Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-fv566 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-17T05:29:19.132Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - The Ecology of Financial Markets

from PART I - HOW AND WHY DO PRICES MOVE?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 February 2018

Jean-Philippe Bouchaud
Affiliation:
Capital Fund Management, Paris
Julius Bonart
Affiliation:
University College London
Jonathan Donier
Affiliation:
Capital Fund Management
Martin Gould
Affiliation:
CFM - Imperial Institute of Quantitative Finance
Get access

Summary

Buyer: How much is it?

Seller: £1.50.

Buyer: OK, I'll take it.

Seller: It's £1.60.

Buyer: What? You just said £1.50.

Seller: That was before I knew you wanted it.

Buyer: You cannot do that!

Seller: It's my stuff.

Buyer: But I need a hundred of those!

Seller: A hundred? It's £1.70 apiece.

Buyer: This is insane!

Seller: It's the law of supply and demand, buddy. You want it or not?

(Translated from “6”, by Alexandre Laumonier)

A market is a place where buyers meet sellers to perform trades, and where prices adapt to supply and demand. This time-worn idea is certainly broadly correct, but reality is rather more intricate. At the heart of all markets lies a fundamental tension: buyers want to buy low and sellers want to sell high. Given these opposing objectives, how do market participants ever agree on a price at which to trade?

As the above dialogue illustrates, if a seller was allowed to increase the price whenever a buyer declared an interest to buy, then the price could reach a level so high that the buyer was no longer interested – and vice-versa. If traders always behaved in this way, then conducting even a single transaction would require a long and hard negotiation. Although this might be feasible if trades only occurred very infrequently, modern financial markets involve many thousands of transactions every single day. Therefore, finding a mechanism to conduct this process at scale, such that huge numbers of buyers and sellers can coordinate in real time, is an extremely complex problem.

Centuries of market activity have produced many possible solutions, each with their own benefits and drawbacks. Today, most markets implement an electronic, continuous-time double-auction mechanism based on the essential idea of a limit order book (LOB), which we introduce in Chapter 3. However, as a brief glance at the financial press will confirm, ensuring market stability and “fair and orderly trading” is still elusive, and it remains unclear whether modern electronic markets are any less prone to serious problems than old-fashioned trading pits.

Type
Chapter
Information
Trades, Quotes and Prices
Financial Markets Under the Microscope
, pp. 5 - 21
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Lyons, R. (2001). The microstructure approach to foreign exchange rate. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Biais, B., Glosten, L., & Spatt, C. (2005). Market microstructure: A survey of microfoundations, empirical results, and policy implications. Journal of Financial Markets, 8(2), 217–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hasbrouck, J. (2007). Empirical market microstructure: The institutions, economics, and econometrics of securities trading. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Amihud, Y., Mendelson, H., & Pedersen, L. H. (2012). Market liquidity: Asset pricing, risk, and crises. Cambridge University Press. https://www.gov.uk/gover nment/collections/future-of-computer-trading.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foucault, T., Pagano, M., & Röell, A. (2013). Market liquidity: Theory, evidence, and policy. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehalle, C. A., & Laruelle, S. (2013). Market microstructure in practice. World Scientific.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easley, D., Prado, M. L. D., & O'Hara, M. (2014). High-frequency trading: New realities for traders, markets and regulators. Risk Books.Google Scholar
Laumonier, A. “6” and “5”, Zones Sensibles Edt.
Bagehot, W. (1971). The only game in town. Financial Analysts Journal, 27(2), 12–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, K. J., Conroy, R. M., & Maier, S. F. (1985). Order flow and the quality of the market. Market-making and the changing structure of the securities industry.(pp. 93–110). Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Glosten, L. R., & Milgrom, P. R. (1985). Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders. Journal of Financial Economics, 14(1), 71–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domowitz, I., & Wang, J. (1994). Auctions as algorithms: Computerized trade execution and price discovery. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 18(1), 29–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handa, P., & Schwartz, R. A. (1996). Limit order trading. The Journal of Finance, 51(5), 1835–1861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madhavan, A. (2000). Market microstructure: A survey. Journal of Financial Markets, 3(3), 205–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. M. (2002). A century of stock market liquidity and trading costs. https:// ssrn.com/abstract=313681.
Handa, P., Schwartz, R. A., & Tiwari, A. (1998). The ecology of an order-driven market. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 24(2), 47–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lux, T., & Marchesi, M. (1999). Scaling and criticality in a stochastic multi-agent model of a financial market. Nature, 397(6719), 498–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farmer, J. D. (2002). Market force, ecology and evolution. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(5), 895–953.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
May, R. M., Levin, S. A., & Sugihara, G. (2008). Complex systems: Ecology for bankers. Nature, 451(7181), 893–895.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bouchaud, J. P., Farmer, J. D., & Lillo, F. (2009). How markets slowly digest changes in supply and demand. In Hens, T. & Schenke-Hoppe, K. R. (Eds.), Handbook of financial markets: Dynamics and evolution. North-Holland, Elsevier.Google Scholar
Farmer, J. D., & Skouras, S. (2013). An ecological perspective on the future of computer trading. Quantitative Finance, 13(3), 325–346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. M. (2013). What do we know about high-frequency trading? https://ssrn. com/abstract=2236201.
Biais, B., & Foucault, T. (2014). HFT and market quality. Bankers, Markets & Investors, 128, 5–19.Google Scholar
Bouchaud, J. P., & Challet, D. (2017). Why have asset price properties changed so little in 200 years. In Abergel, F. et al. (Eds.), Econophysics and sociophysics: Recent progress and future directions. (pp. 3–17). Springer. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Trading strategy.Google Scholar
Black, F. (1986). Noise. The Journal of Finance, 41(3), 528–543.
Shleifer, A., & Summers, L. H. (1990). The noise trader approach to finance. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2), 19–33.Google Scholar
Barber, B. M.,Odean, T. (1999). Do investors trade too much. American Economic Review, 89(5), 1279–1298.Google Scholar
Barber, B. M., & Odean, T. (2000). Trading is hazardous to your wealth: The common stock investment performance of individual investors. The Journal of Finance, 55(2), 773–806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, B. M., & Odean, T. (2001). Boys will be boys: Gender, overconfidence, and common stock investment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 261–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The Case for Index-Fund Investing: https://personal.vanguard.com/pdf/ISGIDX.pdf.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×