Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-nr4z6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-08T15:17:11.338Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 November 2023

Peter Skott
Affiliation:
University of Massachusetts, Amherst
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abe, N. and Tonogi, A. (2010). “Micro and Macro Price Dynamics in Daily Data.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 57(6), pp. 716728.Google Scholar
Abel, A.B. Mankiw, N.G. and Zeckhauser, R.J. (1989). “Assessing Dynamic Efficiency: Theory and Evidence.” Review of Economic Studies, 56(1), pp. 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abel, J. and Deitz, R. (2016). “Underemployment in the Early Careers of College Graduates Following the Grate Recession.” NBER Working Paper 22654.Google Scholar
Aboobaker, A. and Ugurlu, E.N. (2023). “Weaknesses of MMT as a Guide to Development Policy.” Forthcoming in Cambridge Journal of Economics, doi.org/10.1093/cje/bead009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2002). “Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market.” Journal of Economic Literature, 40(1), pp. 772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2009). Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. Aghion, P. and Violante, G.L. (2001). “Deunionization, Technical Change and Inequality.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 55(1), pp. 229264.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., He, A. and le Maire, D. (2022). “Eclipse of Rent-Sharing: The Effects of Managers’ Business Education on Wages and the Labor Share in the US and Denmark.” NBER Working Paper 29874.Google Scholar
Ackerman, F. and Heinzerling, L. (2005). Priceless: On Knowing the Price of Everything and the Value of Nothing. New York: The New Press.Google Scholar
Agarwal, S., Qian, W. and Zou, X. (2021). “Thy Neighbour’s Misfortune: Peer Effects on Consumption.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 13(2), pp. 125.Google Scholar
Agell, J. and Lundborg, P. (1995). “Theories of Pay and Unemployment: Survey Evidence from Swedish Manufacturing Firms.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97(2), pp. 295307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G.A. (1991). “Procrastination and Obedience.” American Economic Review, 81(2), pp. 119.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G.A. (2007). “The Missing Motivation in Macroeconomics.” American Economic Review, 97(1), pp. 536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G.A. (2019). “What Were They Thinking Then: The Consequences for Macroeconomics during the Past 60 Years.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 33(4), pp. 171186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G.A., Dickens, W.T. and Perry, G.L. (1996). “The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1(1996), pp. 175.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G.A., Dickens, W.T. and Perry, G.L. (2000). “Near-Rational Wage and Price Setting and the Long-Run Phillips Curve.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1(2000), pp. 160.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G.A. and Shiller, R.J. (2009). Animal Spirits How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G.A. and Yellen, J.L. (1990). “The Fair Wage-effort Hypothesis and Unemployment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(2), pp. 255283.Google Scholar
Albrecht, J. and Vroman, S. (2002). “A Matching Model with Endogenous Skill Requirements.” International Economic Review, 43(1), pp. 283305.Google Scholar
Alvaredo, F. and Saez, E. (2006). “Income and Wealth Concentration in Spain in a Historical and Fiscal Perspective.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(5), pp. 11401167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez, F. and Lippi, F. (2020). “Temporary Price Changes, Inflation Regimes, and the Propagation of Monetary Shocks.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 12(1), pp. 104152.Google Scholar
Alvarez-Cuadrado, F. and Long, N.V. (2011). “The Relative Income Hypothesis.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 35(9), pp. 14891501.Google Scholar
An, C. and Bosworth, B. (2013). Income Inequality in Korea: An Analysis of Trends, Causes, and Answers. Cambridge, MA and London: Harvard University Asia Center.Google Scholar
Ando, A. and Modigliani, F. (1963). “The ‘Life Cycle’ Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate Implications and Tests.” American Economic Review, 53(1), Part 1, pp. 5584.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1989). “Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence.” Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), pp. 14471458.Google Scholar
Antràs, P. (2004). “Is the U.S. Aggregate Production Function Cobb-Douglas? New Estimates of the Elasticity of Substitution.” B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 4(1), pp. 136.Google Scholar
Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (2010). “The Return of Fiscal Policy.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 32(3), pp. 327346.Google Scholar
Ash, M. Basu, D. and Dube, A. (2017). “Public Debt and Growth: An Assessment of Key Findings on Causality and Thresholds.” Working Paper 2017–10, University of Massachusetts Amherst.Google Scholar
Ashkenas, R.N., DeMonaco, L.J. and Francis, S.C. (1998). “Making the Deal Real: How GE Capital Integrates Acquisitions.” Harvard Business Review, 76(1), pp. 165178.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A.B. (1969). “The Timescale of Economic Models: How Long Is the Long Run?Review of Economic Studies, 36(2), pp. 137152.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A.B. (1999). The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Auerbach, P. (2016). Socialist Optimism: An Alternative Political Economy for the Twenty-First Century. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Auerbach, P. and Skott, P. (2021). “Visions of the Future – A Socialist Departure from Gloom?PSL Quarterly Review, 74(298), pp. 155177.Google Scholar
Autor, D., Dorn, D., Katz, L.F., Patterson, C. and Van Reenen, J. (2020). “Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135(2), pp. 645709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D.H., Katz, L.F. and Kearney, M.S. (2008). “Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2), pp. 300323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D., Manning, A. and Smith, C. (2016). “The Contribution of the Minimum Wage to US Wage Inequality Over Three Decades: A Reassessment.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 8(1), pp. 5899.Google Scholar
Azar, J., Marinescu, I. and Steinbaum, M.I. (2017). “Labor Market Concentration.” Journal of Human Resources, 57(S), pp. 167199.Google Scholar
Baddeley, M. (2014). “Rethinking the Micro-Foundations of Macroeconomics: Insights from Behavioural Economics.” European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention, 11(1), pp. 99112.Google Scholar
Backus, D. and Driffill, J. (1985). “Rational Expectations and Policy Credibility Following a Change in Regime.” Review of Economic Studies, 52, pp. 211222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baily, M.N., Bartelsman, E.J. and Haltiwanger, J. (2001). “Labor Productivity: Structural Change and Cyclical Dynamics.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(3), pp. 420433.Google Scholar
Bakija, J., Cole, A. and Heim, B. (2012). “Jobs and Income Growth of Top Earners and the Causes of Changing Income Inequality: Evidence from U.S. Tax Return Data.” Working Paper, Williams College.Google Scholar
Ball, L. (1994). “What Determines the Sacrifice Ratio?.” In Mankiw, N. (ed.), Monetary Policy, National Bureau of Economic Research, University of Chicago Press, pp. 155193.Google Scholar
Ball, L. (1996). “Disinflation and the NAIRU.” NBER Working Papers 5520, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Ball, L. (1997). “Disinflation and the NAIRU.” In , Christina D. David H. Romer, (eds.), Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, NBER, pp. 167194.Google Scholar
Ball, L. (2014). “Long-Term Damage from the Great Recession in OECD Countries.” European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention, 11(2), pp. 149160.Google Scholar
Ball, L., DeLong, B. and Summers, L. (2014). “Fiscal Policy and Full Employment.” Center for Budget and Policy Priorities.Google Scholar
Ball, L. and Mazumbar, S. (2011). “Inflation Dynamics and the Great Recession.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 42(1), pp. 337405.Google Scholar
Ball, L. and Mazumbar, S. (2015). “A Phillips Curve with Anchored Expectations and Short-Term Unemployment.” IMF Working Paper No. 15/39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, L. and Moffitt, R. (2002). “Productivity Growth and the Phillips Curve.” In Krueger, A.B. and Solow, R.M. (eds.), The Roaring Nineties: Can Full Employment be Sustained? New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 6190.Google Scholar
Barbosa-Filho, N.H. and Taylor, L. (2006). “Distributive and Demand Cycles in the US Economy – A Structuralist Goodwin Model.” Metroeconomica, 57(3), pp. 389411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrales-Ruiz, J., Mendieta-Mũnoz, I., Rada, C., Tavani, D. and von Arnim, R. (2021). “The Distributive Cycle: Evidence and Recent Debates.” Journal of Economic Surveys, 36(2), pp. 468503.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. (1979). “On the Determination of the Public Debt.” Journal of Political Economy, 87(5), pp. 940971.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. (1989). “The Neoclassical Approach to Fiscal Policy.” In Barro, R. (ed.), Modern Business Cycle Theory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 178235.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. (1994). “The Aggregate-Supply/Aggregate-Demand Model.” Eastern Economic Journal, Winter, pp. 16.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. (1995) “Inflation and Economic Growth.” NBER Working Paper, w5326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R.J. and Gordon, D. (1983). “A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model,” Journal of Political Economy, 91, pp. 589610.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. and Grossman, H.I. (1976). Money, Emnployment and Inflation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Basu, D. (2013). “The Time Series of High Debt and Growth in Italy, Japan, and the United States.” Next New Deal: The Blog of the Roosevelt Institute, April, 2012.Google Scholar
Baum, S. (2009). “Description, Prescription and the Choice Of Discount Rates,” Ecological Economics, 69(1), 197205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaudry, P., Galizia, D. and Portier, F. (2017). “Is the Macroeconomy Locally Unstable and Why Should We Care?In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 31, Eichenbaum, M. and Parker, J.A. (eds.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 479530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaudry, P., Galizia, D. and Portier, F. (2020). “Putting the Cycle Back into Business Cycle Analysis.” American Economic Review, 110(1), pp. 147.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L.A., Fried, J.M. and Walker, D.I. (2002). “Managerial Power and Rent Extraction in the Design of Executive Compensation.” The University of Chicago Law Review, 69, pp. 751846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bebczuk, R. and Cavallo, E. (2016). “Is Business Saving Really None of Our Business?Applied Economics, 48(24), pp. 22662284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell-Kelton, S. and Ballinger, R. (2006). “The Monetary Policy of Outcomes Curve: Can the Size and Structure of Public Debt Undermine Policy Objectives?.” In Arestis, P., Baddeley, M. and McCombie, J. (eds.), The New Monetary Policy: Implications and Relevance, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 129148.Google Scholar
Benhabib, J. and Nishimura, K. (1985). “Competitive Equilibrium Cycles.” Journal of Economic Theory, 35(2), pp. 284306.Google Scholar
Beniger, J.R. (1986). The Control Revolution: Technological and Economic Origins of the Information Society. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Benmelech, E., Bergman, N. and Kim, H. (2022). “Strong Employers and Weak Employees: How Does Employer Concentration Affect Wages?Journal of Human Resources, 57, pp. S200–S250.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. (2010). “Monetary Policy Objectives and Tools in a Low-Inflation Environment.” Speech at the Revisiting Monetary Policy in a Low-Inflation Environment Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, Massachusetts.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1999). “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework.” In Taylor, J.B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, North-Holland Elsevier Science, New York.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B.D., Shleifer, A. and Summers, L.H. (1985). “The Strategic Bequest Motive.” Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), pp. 10451458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bewley, T.F. (1998). “Why Not Cut Pay?European Economic Review, 42, pp. 459490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bewley, T.F. (1999). Why Wages Don’t Fall During a Recession. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhargava, S. and Loewenstein, G. (2015). “Behavioral Economics and Public Policy 102: Beyond Nudging.” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 105(5), pp. 396401.Google Scholar
Bhutta, N., Bricker, J., Chang, A.C., Dettling, L.J., Goodman, S., Hsu, J.W., Moore, K.B., Reber, S., Henriques Volz, A. and Windle, R.A. (2020). “Changes in U.S. Family Finances from 2016 to 2019: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances.” Federal Reserve Bulletin, September, 106, No. 5.Google Scholar
Bils, M. and Klenow, P.J. (2004). “Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices.” Journal of Political Economy, 112(5), pp. 947985.Google Scholar
Bivens, J., Mishel, L. and Schmitt, J. (2018). “It’s Not Just Monopoly and Monopsony.” Economic Policy Institute, epi.org/145564.Google Scholar
Black, S.E. and Lynch, L.M. (2001). “How to Compete: The Impact of Workplace Practices and Information Technology on Productivity.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(3), pp. 434445.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (1985). “Debt, Deficits, and Finite Horizons.” Journal of Political Economy, 93(2), 223247.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2000). “What Do We Know about Macroeconomics that Fisher and Wicksell Did Not?Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, pp. 13751409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2008). “The State of Macro.” Annual Review of Economics, Annual Reviews, 1(1), pp. 209228.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2016a). “Do DSGE Models Have a Future?Policy Brief, Peterson Institute for International Economics, 1116.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2016b). “The Phillips Curve: Back to the ’60s?American Economic Review, 106(5), pp. 3134.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2018a). “On the Future of Macroeconomic Models.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), pp. 4354.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2018b). “Should We Reject the Natural Rate Hypothesis?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(1), pp. 97120.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2019). “Public Debt and Low Interest Rates.” American Economic Review, 109(4), pp. 11971229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. (2021). Macroeconomics, 8th edition. Hoboken, NJ: Pearson.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. and Summers, L. (1987). “Hysteresis in Unemployment.” European Economic Review, 31(1–2), pp. 288295.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. and Summers, L.H. (2020). “Automatic Stabilizers in a Low-Rate Environment.” AEA Papers and Proceedings, 110, pp. 125130.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J., Rhee, C. and Summers, L. (1993). “The Stock Market, Profit, and Investment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(1), pp. 115136.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. and Wolfers, J. (2000). “The Role of Shocks and Institutions in the Rise of European Unemployment: The Aggregate Evidence.” Economic Journal, 110(March): C1–C33.Google Scholar
Blanchflower, D. and Oswald, A. (2004). “Well-Being Over Time in Britain and the USA.” Journal of Public Economics, 88(7–8), pp. 13591386.06.Google Scholar
Bleaney, M. and Francisco, M. (2018). “Is the Phillips Curve Different in Poor Countries?Bulletin of Economic Research, 70(1), pp. E17–E28.Google Scholar
Blecker, R.A. and Setterfield, M. (2019). Heterodox Macroeconomics – Models of Demand, Distribution and Growth. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Blinder, A.S. (1991). “Why Are Prices Sticky? Preliminary Results from an Interview Study.” American Economic Review, 81(2), pp. 8996.Google Scholar
Bliss, C.J. (1975). Capital Theory and the Distribution of Income. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Bohn, H. (2009). “Intergenerational Risk Sharing and Fiscal Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, pp. 805816.Google Scholar
Boldrin, M. and Levine, D.K. (2008). Against Intellectual Monopoly. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (1989). “Social Institutions and Technical Choice.” In DeMatteo, M., Vercelli, A. and Goodwin, R. (eds.), Technological and Social Factors in Long Term Economic Fluctuations, Berlin: Springer Verlag.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (1998). “Endogenous Preferences: The Cultural Consequences of Markets and Other Economic Institutions.” Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1), pp. 75111.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (1986). Democracy and Capitalism: Property, Community, and the Contradictions of Modern Social Thought. New York Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. and Park, Y. (2005). “Emulation, Inequality, and Work Hours: Was Thorsten Veblen Right?Economic Journal, 115(507), pp. F397–F412.Google Scholar
Boyer, R. (1990). The Regulation School: A Critical Introduction. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Bresnahan, T.M. and Ramey, V.A. (1994). “Output Fluctuations at the Plant Level.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(3), pp. 593624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bresser-Pereira, L.C. Oreiro, J.L. and Marconi, N. (2014). Developmental Macroeconomics: New Developmentalism as a Growth Strategy. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Breza, E., Kaur, S. and Shamdasani, Y. (2018). “The Morale Effects of Pay Inequality.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(2), pp. 611663.Google Scholar
Brock, W.A. and Hommes, C.H. (1998). “Heterogeneous Beliefs and Routes to Chaos in a Simple Asset Pricing Model.” Journal of Econonmic Dynamics and Control, 22(8–9), pp. 12351274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bronfenbrenner, K. (2009). “No Holds Barred—The Intensification of Employer Opposition to Organizing.” Briefing Paper 235, Economic Policy Institute.Google Scholar
Broome, J. (2012). Climate Matters: Ethics in a Warming World. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Browning, M., Deaton, A. and Irish, M. (1985). “A Profitable Approach to Labor Supply and Commodity Demands over the Life-Cycle.” Econometrica, 53(3), pp. 503543.Google Scholar
Bruno, M. and Easterly, W. (1998). “Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 41(1), pp. 326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buiter, W. (2009). “The Unfortunate Uselessness of Most ‘State of the Art’ Academic Monetary Economics.” blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2009/03/the-unfortunateuselessness-of-most-state-of-the-art-academic-monetary-economics/.Google Scholar
Buiter, W.H. and Miller, M.H. (1983). “Changing the Rules: Economic Consequences of the Thatcher Regime.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 305365.Google Scholar
Bulow, J. and Summers, L. (1986). “A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment.” Journal of Labor Economics, 4(3), pp. 376414.Google Scholar
Caballero, R.J. (1999). “Aggregate Investment.” In Taylor, J.B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, 1, Part B, pp. 813862.Google Scholar
Caballero, R.J. (2010). “Macroeconomics after the Crisis: Time to Deal with the Pretense-of-Knowledge Syndrome.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(4), pp. 85102.Google Scholar
Callaci, B. (2021). “What Do Franchisees Do? Vertical Restraints as Workplace Fissuring and Labor Discipline Devices.” Journal of Law and Political Economy, pp. 397444.Google Scholar
Calmfors, L. and Driffill, J. (1988). “Bargaining Structure, Corporatism and Macroeconomic Performance.” Economic Policy, 6, pp. 1447.Google Scholar
Calvo, G.A. (1983). “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(3), pp. 383398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G. and Thaler, R. (1997). “Labor Supply of New York City Cabdrivers: One Day at a Time.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), pp. 407441.Google Scholar
Campbell, D.T. (1976). “Assessing the Impact of Planned Social Change.” Evaluation and Program Planning, 2(1), pp. 6790.Google Scholar
Campbell, C.M. and Kamlani, K.S. (1997). “The Reasons for Wage Rigidity: Evidence from a Survey of Firms.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(3), pp. 759789.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. and Mankiw, N.G. (1989). “Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 4, pp. 185216.Google Scholar
Canzoneri, M.B., Cumby, R.E. and Diba, B.T. (2007). “Euler Equations and Money Market Interest Rates: A Challenge for Monetary Policy Models.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, pp. 18631881.Google Scholar
Caplin, A.S. and Spulber, D.F. (1987). “Menu Costs and the Neutrality of Money.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(4), pp. 703726.Google Scholar
Card, D., Kramarz, F. and Lemieux, T. (1999). “Changes in the Relative Structure of Wages and Employment: A Comparison of the United States, Canada and France.” Canadian Journal of Economics, 32(4), pp. 843877.Google Scholar
Card, D. and Krueger, A.B. (1995). Myth and Measurement. The New Economics of the Minimum Wage. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Carr, M. and Jayadev, A. (2015). “Relative Income and Indebtedness: Evidence from Panel Data.” Review of Income and Wealth, 61(4), pp. 759772.Google Scholar
Cavallo, A. and Rigobon, R. (2016). “The Billion Prices Project: Using Online Prices for Measurement and Research.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30(2), pp. 151178.Google Scholar
Cengiz, D., Dube, A., Lindner, A. and Zipperer, B. (2019). “The Effect of Minimum Wages on Low-Wage Jobs: Evidence from the United States Using a Bunching Estimator.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134(3), pp. 14051454.Google Scholar
Chalk, N.A. (2000). “The Sustainability of Bond-financed Deficits: And Overlapping Generations Approach.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 45, pp. 293328.Google Scholar
Chandler, A.D. Jr. (1977). The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chang, H.J. (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem.Google Scholar
Chari, V.V. (2010). “Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight, U.S. House of Representatives.” July 20, 2010. people.virginia.edu/~ey2d/Chari_Testimony.pdf.Google Scholar
Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, T. (2006). “Modern Macroeconomics in Practice: How Theory Is Shaping Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(4), pp. 328.Google Scholar
Chetty, R., Friedman, J., Leth-Petersen, S., Nielsen, T. and Olsen, T. (2014). “Active vs. Passive Decisions and Crowd-Out in Retirement Savings Accounts: Evidence from Denmark.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(3), pp. 11411219.Google Scholar
Chiarella, C. and Flaschel, P. (2000). The Dynamics of Keynesian Monetary Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Chiarella, C., Flaschel, P. and Franke, R. (2005). Foundations for a Disequilibrium Theory of the Business Cycle. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cho, J. and Lee, K. (2007). Deregulation of Dismissal Law and Unjust Dismissal in Korea. International Review of Law and Economics, 27, 409422.Google Scholar
Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. (2005). “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), pp. 145.Google Scholar
Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M.S. and Trabandt, M. (2017). “On DSGE Models.” Mimeo, November 9, 2017.Google Scholar
Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M.S. and Trabandt, M. (2018). “On DSGE Models.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(3), pp. 113140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chun, H., Kim, J.W. and Morck, R. (2011). “Varying Heterogeneity among U.S. Firms: Facts and Implications.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(3), pp. 10341052.Google Scholar
Coburn, T. (2012). The Debt Bomb: A Bold Plan to Stop Washington from Bankrupting America. Nashville: Thomas Nelson.Google Scholar
Cohen, A.J. and Harcourt, G.C. (2003). “Retrospectives: Whatever Happened to the Cambridge Capital Theory Controversies?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), pp. 199214.Google Scholar
Coibion, O. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2015). “Is the Phillips Curve Alive and Well after All? Inflation Expectations and the Missing Disinflation.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7(1), pp. 197232.Google Scholar
Coibion, O., Gorodnichenko, Y. and Kumar, S. (2018). “How Do Firms Form Their Expectations? New Survey Evidence.” American Economic Review, 108(9), pp. 26712713.Google Scholar
Colander, D. (1995). “The Stories We Tell: A Reconsideration of AS/AD Analysis.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(3), pp. 169188.Google Scholar
Collard, F., Habib, M. and Rochet, J.-C. (2015). “Sovereign Debt Sustainability in Advanced Economies.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 13(3), pp. 381420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Comin, D. and Mulani, S. (2006). “Diverging Trends in Aggregate and Firm Volatility.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(2), pp. 374383.Google Scholar
Cooper, R.W. and Haltiwanger, J.C. (2006). “On the Nature of Capital Adjustment Costs.” Review of Economic Studies, 73(3), pp. 611633.Google Scholar
Corneo, G. (2018). “Time-poor, Working, Super-rich.” European Economic Review, 101(January), pp. 119.Google Scholar
Crawford, V.P. and Meng, J. (2011). “New York City Cab Drivers’ Labor Supply Revisited: Reference-Dependent Preferences with Rational-Expectations Targets for Hours and Income.” American Economic Review, 101(5), pp. 19121932.Google Scholar
Cronqvist, H., Thaler, R.H. and Yu, F. (2018). “When Nudges are Forever: Inertia in the Swedish Premium Pension Plan.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 108, pp. 153158.Google Scholar
Cubitt, R.P. (1992). “Monetary Policy Games and Private Sector Precommitment.” Oxford Economic Papers, 44(3), pp. 513530.Google Scholar
Cukierman, A. and Lippi, F. (1999). “Central Bank Independence, Centralization of Wage Bargaining, Inflation and Unemployment: Theory and Some Evidence.” European Economic Review, 43(7), pp. 13951434.Google Scholar
Curcuru, S., Heaton, J., Lucas, D. and Moore, D. (2005). Heterogeneity and Portfolio Choice: Theory and Evidence. In Ait-Sahalia, Y. and Hansen, L. (eds.), Handbook of Financial Econometrics, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Cynamon, B.Z. and Fazzari, S.M. (2008). “Household Debt in the Consumer Age: Source of Growth – Risk of Collapse.” Capitalism and Society, 3(2), Article 3.Google Scholar
Daly, M., Hobyn, B. and Lucking, B. (2012). “Why Has Wage Growth Stayed Strong?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Letter 2012–10 April 2, 2012.Google Scholar
DamillRapetti, M., , M. and Rozenwurcel, G. (eds.), (2016). Macroeconomics and Development: Roberto Frenkel and the Economics of Latin America, New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Davidson, P. (1968). “Money, Portfolio Balance, Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth.” Econometrica, 36(2), pp. 292321.Google Scholar
Davidson, P. (2008). “Post World War II Politics and Keynes’s Aborted Revolutionary Economic Theory.” Economia e Sociedade, Campinas, 17, Número Especial, pp. 549568.Google Scholar
Davidson, P. (2010). “Making Dollars and Sense of the U.S. Government Debt.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 32(4), pp. 661665.Google Scholar
Davis, L. (2018). “Financialization and the Non-financial Corporation: An Investigation of Firm-level Investment Behavior.” Metroeconomica, 69(1), pp. 270307.Google Scholar
Davis, L. and Skott, P. (2012). “Positional Goods, Climate Change and the Social Returns to Investment.” In Michl, Tom, Rezai, Armon and Taylor, Lance (eds.), Social Fairness and Economics: Economic Essays in the Spirit of Duncan Foley, Routledge.Google Scholar
Day, R.H. (1994). “Complex Economic Dynamics – Vol. 1: An Introduction to Dynamical Systems and Market Mechanisms.” Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Debreu, G. (1974). “Excess Demand Functions.” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1(1), pp. 1521.Google Scholar
De Giorgi, G., Frederiksen, A. and Pistaferri, L. (2020). “Consumption Network Effects.” Review of Economic Studies, 87(1), pp. 130163.Google Scholar
De Grauwe, P. (2012). Lectures on Behavioral Macroeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
De Loecker, J. and Eeckhout, J. (2017). “The Rise of Market Power and the Macroeconomic Implications.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135(2), pp. 561644.Google Scholar
DeLong, B. (2009). “The Intellectual Decline Collapse of the Chicago School, Part XLIV.” delong.typepad.com/sdj/2009/03/Employment-cost-index-since-2001.html.Google Scholar
DeLong, J.B. and Summers, L. (2012). “Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 233274.Google Scholar
Diallo, M.B., Flaschel, P. Krolzig, H.-M. and Proano, C. (2011). “Reconsidering the Dynamic Interaction Between Real Wages and Macroeconomic Activity.” Research in World Economy, 2(1), pp. 7793.Google Scholar
Diamond, P.A. (1965). “National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model.” American Economic Review, 55(5), pp. 11261150.Google Scholar
Domar, E.D. (1946). “Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment.” Econometrica, 14(2), pp. 137147.Google Scholar
Doms, M. and Dunne, T. (1998). “Capital Adjustment Patterns in Manufacturing Plants.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 1(2), pp. 409429.Google Scholar
Dube, A. Giuliano, L. and Leonard, J. (2019). “Fairness and Frictions: The Impact of Unequal Raises on Quit Behavior.” American Economic Review, 109(2), pp. 620663.Google Scholar
Dube, A., Lester, T. and Reich, M. (2010). “Minimum Wage Effects Across State Borders: Estimates Using Contiguous Counties.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 92(4), pp. 945964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duesenberry, J. (1949). Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Dunlop, J.T. (1938). “The Movement of Real and Money Wage Rates.” Economic Journal, 48(191), pp. 413434.Google Scholar
Dutt, A.K. (1986). “Wage Rigidity and Unemployment: The Simple Diagrammatics of Two Views.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 9(2), pp. 279290.Google Scholar
Dutt, A.K. (1992). “Conflict Inflation, Distribution, Cyclical Accumulation and Crises.” European Journal of Political Economy, 8, pp. 579597.Google Scholar
Dutt, A.K. (2003). “On Post Walrasian Economics, Macroeconomic Policy, and Heterodox Economics.” International Journal of Political Economy, 33(2), pp. 4767.Google Scholar
Dutt, A.K. (2009). “Happiness and the Relative Income Hypothesis.” In A.K. Dutt and B. Radcliff, (eds.), Happiness, Economics and Politics: Towards a Multi-Disciplinary Approach. Elgar.Google Scholar
Dutt, A.K. and Skott, P. (1996). “Keynesian Theory and the Aggregate-Supply/Aggregate-Demand Framework: A Defense.” Eastern Economic Journal, 22(3), Summer, pp. 313333.Google Scholar
Dutt, A.K. and Skott, P. (2006). “Keynesian Theory and the AD-AS Framework: A Reconsideration.” In Chiarella, C., Flaschel, P., Franke, R. and Semmler, W. (eds.), Quantitative and Empirical Analysis of Nonlinear Dynamic Macromodels. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Dynan, K.E., Skinner, J. and Zeldes, S.P. (2004). “Do the Rich Save More?” Journal of Political Economy, 112 (2, April), pp. 397444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterlin, R. (1974). “Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence.” In David, R. and Reder, M. (eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz, New York: Academic Press. pp. 89125.Google Scholar
Easterlin, R. (2001). “Income and Happiness, Towards a Unified Theory.” The Economic Journal, 111(473), pp. 465484.Google Scholar
Economic Policy Institute. (2018). “Policy Agenda.” www.epi.org/policy/. Economist. (2009). “What Went Wrong with Economics.” 16 July, www.economist.com/leaders/2009/07/16/what-went-wrong-with-economics.Google Scholar
Economist. (2014). “Hail, the Swabian Housewife – Views on Economics, the Euro and Much else Draw on a Cultural Archetype.” 1 March, www.economist.com/europe/2014/02/01/hail-the-swabian-housewife?.Google Scholar
Economist. (2018). “Labour Monitoring Technologies Raise Efficiency – and Hard Questions.” 1 March, www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2018/03/01/labour-monitoring-technologies-raise-efficiency-and-hard-questions.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, G.B., Mehrotra, N.R. and Robbins, J.A. (2019). “A Model of Secular Stagnation: Theory and Quantitative Evaluation.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 11(1), pp. 148.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, G.B., Robbins, J.A., and Wold, E.G. (2021). “Kaldor and Piketty’s Facts: The Rise of Monopoly Power in the United States.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 124, Supplement, pp. S19–S38.Google Scholar
Eichenbaum, M., Jaimovich, N. and Rebelo, S. (2011). “Reference Prices, Costs, and Nominal Rigidities.” American Economic Review, 101(1), pp. 234262.Google Scholar
Eidelson, J. (2019). “Instacart Doesn’t Want ‘No’ for an Answer.” Bloomberg Businessweek, 22 July, pp. 2224.Google Scholar
Elmendorf, D. and Mankiw, N.G. (1999). “Government Debt.” In Taylor, J.B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1C, Amsterdam, North-Holland.Google Scholar
Elson, Charles M. and Ferrere, Craig K. (2012). “Executive Superstars, Peer Groups and Over-Compensation – Cause, Effect and Solution.” Available at SSRN: ssrn.com/abstract=2125979 or dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2125979.Google Scholar
Engen, E.M. and Hubbard, R. Glenn (2004). “Federal Government Debts and Interest Rates.” In Gertler, M. and Rogoff, K. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2004, 19, Cambridge and London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, G. (2019). What’s Wrong with Modern Money Theory?: A Policy Critique. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2001). “Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State.” In Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fafchamps, M. and Shilpi, F. (2008). “Subjective Welfare, Isolation, and Relative Consumption,” Journal of Development Economics, 86(1), pp. 4360.Google Scholar
Fairris, D. (1997). Shopfloor Matters: Labor-Management Relations in Twentieth-Century American Manufacturing. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Farber, H.S. (2005). “Is Tomorrow Another Day? The Labor Supply of New York City Cabdrivers.” Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), pp. 4682.Google Scholar
Farber, H.S. (2008). “Reference-Dependent Preferences and Labor Supply: The Case of New York City Taxi Drivers.” American Economic Review, 98(3), pp. 10691082.Google Scholar
Farber, H.S., Herbst, D., Kuziemko, I. and Naidu, S. (2021). “Unions and Inequality Over the Twentieth Century: New Evidence from Survey Data.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 136(3), pp. 13251385.Google Scholar
Fazzari, S.M., Hubbard, R.G. and Petersen, B.C. (1988). “Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1988(1), pp. 141195.Google Scholar
Fazzari, S.M., Ferri, P.E., Greenberg, E.G. and Variato, A.M. (2013). “Aggregate Demand, Instability, and Growth.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 1(1), pp. 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feenstra, R.C. and Hanson, G.H. (1996). “Globalization, Outsourcing, and Wage Inequality.” American Economic Review, 86(2), pp. 240245.Google Scholar
Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. (2003). “Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity – Evidence and Economic Applications.” In Dewatripont, M., L. Hansen and St. Turnovsky (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics – 8th World Congress, Econometric Society Monographs, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Goette, L. and Zehnder, C. (2009). “A Behavioral Account of the Labor Market: The Role of Fairness Concerns.” Annual Review of Economics, 2009(1), pp. 355384.Google Scholar
Fel’dman, G.A. (1928). “On the Theory of Growth Rates of National Income.” Translated and Reprinted in Two Parts in Spulber, N. (ed.), (1964). Foundations of Soviet Strategy for Economic Growth. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, pp. 174199 and 304331.Google Scholar
Felipe, J. (2001). “Endogenous Growth, Increasing Returns and Externalities: An Alternative Interpretation of the Evidence.” Metroeconomica, 52(4), pp. 391427.Google Scholar
Felipe, J. and Fisher, F.M. (2003). “Aggregation in Production Functions: What Applied Economists Should Know.” Metroeconomica, 54(2–3), pp. 208262.Google Scholar
Ferguson, C.E. (1971). “Capital Theory up to Date: A Comment on Mrs Robinson’s Article.” Canadian Journal of Economics, 4(2), pp. 250254.Google Scholar
Fernholz, T. (2013). “How Influential Was the Rogoff-Reinhart Study Warning That High Debt Kills Growth?” Quartz, April 16, 2013, qz.com/75117/how-influentialwas-the-study-warning-high-debt-kills-growth/.Google Scholar
Fershtman, C. and Segal, U. (2018). “Preferences and Social Influence.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 10(3), pp. 124142.Google Scholar
Fisher, F.M. (1971). “Aggregate Production Functions and the Explanation of Wages: A Simulation Experiment.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 53(4), pp. 30525.Google Scholar
Fisher, F.M., Solow, R.M. and Kearl, J.M. (1977). “Aggregate Production Functions: Some CES Experiments.” Review of Economic Studies, 44(2), pp. 305320.Google Scholar
Flaschel, P. and Franke, R. (2000). “An Old-Keynesian Note on Destabilizing Price Flexibility.” Review of Political Economy, 12(3), pp. 273283.Google Scholar
Flaschel, P. and Krolzig, H.M. (2006). “Wage-Price Phillips Curves and Macroeconomic Stability: Basic Structural Form, Estimation and Analysis.” In C. Chiarella,Google Scholar
Flaschel, P., Franke, R. and Semmler, W. (eds.), Quantitative and Empirical Analysis of Nonlinear Dynamic Macromodels, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 747.Google Scholar
Fogg, N. and Harrington, P. (2011). “Rising Mal-Employment and the Great Recession: The Growing Disconnection between Recent College Graduates and the College Labor Market.” Continuing Higer Education Review, 75, pp. 5165.Google Scholar
Foley, D.K., Michl, T.R. and Tavani, D. (2019). Growth and Distribution, 2nd ed. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Frank, R.H. (1985a). Choosing the Right Pond. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Frank, R.H. (1985b). “The Demand for Unobservable and Other Nonpositional Goods.” American Economic Review, 75(1), pp. 101116.Google Scholar
Frank, R.H. (2005). “Positional Externalities Cause Large and Preventable Welfare Losses.” American Economic Review, 95(2), pp. 137141.Google Scholar
Frank, R.H. (2008). “Should Public Policy Respond to Positional Externalities?Journal of Public Economics, 92(8–9), pp. 17771786.Google Scholar
Frank, R.H. (2012). “Why Do Americans Save So Little and Does It Matter?” In Yates, Joshua and Davison Hunter, James (eds.) Thrift and Thriving in America: Capitalism and Moral Order from the Puritans to the Present. Oxford Scholarship Online, pp. 417436.Google Scholar
Franke, R. (2018). “Can Monetary Policy Tame Harrodian Instability?Metroeconomica, 69(3), pp. 593618.Google Scholar
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. and O’Donoghue, T. (2002). “Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review.” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XL (June), pp. 351401.Google Scholar
Freeman, C. (1995). The National System of Innovation in Historical Perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(1), pp. 524.Google Scholar
Freeman, R.B. (2007). “The Great Doubling: The Challenge of the New Global Labor Market.” In Edwards, J. Crain, M. and Kalleberg, A. (eds.) Ending Poverty in America: How to Restore the American Dream. New York: The New Press.Google Scholar
Freeman, R.B. and Medoff, J.L. (1984). What Do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Frey, B. and Stutzer, A. (2002). “What Can Economists Learn from Happiness Research?Journal of Economic Literature. 40(2), pp. 402435.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. (1957). A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. (1968). “The Role of Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review, 58(1) (March), pp. 117.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. and Schwartz, A.J. (1963). A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Frydman, R. and Phelps, E.S. (eds) (1983). Individual Forecasting and Aggregate Outcomes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gabaix, X. and Landier, A. (2008). “Why Has CEO Pay Increased So Much?The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1), pp. 49100.Google Scholar
Gali, J. (2016). Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business Cycle, 2nd edition. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (1999). “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, pp. 195222.Google Scholar
Gao, Z., Sockin, M. and Xiong, M. (2020). “Economic Consequences of Housing Speculation.” Review of Financial Studies, 33, pp. 52485287.Google Scholar
Garicano, L. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2006). “Organization and Inequality in a Knowledge Economy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), pp. 13831435.Google Scholar
Giglio, S., Maggiori, M. and Utkus, S. (2021). “Five Facts about Beliefs and Portfolios.” American Economic Review, 111(5), pp. 14811522.Google Scholar
Girardi, D. and Pariboni, R. (2020). “Autonomous Demand and the Investment Share.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 8(3), pp. 428453.Google Scholar
Godley, W. (1999). “Seven Unsustainable Processes.” Strategic Analysis, January, Levy Economics Institute. www.levyinstitute.org/publications/seven-unsustainable-processes.Google Scholar
Godley, W. and Lavoie, M. (2007). Monetary Economics. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Goldin, C. and Katz, L.F. (2008). The Race Between Education and Technology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gomes, F., Haliassos, M. and Ramadorai, T. (2021). “Household Finance.” Journal of Economic Literature, 59(3), pp. 9191000.Google Scholar
Goodhart, C.A.E. (1975). “Problems of Monetary Management: The UK Experience.” In Papers in Monetary Economics, Vol I, Reserve Bank of Australia. Reprinted in Courakis, A.S. (ed.), Inflation, Depression, and Economic Policy in the West, Rowman & Littlefield, pp. 111146.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R.M. (1951). “The Nonlinear Accelerator and the Persistence of Business Cycles.” Econometrica, 19(1), 117.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R.M. (1967). “A Growth Cycle.” In Feinstein, C.H. (ed.), Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R.M. (1989). Essays in Nonlinear Economic Dynamics. Frankfurt am Main: Peter Lang.Google Scholar
Gordon, R.J. (1997). “The Time-Varying NAIRU and Its Implications for Economic Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, pp. 1132.Google Scholar
Gordon, R.J. (2009). “Is Modern Macro or 1978-era More Relevant to the Understanding of the Current Economic crisis?Mimeo.Google Scholar
Grandmont, J.-M. (1985). “On Endogenous Competitive Business Cycles.” Econometrica, 53(5), pp. 9951045.Google Scholar
Green, F. (1981). “The Effect of Occupational Pension Schemes on Saving in the United Kingdom: A Test of the Life Cycle Hypothesis.” Economic Journal, 91(361), pp. 136144.Google Scholar
Green, F. (1988). “Technical Efficiency and Production Relations: An Expository Note.” Mimeo.Google Scholar
Green, F. (1991). “Institutional and Other Unconventional Theories of Saving.” Journal of Economic Issues, 25(1), pp. 93113.Google Scholar
Green, F. (2004). “Why Has Work Effort Become More Intense?Industrial Relations, 43(4), pp. 709741.Google Scholar
Greenspan, A. (2005). “Economic Flexibility.” Remarks by Chairman Alan Greenspan before the National Italian American Foundation, Washington, D.C. www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/20051012/default.htm.Google Scholar
Gregg, P. and Manning, A. (1997). “Skill-Biassed Change, Unemployment and Wage Inequality.” European Economic Review, 41(6), pp. 11731200.Google Scholar
Grissmer, D.W. (2000). The Continuing Use and Misuse of SAT Scores. Psychology, Public Policy, and Law, 6(1), 223232.Google Scholar
Groot, W. and Maassen van den Brink, H. (2000). “Overeducation in the Labor Market: A Meta-analysis.” Economics of Education Review, 19(2), pp. 149158.Google Scholar
Gross, D.B. and Souleles, N.S. (2002). “Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), pp. 149185.Google Scholar
Grubb, D. (1986). “Topics in the OECD Phillips Curve.” Economic Journal, 96(381), 5579.Google Scholar
Guimaraes, B. and Sheedy, K.D. (2011). “Sales and Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review, 101(2), pp. 84476.Google Scholar
Gustman and Steinmeier (2002). “The Influence of Pensions on Behavior: How Much Do We Really Know?” TIAA-CREF Institute Working Paper No. RD71.Google Scholar
Guy, F. (2007). “Strategic Bundling: Information Products, Market Power, and the Future of Globalization.” Review of International Political Economy, 14(1): 2648.Google Scholar
Guy, F. and Skott, P. (2008). “Information and Communications Technologies, Coordination and Control, and the Distribution of Income.” Journal of Income Distribution, 17(3–4), pp. 7192.Google Scholar
Hahn, F.-H. (1973). “The Winter of Our Discontent.” Economica, 40(159), pp. 322330.Google Scholar
Hahn, F.H. and Solow, R. (1986). A Critical Essay on Modern Macroeconomic Theory, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Haldane, A.G. and Turrell, A.E. (2018). “An Interdisciplinary Model for Macroeconomics.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), pp. 219251.Google Scholar
Hale, J.K. (1969). Ordinary Differential Equations. New York: Wiley Interscience.Google Scholar
Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. eds. (2001). Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hamermesh, D.S. (1993). Labor Demand. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Handel, M.J. (2003). “Skills Mismatch in the Labor Market.” Annual Review of Sociology, 29, pp. 135165.Google Scholar
Harcourt, G.C. (1972). Some Cambridge Controversies in the Theory of Capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Harcourt, G.C. and Laing, N.F. (eds.), (1971). Capital and Growth. Harmondswirth: Penguin.Google Scholar
Hargreaves-Heap, S.P. (1980). “Choosing the Wrong Natural Rate: Accelerating Inflation or Decelerating Employment and Growth.” Economic Journal, 90(359), pp. 611620.Google Scholar
Hargreaves-Heap, S. and Varoufakis, Y. (2002). “Some Experimental Evidence on the Evolution of Discrimination, Co-operation and Perceptions of Fairness.” Economic Journal, 112(481), 679703.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. (1939). “An Essay in Dynamic Theory.” Economic Journal, 49(193), 1433.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. (1973). Economic Dynamics. London and Basingstoke: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hazell, J., Herreño, J., Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2022). “The Slope of the Phillips Curve: Evidence from U.S. States.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 137(3), pp. 12991344.Google Scholar
Heckman, J.J. (2007). “Comments on Are Protective Labor Market Institutions at the Root of Unemployment? A Critical Review of the Evidence by David Howell, Dean Baker, Andrew Glyn, and John Schmitt.” Capitalism and Society, 2(1), Article 5.Google Scholar
Hein, E. (2014). Distribution and Growth after Keynes. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
Hendry, D.F. and Muellbauer, J.N.J. (2018). “The Future of Macroeconomics: Macro Theory and Models at the Bank of England.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), pp. 287328.Google Scholar
Herndon, T., Ash, M. and Pollin, R. (2014). “Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff.” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38(2), pp. 257279.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. (1935). “Annual Survey of Economic Theory: The Theory of Monopoly.” Econometrica, 3(1), pp. 120.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. (1937). “Mr. Keynes and the ‘Classics’; A Suggested Interpretation.” Econometrica, 5(2) (April), pp. 147159.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. (1950). A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. (1965). Capital and Growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. (1975). The Crisis in Keynesian Economics. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. (1980–81). “‘IS-LM’: An Explanation.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 3(2) (Winter), pp. 139154.Google Scholar
Hirsch, F. (1977). Social Limits to Growth, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul Ltd.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A.O. (1970). Exit, Voice and Loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (1988). Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Hoel, M. and Sterner, T. (2007). “Discounting and Relative Prices.” Climatic Change, 84(3–4), pp. 265280.Google Scholar
Hoff, K. and Stiglitz, J. (2016). “Striving for Balance in Economics: Towards a Theory of the Social Determination of Behavior.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 126, Part B, pp. 2557.Google Scholar
Holt, R.P.F., Rosser, J.B. and Colander, D. (2011). “The Complexity Era in Economics.” Review of Political Economy, 23(3), pp. 357369.Google Scholar
Hoover, K.D. (1988). The New Classical Macroeconomics: A Sceptical Inquiry. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hoover, K.D. (2001). The Methodology of Empirical Macroeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Howell, D.R., Baker, D., Glyn, A. and Schmitt, J. (2007). “Are Protective Labor Market Institutions at the Root of Unemployment? A Critical Review of the Evidence.” Capitalism and Society, 2(1), Article 1.Google Scholar
Hubbard, R. and Palia, D. (1995). “Benefits of Control, Managerial Ownership, and the Stock Returns of Acquiring Firms.” RAND Journal of Economics, 26(4), pp. 782793.Google Scholar
Irons, J. and Bivens, J. (2010). “Government Debt and Economic Growth.” EPI Briefing Paper #271. Economic Policy Institute.Google Scholar
Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976). “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3, pp. 305360.Google Scholar
Johansson-Stenman, O., Carlson, F. and Daruvala, D. (2002). “Measuring Future Grandparents’ Preferences for Equality and Relative Standing.” Economic Journal, 112(479), pp. 362383.Google Scholar
Johnson, D.S., Parker, J.A. and Souleles, N.S. (2006). “Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates of 2001.” American Economic Review, 96(5), pp. 15891610.Google Scholar
Johnston, K. (2019). “What Makes You Work Harder? Strap on a Censor and Find Out.” The Boston Globe, July 16.Google Scholar
Jones, C.I. and Klenow, P.J. (2016). “Beyond GDP? Welfare across Countries and Time.” American Economic Review, 106(9), pp. 24262457.Google Scholar
Jonscher, C. (1994). “An Economic Study of the Information Technology Revolution.” In Allen, T. J. and Scott Morton, M.S.. (eds.), Information Technology and the Corporation of the 1990s: Research Studies, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Jonsson, T. and Österholm, P. (2012). “The Properties of Survey-based Inflation Expectations in Sweden.” Empirical Economics, 42, pp. 7994.Google Scholar
Kahn, S. (1997). “Evidence of Nominal Wage Stickiness from Microdata.” American Economic Review, 87(5), pp. 9931008.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (1994). “New Challenges to the Rationality Assumption.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 150(1), pp. 1836.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J.L. and Thaler, R. (1986). “Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market.” American Economic Review, 76(4), 728741.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J.L. and Thaler, R. (1991). “The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion and Status quo Bias.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193206.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1940). “A Model of the Trade Cycle.” Economic Journal, 50(197), pp. 7892.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1955). “Alternative Theories of Distribution.” Review of Economic Studies, 23(2), pp. 83100.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1966). “Marginal Productivity and the Macro-economic Theories of Distribution: Comment on Samuelson and Modigliani.” The Review of Economic Studies, 33(4), pp. 309319.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1980). “Monetarism and U.K. Monetary Policy.” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 4(4), 293318.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. (1935 [1971]). “The Mechanism of the Business Upswing.” Reprinted in M. Kalecki (1971) Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. (1937a). “The Principle of Increasing Risk.” Economica, 4(16), pp. 440447.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. (1937b). “A Theory of the Business Cycle.” Review of Economic Studies, 4(2), pp. 7797.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. (1943 [1971]). “Political Aspects of Full Employment.” The Political Quarterly, pp. 322330. Reprinted in M. Kalecki (1971) Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy 1933–1970, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. (1976). Essays on Developing Economies. Hassocks: Harvester Press.Google Scholar
Kaplan, G., Moll, B. and Violante, G.L. (2018). “Monetary Policy According to HANK.” American Economic Review, 108(3), 697743.Google Scholar
Kaplan, G. and Violante, G.L. (2018). “Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(3), pp. 167194.Google Scholar
Karanassou, M., Sala, H. and Snower, D.J. (2005). “A Reappraisal of the Inflation–Unemployment Tradeoff.” European Journal of Political Economy, 21(1), pp. 132.Google Scholar
Kashyap, A. (1995). “Sticky Prices: New Evidence from Retail Catalogs.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1), pp. 245274.Google Scholar
Katz, L.F. and Murphy, K.M. (1992). Changes in Relative Wages, 1963–1987: Supply and Demand Factors: Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(1), pp. 3578.Google Scholar
Kehoe, P. and Midrigan, V. (2015). “Prices Are Sticky after All.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 75, pp. 3553.Google Scholar
Kelton, S. (2019). “The Wealthy Are Victims of Their Own Propaganda.” Bloomberg, February 1, 2019, (www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2019-02-01/rich-must-embrace-deficits-to-escape-taxes#xj4y7vzkg).Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1930a [1981]). “The Question of HighWages.” The Political Quarterly. Reprinted in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes Vol. XX, London and Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1981, pp. 316.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1930b). A Treatise on Money Macmillan, The Collected Works of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. V.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London and Basingstoke: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1937a). “Ex Ante and Ex Post.” Reprinted in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes Vol. XIV, London and Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1978.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1937b). “The General Theory of Employment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51(2), pp. 209223.Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1939). “Relative Movements of Real Wages and Output.” Economic Journal, 49(193), pp. 3451.Google Scholar
Kim, H.K. and Skott, P. (2016). “Labor Market Reforms and Wage Inequality in Korea.” Metroeconomica, 67(2), pp. 313333.Google Scholar
King, J. (2012). The Microfoundations Delusion. Cheltenham: Elgar.Google Scholar
King, R.G. (2000). “The New IS-LM Model: Language, Logic and Limits.” Economic Quarterly, 86(3), pp. 45103.Google Scholar
Kirman, A. (1989). “The Intrinsic Limits of Modern Economic Theory: The Emperor has No Clothes.” Economic Journal, 99(395), pp. 12639.Google Scholar
Kirman, A. (1992). “Who or What Does the Representative Individual Represent?The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(2), pp. 117136.Google Scholar
Kirsanova, T., Leith, C. and Wren-Lewis, S. (2009). “Monetary and Fiscal Policy Interaction: The Current Consensus Assignment in the Light of Recent Developments.” Economic Journal, 119(541), pp. F482–F496.Google Scholar
Klenow, P.J. and Malin, B.A. (2010). “Microeconomic Evidence on Price-Setting.” In Friedman, B.M. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, 3, Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 231284.Google Scholar
Kleven, H. Jacobsen. (2014). “How Can Scandinavians Tax So Much?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(4), pp. 7798.Google Scholar
Klump, R., McAdam, P. and Willman, A. (2007). “Factor Substitution and Factor-Augmenting Technical Progress in the United States: A Normalized Supply-Side System Approach.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(1), pp. 18392.Google Scholar
Koszegi, B. and Rabin, M. (2006). “A Model of Reference-Dependent Preferences.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), pp. 11331165.Google Scholar
Kotz, D., McDonough, T. and Reich, M. (1994). Social Structures of Accumulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Krueger, A.B. (1999). Measuring Labor’s Share, in American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 89(2), 4551.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (1994). “Past and Prospective Causes of High Unemployment.” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (1998). “It’s Baaack: Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 29(2), pp. 137206.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2010). “Notes on Rogoff.” The New York Times, krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/07/21/notes-on-rogoff-wonkish/.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2013). “The Japan Story.” The New York Times, krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/02/05/the-japan-story/?_r=0.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2018a). “Good Enough for Government Work? Macroeconomics Since the Crisis.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), pp. 156168.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2018b). “What Do We Actually Know about the Economy?New York Times, 16 September.Google Scholar
Kurz, H.D. and Salvadori, N. (1995) Theory of Production: A Long-Period Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kurzweil, R. (1992). The Age of Intelligent Machines. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. (1977). “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans.” Journal of Political Economy, 85(3), pp. 473492.Google Scholar
Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. (1982). “Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations.” Econometrica, Econometric Society, 50(6, Nov.), pp. 13451370.Google Scholar
Lachowska, M. and Mych, M. (2018). “The Effect of Public Pension Wealth on Saving and Expenditure.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 10(3), pp. 284308.Google Scholar
Laibson, D. and List, J.A. (2015). “Principles of (Behavioral) Economics.” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 2015, 105(5), 385390.Google Scholar
La Porta, R. and Shleifer, A. (2014). “Informality and Development.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(3), pp. 109126.Google Scholar
Lavoie, M. (2014). Post-Keynesian Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Lawler, P. (2001). “Centralised Wage Setting, Inflation Contracts, and the Optimal Choice of Central Banker.” Economic Journal, 110(463), pp. 559575.Google Scholar
Layard, R. Nickell, S. and Jackman, R. (1991). Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Leão, P. (2013). “The Effect of Government Spending on the Debt-to-GDP Ratio: Some Keynesian Arithmetic.” Metroeconomica, 64(3), pp. 448465.Google Scholar
Lebergott, S. (1964). Manpower in Economic Growth. The American Record since 1800. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. (1968). On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. (1999). “Mr. Keynes and the Moderns.” In Pasinetti, L. and Schefold, B. (eds.), The Impact of Keynes on Economics in the Twentieth Century, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Lerner, A.P. (1943). “Functional Finance and the Federal Debt.” Social Research, 10(1), pp. 3851.Google Scholar
Levine, R. and Renelt, D. (1992). “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions.” American Economic Review, 82(4), pp. 942963.Google Scholar
Levy, D., Bergen, M., Dutta, S. and Venable, R. (1997). “The Magnitude of Menu Costs: Direct Evidence from Large U.S. Supermarket Chains.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(3), pp. 791825.Google Scholar
Lewis, M. (2017). The Undoing Project. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Lewis, W.A. (1954). “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor.” The Manchester School, 22(2), pp. 139191.Google Scholar
Lindbeck, A. and Snower, D.J (1988). The Insider-Outsider Theory of Employment and Unemployment, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Linde, J., Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2016). “Challenges for Central Banks’ Models.” Sveriges Riksbank Research Paper Series, 147.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (1972). “Expectations and the Neutrality of Money.” Journal of Economic Theory, 4(2), pp. 103124.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (1975). “An Equilibrium Model of the Business Cycle.” Journal of Political Economy, 83 (Dec.), pp. 11131144.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. Jr. (1976). “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique.” In Brunner, K. and Meltzer, A. (eds.), The Phillips Curve and the Labor Markets, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1, 1946.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. Jr. (1980). “The Death of Keynesian Economics.” Issues and Ideas, Winter, pp. 1819.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (1981). Studies in Business-cycle Theory. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (2003). “Macroeconomic Priorities.” American Economic Review, 93(1), pp. 114.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (2004). “The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 2003 Annual Report Essay.Google Scholar
Luo, M. (2010). “Overqualified? Yes, but Happy to Have a Job.” New York Times, 28 March 2010.Google Scholar
Luttmer, E. (2005). “Neighbors as Negatives: Relative Earnings and Well-being.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 120(3), pp. 9631002.Google Scholar
McNicholas, C., Mokhiber, Z. and von Wilpert, M. (2018). “Janus and Fair Share Fees: The organizations Financing the Attack on Unions’ Ability to Represent Workers.” Economic Policy Institute.Google Scholar
Maka, A. and Barbosa, F. (2013). “Phillips Curves: An Encompassing Test.” XLI Encontro Nacional de Economia (ANPEC).Google Scholar
Malinvaud, E. (1977). The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Mankiw, G. (2001). “The Inexorable and Mysterious Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment.” Economic Journal, 111(471), pp. 4561.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. G. and Reis, R. (2018). “Friedman’s Presidential Address in the Evolution of Macroeconomic Thought.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(1), pp. 8196.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N.G. Rotemberg, J.J. and Summers, L.H. (1985). “Intertemporal Substitution in Macroeconomics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, pp. 225251.Google Scholar
Manning, A. (2003). Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Mantel, R. (1976). “Homothetic Preferences and Community Excess Demand Functions.” Journal of Economic Theory, 12(2), 197201.Google Scholar
Marglin, S.A. (1984). Growth, Distribution, and Prices. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1887). “A Fair Rate of Wages.” In Pigou, A.C. (Ed.), 1956. Memorials of Alfred Marshall. New York: Kelley & Millman, pp. 212226.Google Scholar
Martinez, I.Z., Saez, E. and Siegenthaler, M. (2021). “Intertemporal Labor Supply Substitution? Evidence from the Swiss Tax Holidays.” American Economic Review, 111(2), pp. 506546.Google Scholar
Martins, G.K. and Skott, P. (2021). “Macroeconomic Policy, Inflation and Deindustrialization in a Dual Economy.” Industrial and Corporate Change, 30(2), pp. 409444.Google Scholar
Marx, K. (1852 [1978]). The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte. Beijing: Foreign Languages Press.Google Scholar
Marx, K. (1867 [1906]). Capital. A Critique of Political Economy, vol. 1. The Modern Library, New York.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Michael, D., Whinston and Jerry R. Green (1995). Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mason, J.W. (2018). “Income Distribution, Household Debt, and Aggregate Demand: A Critical Assessment.” Levy Economics Institute Working Paper 901.Google Scholar
Matthews, P.H. (2021). “The Dialectics of Differentiation: Marx’s Mathematical Manuscripts and Their Relation to His Economics.” Review of Social Economy, 79(1), pp. 2550.Google Scholar
Mavroeidis, S., Plagborg-Møller, M. and Stock, J.H. (2014). “Empirical Evidence on Inflation Expectations in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve.” Journal of Economic Literature, 52(1), 124188.Google Scholar
Mian, A. and Sufi, A. (2009). “The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expansion: Evidence from the U.S. Mortgage Default Crisis.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4), pp. 14491496.Google Scholar
Mian, A. and Sufi, A. (2011). “House Prices, Home Equity-Based Borrowing, and the US Household Leverage Crisis.” American Economic Review, 101(5), pp. 21322156.Google Scholar
Mian, A. and Sufi, A. (2018). “Finance and Business Cycles: The Credit-Driven Household Demand Channel.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(3), pp. 3158.Google Scholar
Michl, T.R. (2013). “Public Debt, Growth, and Distribution.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 1(1), 272296.Google Scholar
Miller, M.H. and Modigliani, F. (1961). “Dividend Policy, Growth, and the Valuation of Shares.” Journal of Business, 34(4), pp. 411433.Google Scholar
Minford, P. (1980). “Memorandum by Professor A.P. Minford.” In Memoranda on Monetary Policy, House of Commons Treasury and Civil Service Committee, sess. 1979–80, HMSO.Google Scholar
Minsky, Hyman P. (1975). John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. (1986). Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. (1993). “The Financial Instability Hypothesis.” In Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (eds.), The Elgar Companion to Radical Political Economy, pp. 153158, Aldershot: Elgar.Google Scholar
Mishel, L. and Kandra, J. (2021). “CEO Pay Has Skyrocketed 1,322% since 1978.” EPI Report, epi.org/232540.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M.H. (1958). “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment.” The American Economic Review, 48(3), pp. 261297.Google Scholar
Moore, B.J. (1988). Horizontalists and Verticalists: The Macroeconomics of Credit Money, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Moriguchi, Chiaki and Saez, Emmanuel. (2007). “The Evolution of Income Concentration in Japan, 1886–2005: Evidence from Income Tax Statistics.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), pp. 713734.Google Scholar
Morishima, M. (1966). “Refutation of the Nonswitching Theorem.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(4), pp. 520525.Google Scholar
Muellbauer, J. (2010). “Household Decisions, Credit Markets and the Macroeconomy: Implications for the Design of Central Bank Models.” Bank for International Settlements, Working Paper 306.Google Scholar
Muellbauer, J. (2020). “Implications of Household-Level Evidence for Policy Models: The Case of Macro-financial Linkages.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 36(3), pp. 510555.Google Scholar
Muellbauer, J. and Murphy, A. (1997). “Booms and Busts in the UK Housing Market.” Economic Journal, 107(445), pp. 17011727.Google Scholar
Munnell, A.H., Chen, A. and Siliciano, R.L. (2021). “The National Retirement Index: An Update from the 2019 SCF.” Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, Briefs, January, 21(2).Google Scholar
Murakami, H. (2018). “A Two-sector Keynesian Model of Business Cycles.” Metroeconomica, 69(2), pp. 444472.Google Scholar
Murphy, K.J. and Zábojník, J. (2004). “CEO Pay and Appointments: A Market-based Explanation for Recent Trends.” American Economic Review, 94(2), pp. 192196.Google Scholar
Musgrave, A. (1981). “‘Unreal Assumptions’ in Economic Theory: The F-Twist Untwisted.” Kyklos, 34(3), pp. 377387.Google Scholar
Muth, J.F. (1961). “Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements.” Econometrica, 29(3), pp. 315335.Google Scholar
Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2013). “Price Rigidity: Microeconomic Evidence and Macroeconomic Implications.” Annual Review of Economics, 5, pp. 133163.Google Scholar
Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2014). “Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union: Evidence from US Regions.” American Economic Review, 104(3), pp. 753792.Google Scholar
Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2018). “Identification in Macroeconomics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(3), pp. 5986.Google Scholar
Nakatani, T. and Skott, P. (2007). “Japanese Growth and Stagnation: A Keynesian Perspective.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 18(3), pp. 306332.Google Scholar
Nersisyan, Y. and Wray, L.R. (2010). “Deficit Hysteria Redux? Why We Should Stop Worrying about U.S. Government Deficits.” Public Policy Brief, no. 111, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.Google Scholar
Newell, A. and Symons, J.S.V. (1987). “Corporatism, Laissez Faire, and the Rise in Unemployment.” European Economic Review, 31(3), 567601.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. (1978). The Investment Decisions of Firms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. (1997). “Unemployment and Labour Market Rigidities: Europe Versus North America.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), pp. 5574.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. (1998). “Unemployment: Questions and Some Answers.” The Economic Journal, 108(448), pp. 802816.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. (2003). “Labour Market Institutions and Unemployment in OECD Countries.” CESifo DICE Report 2/2003.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D. (1994). Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D. (2008). A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Noyola, J.F. (1956). “Inflation in Chile: An Unorthodox Approach.” International Economic Papers, 10, pp. 603648.Google Scholar
Nurkse, R. (1953). Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
O’Brien, M. (2013). “Forget Excel: This Was Reinhart and Rogoff’s Biggest Mistake – Correlation Is Not Causation.” The Atlantic, www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2013/04/forget-excel-this-was-reinhart-and-rogoffs-biggest-mistake/275088/.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, M. (2013). “On Keeping Your Powder Dry: Fiscal Foundations of Financial and Price Stability.” Working Paper 9563, CEPR.Google Scholar
O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (1999). “Doing It Now or Later.” American Economic Review, 89(1), pp. 103124.Google Scholar
O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (2015). “Present Bias: Lessons Learned and to Be Learned.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 105(5), pp. 273279.Google Scholar
OECD. (1994). Jobs Study. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OECD. (2000). Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OECD. (2015). Economic Surveys – Japan April 2015. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OECD. (2019a). Economic Surveys – Japan April 2019. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OECD. (2019b). Tax Policy Reforms 2019: OECD and Selected Partner Economies, OECD Publishing, Paris, doi.org/10.1787/da56c295-en.Google Scholar
Oh, J-S. (2018). “Macroeconomic Stability in a Flexible Labor Market.” Metroeconomica, 69(3), pp. 655680.Google Scholar
Oswald, A. (1997). “Happiness and Economic Performance.” The Economic Journal, 107 (November), pp. 18151831.Google Scholar
Palley, T. (2002). “Economic Contradictions Coming Home to Roost? Does the U.S. Economy Face a Long-Term Aggregate Demand Generation Problem?Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 25(1), pp. 932.Google Scholar
Palley, T. (2010). “The Simple Macroeconomics of Fiscal Austerity, Public Sector Debt and Deflation.” IMK Working Paper, no.8/2010. Dusseldorf.Google Scholar
Palley, T. (2019). “The Fallacy of the Natural Rate of Interest and Zero Lower Bound Economics: Why Negative Interest Rates May Not Remedy Keynesian Unemployment.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 7(2), pp. 151170.Google Scholar
Palley, T. (2020). “What’s Wrong with Modern Money Theory: Macro and Political Economic Restraints on Deficit-financed Fiscal Policy.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 8(4), pp. 472493.Google Scholar
Parker, J.A., Souleles, N.S., Johnson, D.S. and McClelland, R. (2013). “Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008.” American Economic Review, 103(6), pp. 25302553.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L.L. (1962). “Rate· of Profit and Income Distribution in Relation to the Rate of Economic Growth.” Review of Economic Studies, 29(4), pp. 267279.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L.L. (1966). “Paradoxes in Capital Theory: A Symposium: Changes in the Rate of Profit and Switches of Techniques.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(4), pp. 503517.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L.L. (1969). “Switches of Technique and the ‘Rate of Return’ in Capital Theory.” Economic Journal, 79(315), pp. 508531.Google Scholar
Pástor, L. and Veronesi, P. (2009). “Technological Revolutions and Stock Prices.” American Economic Review, 99(4), pp. 14511483.Google Scholar
Pedersen, P. and Smith, N. (2002). “Unemployment Traps: Do Financial Disincentives Matter?European Sociological Review, 18(3), pp. 271288.Google Scholar
Penrose, E. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (1990). Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics, Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Phelps, Edmund S. (1967). “Phillips Curves, Expectations of Inflation, and Optimal Unemployment Over Time.” Economica, 34(135), pp. 254281.Google Scholar
Phelps, E.S. (1969). “The New Microeconomics in Inflation and Employment Theory.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 59(2), pp. 147160.Google Scholar
Phillips, A.W. (1958). “The Relationship between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the United Kingdom 1861–1957.” Economica. 25(100), pp. 283299.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. (2020). Capital and Ideology. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. and Saez, E. (2003). Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–2002. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), pp. 139.Google Scholar
Piketty, T., Postel-Vinay, G. and Rosenthal, J-L. (2006). “Wealth Concentration in a Developing Economy: Paris and France, 1807–1994.” American Economic Review, 96(1), pp. 236256.Google Scholar
Pollin, R. and Zhu, A. (2006). “Inflation and Economic Growth: A Cross-country Nonlinear Analysis.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 28(4), pp. 593614.Google Scholar
Poterba, J.M. (1987). “Tax Policy and Corporate Saving.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1987, pp. 455503.Google Scholar
Rabin, M. (1998). “Psychology and Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature XXXVI (March), pp. 1146.Google Scholar
Rabinovich, J. (2019). “The Financialization of the Non-financial Corporation. A Critique to the Financial Turn of Accumulation Hypothesis.” Metroeconomica, 70(4), pp. 738775.Google Scholar
Rachel, L. and Summers, L. (2019). “On Secular Stagnation in the Industrialized World.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 50(1), pp. 154.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F.P. (1928). “A Mathematical Theory of Saving.” Economic Journal, 38(152), pp. 543559.Google Scholar
Raymond, E. (1999). “The Cathedral and the Bazaar.” Knowledge, Technology and Policy, 12, pp. 2349.Google Scholar
Razmi, A., Rapetti, M. and Skott, P. (2012). “The Real Exchange Rate and Economic Development.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 23(2), pp. 151169.Google Scholar
Read, D., Loewenstein, G. F. and Kalyanaraman, S. (1999). “Mixing Virtue and Vice: Combining the Immediacy Effect and the Diversification Heuristic.” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12, pp. 257273.Google Scholar
Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. (2009). “The Aftermath of Financial Crises.” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 99(2), pp. 466472.Google Scholar
Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. (2010). “Growth in a Time of Debt.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 100(2), pp. 573578.Google Scholar
Reis, R. (2006). “Inattentive Producers.” Review of Economic Studies, 73(3), pp. 793821.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1953–54). “The Production Function and the Theory of Capital.” Review of Economic Studies, 21(2), pp. 81106.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1970). “Quantity Theories Old and New: A Comment.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2(4), pp. 504512.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1971). “Capital Theory up to Date: A Reply.” Canadian Journal of Economics, 4(2), pp. 254256.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1974a). “History versus Equilibrium.” Thames Papers in Political Economy.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1974b). “What Has Become of the Keynesian Revolution?Challenge, 16(6), pp. 611.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1978). Contributions to Modern Economics. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Rogoff, K. (1985). “The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, pp. 11691190.Google Scholar
Roine, J. and Waldenström, D. (2006). The Evolution of Top Incomes in an Egalitarian Society: Sweden, 19032004. Helsinki: IEHC.Google Scholar
Romer, D. (2018). Advanced Macroeconomics, 5th Ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Romer, P. (2016). “The Trouble with Macroeconomics.” paulromer.net/the-troublewith-macro/WP-Trouble.pdf.Google Scholar
Roose, K. (2019). “When Tech Takes over Boss’s Role.” New York Times, 24 June.Google Scholar
Ros, J. (2013). Rethinking Economic Development, Growth and Institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rose, H. (1967). “On the Non-Linear Theory of the Employment Cycle.” Review of Economic Studies, 34(2), pp. 153173.Google Scholar
Rowthorn, R. (1977). “Conflict, Inflation and Money.” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1(3), pp. 215239.Google Scholar
Rowthorn, R. (1995). “Capital Formation and Unemployment.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 11(1), pp. 2639.Google Scholar
Rudd, J. and Whelan, K. (2005). “New Tests of the New-Keynesian Phillips Curve.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(6), pp. 11671181.Google Scholar
Ryoo, S. (2010). Long Waves and Short Cycles in a Model of Endogenous Financial Fragility. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 74, pp. 163186.Google Scholar
Ryoo, S. (2016). “Household Debt and Housing Bubbles: A Minskian Approach to Boom-bust Cycles.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 26(5), pp. 9711006.Google Scholar
Ryoo, S. and Kim, Y.K. (2014). “Income Distribution, Consumer Debt and Keeping Up with the Joneses.” Metroeconomica, 65(4), pp. 585618.Google Scholar
Ryoo, S. and Skott, P. (2013). “Public Debt and Full Employment in a Stock-Flow Consistent Model of a Corporate Economy.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 35(4), pp. 511527.Google Scholar
Ryoo, S. and Skott, P. (2017). “Fiscal and Monetary Policy Rules in an Unstable Economy.” Metroeconomica, 68(3), pp. 500548.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. (1939). “Interactions between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principle of Acceleration.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 21(2), pp. 7578.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. (1966). “A Summing Up.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(4), pp. 568583.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. and Modigliani, F. (1966). “The Pasinetti Paradox in Neoclassical and More General Models.” Review of Economic Studies, 33(4), pp. 269301.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. and Solow, R.M. (1960). “Analytical Aspects of Anti-Inflation Policy.” American Economic Review, 50(2), pp. 177194.Google Scholar
Sarel, M. (1996). “Nonlinear Effects of Inflation on Economic Growth.” Internation Monetary Fund – Staff Papers, 43(1), pp. 199215.Google Scholar
Sattinger, M. (2006). “Overlapping Labor Markets.” Labour Economics, 13, pp. 237257.Google Scholar
Schlicht, E. (2006). “Public Debt as Private Wealth: Some Equilibrium Considerations.” Metroeconomica, 57(4), pp. 494520.Google Scholar
Schmitt-Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2007). “Optimal Simple and Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, pp. 17021725.Google Scholar
Schneider, D. and Harknett, K. (2019). “It’s about Time: How Work Schdule Instability Matters for Workers, Families and Racial Inequality.” Research Brief, October 2019, shift.hks.harvard.edu/files/2019/10/Its-About-Time-How-Work-Schedule-Instability-Matters-for-Workers-Families-and-Racial-Inequality.pdf.Google Scholar
Seater, J.J. (1993). “Ricardian Equivalence.” Journal of Economic Literature, 31(1), pp. 142190.Google Scholar
Seers, D. (1962). “A Theory of Inflation and Growth in Under-Developed Economies Based on the Experience of Latin America.” Oxford Economic Papers, 14 (June), pp. 174195.Google Scholar
Sell, S. and May, C. (2001). Moments in Law: Contestation and Settlement in the History of Intellectual Property. Review of International Political Economy, 8(3) pp. 467500.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1983). “Poor, Relatively Speaking.” Oxford Economic Papers, 35(2), pp. 153169.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1992). Inequality Reexamined. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (2000). “The Discipline of Cost-benefit Analysis.” The Journal of Legal Studies, 29(S2), pp. 931952.Google Scholar
Sethi, R. (1996). “Endogenous Regime Switching in Speculative Markets.” Structural Change and Econonmic Dynamics, 7(1), pp. 99118.Google Scholar
Setterfield, M. and Thirlwall, A. (2010). “Macrodynamics for a Better Society: The Economics of John Cornwall.” Review of Political Economy, 22(4), pp. 481498.Google Scholar
Shaikh, A. (1974). “Laws of Production and Laws of Algebra: The Humbug Production Function.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 56(1), pp. 115120.Google Scholar
Shafir, E. Diamond, P. and Tversky, A. (1997). “Money Illusion.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), pp. 341374.Google Scholar
Shapiro, C. and Stiglitz, J. (1984). “Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device.” American Economic Review, 74(3), pp. 433444.Google Scholar
Shea, J. (1995). “Union Contracts and the Life-cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis.” American Economic Review, 85 (March), pp. 186200.Google Scholar
Shefrin, H.M. and Thaler, R.H. (1988). “The Behavioral Life-cycle Hypothesis.” Economic Inquiry, 26(4), pp. 609643.Google Scholar
Sheffrin, S.M. (1983). Rational Expectations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sims, C.A. (2003). “Implications of Rational Inattention.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, pp. 665690.Google Scholar
Simon, H.A. (1957). Models of Man. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (1981). “On the Kaldorian Saving Function.” Kyklos, 34(3), pp. 563581.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (1988). “Finance, Saving and Accumulation.” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12(3), pp. 339354.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (1989a). “Effective Demand, Class Struggle and Cyclical Growth.” International Economic Review, 30(1), pp. 231247.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (1989b). Conflict and Effective Demand in Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (1991). “Efficiency Wages, Mark-up Pricing and Effective Demand.” In Michie, J. (Ed.), The Economics of Restructuring and Intervention. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, pp. 138151.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (1997). “Stagflationary Consequences of Prudent Monetary Policy in a Unionized Economy.” Oxford Economic Papers, 49(4), pp. 609622.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (1999). “Wage Formation and the (Non-) Existence of the NAIRU.” Economic Issues, 4, pp. 7792.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2001). “Demand Policy in the Long Run.” In Arestis, P., Desai, M. and Dow, S. (eds.), Money Macroeconomics and Keynes, Routledge, pp. 124139.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2005). “Fairness as a Source of Hysteresis in Employment and Relative Wages.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 57, pp. 305331.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2006). “Wage Inequality and Overeducation in a Model with Efficiency Wages.” Canadian Journal of Economics, 39(1), pp. 94123.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2010). “Growth, Instability and Cycles: Harrodian and Kaleckian Models of Accumulation and Income Distribution.” In Setterfield, M. (ed.), Handbook of Alternative Theories of Economic Growth, Edward Elgar, pp. 108131.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2013). “Increasing Inequality and Financial Instability.” Review of Radical Political Economics, 45(4), pp. 474482.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2015). “Growth Cycles and Price Flexibility.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 3(3), pp. 374386.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2016a). “Aggregate Demand, Functional Finance, and Secular Stagnation.” European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention, 13(2), pp. 172188.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2016b). “Public Debt, Secular Stagnation and Functional Finance.” In Madsen, M.O. and Olesen, F. (eds.), Macroeconomics after the Financial Crisis: A Post-Keynesian Perspective, Routledge pp. 2037.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2021). “Fiscal Policy and Structural Transformation in Developing Economies.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 56, pp. 129140.Google Scholar
Skott, P. (2023). “Endogenous Business Cycles and Economic Policy.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 210, pp. 6182.Google Scholar
Skott, P. and Davis, L. (2013). “Distributional Biases in the Evaluation of Climate Change.” Ecological Economics, 85, pp. 188197.Google Scholar
Skott, P. and Guy, F. (2007). “A Model of Power-Biased Technological Change.” Economics Letters, 95, 124131.Google Scholar
Skott, P. and Guy, F. (2008). “Power, Productivity, and Profits.” In Braham, M. and Steffen, F. (eds.), Power, Freedom and Voting, Berlin: Springer Verlag, pp. 385404.Google Scholar
Skott, P. and Ryoo, S. (2008). “Macroeconomic Implications of Financialization.” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(6), pp. 827862.Google Scholar
Skott, P. and Ryoo, S. (2014). “Public Debt in an OLG Model with Imperfect Competition: Long-Run Effects of Austerity Programs and Changes in the Growth Rate.” BE Press Journal of Macroeconomics, 14(1), pp. 533552.Google Scholar
Skott, P. and Ryoo, S. (2017). “Functional Finance and Intergenerational Distribution in a Keynesian OLG Model.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 5(1), pp. 112134.Google Scholar
Skott, P. and Zipperer, B. (2012). “An Empirical Evaluation of Three Post-Keynesian Models.” Intervention – European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies, 9(2), pp. 277308.Google Scholar
Slonimczyk, F. and Skott, P. (2012). “Employment and Distribution Effects of the Minimum Wage.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 84(1), pp. 245264.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2003). “An Estimated Stochastic Dynamic General Equilibrium Model.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(5), pp. 11231175.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007). “Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach.” American Economic Review, 97(3), pp. 586606.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: Everyman edition.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. (1956). “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), pp. 6594.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. (1986). “What Is a Nice Girl Like You Doing in a Place Like This? Macroeconomics after Fifty Years.” Eastern Economic Journal, 12(3), pp. 191198.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. (1990). The Labor Market as a Social Institution. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. (1998). “What Is Labour-Market Flexibility? What Is It Good For?Keynes Lecture, British Academy, www.britac.ac.uk/pubs/proc/files/97p189.pdf.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. (2008). “The State of Macroeconomics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(1), pp. 243246.Google Scholar
Somville, V. and Vandewalle, L. (2018). “Saving by Default: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Rural India.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 10(3), pp. 3966.Google Scholar
Sonnenschein, H. (1972). “Market Excess Demand Functions.” Econometrica, 40(3), pp. 549563.Google Scholar
Staiger, D., Stock, J.H. and Watson, M.W. (1997). “The NAIRU, Unemployment and Monetary Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(1), pp. 3349.Google Scholar
Stallman, R. (1985). The GNU manifesto.Google Scholar
Stanton, E. (2010). “Negishi Welfare Weights in Integrated Assessment Models: The Mathematics of Global Inequality.” Climatic Change, 107(3), pp. 417432.Google Scholar
Starr, E. (2019). “The Use, Abuse and Enforceability of Non-Compete and No-Poach Agreements.” Economic Policy Institute.Google Scholar
Stedman, L.C. (2009). “The NAEP Long-Term Trend Assessment: A Re-View of Its Transformation, Use, and Findings.” Mimeo.Google Scholar
Stern, N. (2006). The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Online at www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_climate_change/sternreview_index.cfm.Google Scholar
Stevens, P. (2004). “Diseases of Poverty and the 10/90 Gap.” International Policy Network.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J.E. (1969). “A Re-Examination of the Modigliani–Miller Theorem.” American Economic Review, 59(5), pp. 784793.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J.E. (1997). “Reflections on the Natural Rate Hypothesis.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(1), pp. 310.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J.E. (2018). “Where Modern Macroeconomics Went Wrong.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), pp. 70106.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J.E. and Weiss, A. (1981). “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information.” American Economic Review, 71(3), pp. 393410.Google Scholar
Sturgeon, T.J. (2002). “Modular Production Networks: A New American Model of Industrial Organization.” Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(3), pp. 451496.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1986). The Economics of Rights, Welfare and Co-operation. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Summers, L.H. (2013). [Presentation at the] “IMF Fourteenth Annual Research Conference in Honor of Stanley Fischer.” larrysummers.com/imf-fourteenth-annualresearch-conference-in-honor-of-stanley-fischer/.Google Scholar
Summers, L.H. (2015a). “Demand Side Secular Stagnation.” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 105(5), pp. 6065.Google Scholar
Summers, L.H. (2015b). “On Secular Stagnation: A Response to Bernanke.” larrysummers.com/2015/04/01/on-secular-stagnation-a-response-to-bernanke/.Google Scholar
Summers, L.H. (2018). “Secular Stagnation and Macroeconomic Policy.” IMF Economic Review, 66, pp. 226250.Google Scholar
Sunkel, O. (1958). “La inflacion chilena: un enfoque heterodoxo.” El Trimestre Economico, 25, pp. 107131.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. (1995). “Why the Interpretation of the Cobb–Douglas Production Function Must be Radically Changed.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 6(4), pp. 485504.Google Scholar
Tarshis, L. (1939). “Changes in Real and Money Wage Rates.” Economic Journal, 49(193), pp. 150154.Google Scholar
Taylor, J.B. (1993). “Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, pp. 195214.Google Scholar
Tcherneva, P.R. (2019). “MMT Is Already Helping.” Jacobin, 02/27/2019.Google Scholar
Thaler, R.H. and Benartzi, S. (2004). “Save More Tomorrow – Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee Saving.” Journal of Political Economy, 112(1), pt. 2, pp. S164–S187.Google Scholar
Thompson, S. (2018). “Employment and Fiscal Policy in a Marxian Model.” Metroeconomica, 69(4), pp. 820846.Google Scholar
Tirole, J. (1986). “Hierarchies and Bureaucracies: On the Role of Collusion in Organizations.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 2(2), pp. 181214.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1969). “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1(1), pp. 1529.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1972). “Inflation and Unemployment.” American Economic Review, 62(1/2), pp. 118.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1975). “Keynesian Model of Recession and Depression.” American Economic Review, pp. 195202.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1980). Asset Accumulation and Economic Activity. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1986). “High Time to Restore the Employment Act of 1946.” Challenge, 29(2), pp. 412.Google Scholar
Tobin, J. (1993). “Price Flexibility and Output Stability: An Old Keynesian View.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(1), pp. 4565.Google Scholar
Toksvig, L. (2007). “Forsyningen af tømmer til flådens skibe i 1800-tallet. Historien om de nordsjællandske flådeege.” DST, Årg. 92. Hft. 128.Google Scholar
Torre, V. (1977). “Existence of Limit Cycles and Control in Complete Keynesian System by Theory of Bifurcation.” Econometrica, 45(6), pp. 14571466.Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1992). “Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Representation of Uncertainty.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), pp. 297323.Google Scholar
Twenge, J.M., Campbell, S.M., Hoffman, B.J. and Lance, C. E. (2010). “Generational Differences in Work Values: Leisure and Extrinsic Values Increasing, Social and Intrinsic Values Decreasing.” Journal of Management, 36(5), pp. 11171142.Google Scholar
Twenge, J.M., Campbell, S.M. and Freeman, E.C. (2012). “Generational Differences in Young Adults’ Life Goals, Concern for Others, and Civic Orientation, 1966–2009.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 102(5), pp. 10451062.Google Scholar
Uribe, M. (2000). “Staggered Price Indexation.” NBER working Paper w27657.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. (1899). The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions. New York: The Macmillan Company.Google Scholar
Vedder, R., Denhart, C. and Robe, J. (2013). “Why Are Recent College Graduates Underemployed?Institute of Education Science.Google Scholar
Vogelstein, F. (2013). “And Then Steve Said, ‘Let There Be an iPhone’.” New York Times (www.nytimes.com/2013/10/06/magazine/and-then-steve-said-let-there-be-an-iphone.html?pagewanted=all):Google Scholar
von Arnim, R. and Barrales, J. (2015). “Demand-Driven Goodwin Cycles with Kaldorian and Kaleckian Features.” Review of Keynesian Economics, 3(3), pp. 351373.Google Scholar
von Braun, C-F. (1990). “The Acceleration Trap.” Sloan Management Review, 32(1), pp. 4958.Google Scholar
Wade, J.B., Porac, J.F. and Pollock, T.G. (1997). “Worth, Words, and the Justification of Executive Pay.” Journal of Organizational Behavior, 18, pp. 641657.Google Scholar
Weed, J. (2020). “Looking for the Cheapest Airfare? Good Luck With That|.” New York Time, print edition January 28, p. B4 (online edition, January 27, www.nytimes.com/2020/01/27/business/cheap-airfare.html?searchResultPosition=1).Google Scholar
Weitzman, M.L. (2007). “A Review of The Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change.” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XLV (September), 703724.Google Scholar
Wilhelm, M.O. (1996). “Bequest Behavior and the Effect of Heirs’ Earnings: Testing the Altruistic Model of Bequests.” American Economic Review, 86(4), pp. 874892.Google Scholar
Wood, A. (1994). North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wood, A.J. and Burchell, B. (2018). Unemployment and Well-being. In Lewis, A. (ed.), The Cambridge Handbook of Psychology and Economic Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (1999). “Revolution and Evolution in Twentieth-Century Macroeconomics.” Paper presented at the conference, Frontiers of the Mind in the Twenty-First Century, U.S. Library of Congress, Washington DC. URL www.columbia.edu/mw2230/macro20C.pdf.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wray, R. (2000). “Can The Expansion Be Sustained? A Minskian View.” Levy Institute Policy Note 2000/5.Google Scholar
Wray, R. (2015). Modern Money Theory: A Primer on Macroeconomics for Sovereign Monetary Systems. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Wren-Lewis, S. (2007). “Are There Dangers in the Microfoundations Consensus?” In Arestis, P. (ed.), Is There a New Consensus in Macroeconomics? Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 4360.Google Scholar
Wren-Lewis, S. (2018). “Ending the Microfoundations Hegemony.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), pp. 5569.Google Scholar
Yagan, D. (2018). “Employment Hysteresis from the Great Recession.” UC Berkeley and NBER.Google Scholar
Yoo, G. and Kang, C. (2012). The Effect of Protection of Temporary Workers on Employment Levels: Evidence from the 2007 Reform of South Korea. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 65(3), pp. 578606.Google Scholar
Zeldes, S. (1989). “Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Political Economy, 97(2), pp. 305346.Google Scholar
Zipperer, B. and Skott, P. (2011). “Cyclical Patterns of Employment, Utilization and Profitability.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 44(1), pp. 2558.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Peter Skott, University of Massachusetts, Amherst
  • Book: Structuralist and Behavioral Macroeconomics
  • Online publication: 10 November 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009367349.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Peter Skott, University of Massachusetts, Amherst
  • Book: Structuralist and Behavioral Macroeconomics
  • Online publication: 10 November 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009367349.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Peter Skott, University of Massachusetts, Amherst
  • Book: Structuralist and Behavioral Macroeconomics
  • Online publication: 10 November 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009367349.014
Available formats
×