Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-8kt4b Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-24T18:04:42.475Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

American Legislative Decision Making and the Size Principle

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Fred Thompson*
Affiliation:
Economic Council of Canada and, University of California, Los Angeles

Abstract

This article explains why previous empirical tests of the size principle have failed to produce conclusive results. Particular stress is given to seldom considered aspects of constitutional choice; their implications are explored by means of a simple simulation. Then I propose a test of the size principle and report some initial empirical findings based upon this test.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1979

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abrahms, Burton A. (1977). “Legislative Profits and the Economic Theory of Representative Voting: An Empirical Investigation.” Public Choice 31: 111–19.Google Scholar
Adrian, Charles, and Press, Charles (1968). “Decision Costs in Coalition Formation.” American Political Science Review 62: 556–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, A. A. (1950). “Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory.” Journal of Political Economy 58: 211–21.Google Scholar
Bodily, S. E. (1978). “Analysis of Risks to Life and Limb.” Darden School Working Paper DSWP–78–22, Darden Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Virginia.Google Scholar
Breton, Albert (1974). The Economic Theory of Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M., and Tullock, Gordon (1962). The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Cherryholmes, Cleo, and Shapiro, M. (1969). Representatives and Roll Calls: A Computer Simulation of Voting in the Eighty-Eighth Congress. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Cohen, M. D. (1974). “The Importance of Member Preferences in Committee Assignment: An Assessment Against Optimal Standards and a Simple Process Model.” Presented at MSSB Conference on Mathematical Models of Congress, Aspen, Colorado.Google Scholar
DiPalma, Giuseppe (1976). “Institutional Rules and Legislative Outcomes in the Italian Parliament.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 1: 147–79.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. A., and Fiorina, M. P. (1974). “The Paradox of Not Voting: A Decision Theoretic Analysis.” American Political Science Review 68: 525–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferejohn, J. A., and Fiorina, M. P. (1975). “Closeness Counts only in Horseshoes and Dancing.” American Political Science Review 69: 920–25.Google Scholar
Fiorina, M. P., and Noll, R. G. (1978). “Voters, Bureaucrats, and Legislators: A Rational Choice Perspective on the Growth of Bureaucracy.” Journal of Public Economics 9: 221–38.Google Scholar
Fishburn, P. C. (1973). The Theory of Social Choice. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Fischhoff, B., Slovic, Paul, and Lichtenstein, Sarah (1976). “How Safe is Safe Enough?: A Psychometric Study of Attitudes towards Technological Risks and Benefits.” Decision Research Report No. 76–1, Decision Research, University of Oregon, Eugene.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell (1976). “Hollow Victory: The Minimum Winning Coalition.” American Political Science Review 70: 1202–14.Google Scholar
Hinckley, Barbara (1972). “Coalitions in Congress: Size and Ideological Distance.” Midwest Journal of Political Science 16: 197207.Google Scholar
Koehler, D. H. (1972). “The Legislative Process and Minimal Winning Coalition.” In Niemi, R. G. and Weisburg, A. F. (eds.), Probability Models of Collective Decision Making. Columbus, Ohio: Merrill.Google Scholar
Kogan, N., and Wallich, M. (1964). Risk Taking: A Study in Cognition and Personality. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Lindblom, C. E. (1977). Politics and Markets. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Matthews, Donald, and Stimson, James (1970). “Decision Making in the U.S. House of Representatives: A Preliminary Model.” In Uler, S. (ed.), Political Decision Making. New York: Van Nostrand-Rinehold.Google Scholar
Peltzman, Sam (1976). “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics 19: 211–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rohde, David, and Shepsle, K. A. (1973). “Democratic Committee Assignments in the House of Representatives: Strategic Aspects of the Social Choice Process.” American Political Science Review 67: 889905.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1947). Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. (1974). “On the Size of Winning Coalitions.” American Political Science Review 68: 505–18, 522–24.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. (1975). “A Model of the Congressional Committee Assignment Process: Constrained Maximization in the Institutional Setting.” Public Choice 23: 5578.Google Scholar
Silverman, J., and Durdan, G. (1976). “Determining Legislative Preferences on the Minimum Wage: An Economic Approach.” Journal of Political Economy 84: 317–29.Google Scholar
Silberman, L. H. (1978). “Will Lawyering Strangle Democratic Capitalism?Regulation 2, No. 2: 1522.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1971). “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2: 321.Google Scholar
Strom, Gerald S., and Rundquist, Barry S. (1977). “A Revised Theory of Winning in House Senate Conferences.” American Political Science Review 71: 448–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, Fred, and Stanbury, W. T. (1979). “The Political Economy of Interest Groups in the Legislative Process in Canada.” In Kruhlak, O. M., Schultz, Richard, and Pobihushchy, S. I. (eds.), The Canadian Political Process, 3rd ed. Toronto: Holt, Rinehart and Winston of Canada.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.