1990. Handbook of United States Election Laws and Practices. New York: Greenwood Press.Google Scholar
Bush v. Vera. 1996. 000 U.S. 94–805.Google Scholar
Cameron, Charles, Epstein, David, and O'Halloran, Sharyn. 1996. “Do Majority-Minority Districts Maximize Substantive Black Representation in Congress?American Political Science Review 90(12):794812.Google Scholar
Cole, Richard L., Taebel, Delbert A., and Engstrom, Richard L.. 1990. “Cumulative Voting in a Municipal Election: A Note on Voter Reactions and Electoral Consequences.” Western Political Quarterly 43(03):191–9.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary. 1984. “Strategic Electoral Choice in Multi-Member Districts: Approval Voting in Practice.” American Journal of Political Science 28(03):722–38.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary. 1990. “Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems.” American Journal of Political Science 34(11):903–35.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary. 1994. “Strategic Voting Equilibria Under the Single Non-Transferable Vote.” American Political Science Review 88(09):608–21.Google Scholar
Fey, Mark. 1997. “Stability and Coordination in Duverger's Law: A Formal Model of Pre-Election Polls and Strategic Voting.” American Political Science Review 91(03):135–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Filer, John, Kenny, Lawrence, and Morton, Rebecca. 1991. “Voting Laws, Educational Policies, and Minority Turnout.” Journal of Law and Economics 34(10):371–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Myerson, Roger B., Rietz, Thomas A., and Weber, Robert J.. 1993. “An Experiment on Coordination in Multi-Candidate Elections: The Importance of Polls and Election Histories.” Social Choice and Welfare 10:223–47.Google Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Myerson, Roger B., Rietz, Thomas A., and Weber, Robert J.. 1996. “An Experimental Study of Voting Rules and Polls in Three-Way Elections.” The International Journal of Game Theory 25(1):355–83.Google Scholar
Gerber, Elisabeth R., Morton, Rebecca B., and Rietz, Thomas A.. 1996. “Majority Requirements and Minority Representation.” Working Paper, Department of Political Science, The University of Iowa.Google Scholar
Glazer, Amihai, Glazer, Debra G., and Grofman, Bernard. 1984. “Cumulative Voting in Corporate Elections: Introducing Strategy Into the Equation.” South Carolina Law Review 35(Winter):295309.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard, and Davidson, Chandler, eds. 1992. Controversies in Minority Voting. Washington DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard, Handley, Lisa, and Niemi, Richard. 1992. Minority Representation and the Quest for Voting Equality. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Grove v. Emison. 1993. 507 U.S. 25, 37–42.Google Scholar
Guinier, Lani. 1994. The Tyranny of the Majority. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Holder v. Hall. 1994. 512 U.S. 574.Google Scholar
Jewell, Malcolm. 1970. “Commentary on ‘the court, the people’ and ‘one man, one vote.’” In Polsby, Nelson, ed. Reapportionment in the 1970s. Berkeley: University of California Press. Pp. 4652.Google Scholar
Klain, Maurice. 1955. “A New Look at the Constituencies: The Need for a Recount and a Reappraisal.” American Political Science Review 49(12):1105–19.Google Scholar
Kousser, J. Morgan. 1992. “The Voting Rights Act and the Two Reconstructions.” In Grofman, Bernard and Davidson, Chandler, eds. Controversies in Minority Voting. Washington DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Ledyard, John O. 1984. “The Pure Theory of Large Two-Candidate Elections.” Public Choice 44(1):741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merrill, Samuel III. 1981. “Strategic Decisions Under One-Stage Multi-Candidate Voting Systems.” Public Choice 36(1):115–34.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B., Rietz, Thomas A. and Weber, Robert J.. 1996. “Campaign Finance Levels as Coordinating Signals in Three-Way, Experimental Elections.” Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Department of Finance, Working Paper #150.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. and Weber, Robert J.. 1993. “A Theory of Voting Equilibria.” American Political Science Review 87(03):102–14.Google Scholar
Palfrey, Thomas R. 1989. “A Mathematical Proof of Duverger's Law.” In Ordeshook, Peter, ed. Models of Strategic Choice in Politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Pp. 6992.Google Scholar
Pitkin, Hanna. 1967. The Concept of Representation. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Rae, Douglas. 1971. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Saari, Donald G. 1994. Geometry of Voting. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Sawyer, Jack, and MacRae, Duncan Jr. 1962. “Game Theory and Cumulative Voting in Illinois: 1902–1954.” American Political Science Review 56(12):936–46.Google Scholar
Shaw v. Reno. 1993. 509 U.S. 630.Google Scholar
Still, Edward. 1990. “Cumulative and Limited Voting in Alabama.” Presented at the Conference on Representation, Reapportionment, and Minority Empowerment, Pomona College, Claremont, CA, 03.Google Scholar
Swain, Carol. 1993. Black Faces, Black Interests. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Welch, Susan. 1990. “The Impact of At-Large Elections on the Representation of Blacks and Hispanics.” Journal of Politics 52(11):1050–76.Google Scholar