Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-tn8tq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-18T22:58:27.053Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

18 - Making Deals in Congress

from Lowering Barriers to Policy Making

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2015

Sarah A. Binder
Affiliation:
George Washington University
Frances E. Lee
Affiliation:
University of Maryland
Nathaniel Persily
Affiliation:
Stanford Law School
Get access

Summary

There is one unavoidable fact about legislating in a democratic system. No single person, faction, or interest can get everything it wants. Legislating inevitably means compromising, except in the rare circumstances when consensus is so strong that one dominant view can prevail with ease.

Robert Kaiser 2013, p. 174

Compromise may be the “unavoidable fact” about legislating in a democratic system. Yet, scholars have few systematic answers to this question: How do legislators “get to yes”? To put the question in language more familiar to students of politics: How do politicians with diverse, often-conflicting interests and policy preferences reach agreements on public policy in a legislative body of co-equals? In this chapter, we offer a perspective on deal making in the contemporary Congress, highlighting the impact of political and partisan considerations on lawmakers' abilities to secure policy agreements.

Negotiation in Congress is never solely about policy: politics and policy are always intertwined. Congressional negotiations thus differ from those in the private sector, in which actors seek to maximize benefits and minimize costs and the substantive terms of an offer are paramount. Congressional deal making occurs in a political context that shapes the willingness of party leaders and their “rank and file” to negotiate at all or to accept even favorable offers. Lawmakers must justify votes and policy compromises to their constituencies, whereas party leaders must attend to key groups in the party coalition and to the party's public image. Given the political context of congressional negotiations, we evaluate the tools and institutional arrangements that make deals in Congress more likely – emphasizing that conflicting incentives and interests place a premium on negotiating out of the public eye. We conclude with a broader assessment of the prospects for negotiation in a party-polarized Congress.

DISTRIBUTIVE VERSUS INTEGRATIVE MODELS OF NEGOTIATION IN CONGRESS

Negotiation theorists typically distinguish between distributive and integrative solutions to public problems (see Chapters 4 and 5). Distributive solutions involve zero-sum bargaining over extant benefits.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adler, E. Scott and Wilkerson, John D.. 2013. Congress and the Politics of Problem Solving. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Andres, Gary. 2005. “The Contemporary Presidency: Polarization and White House/Legislative Relations: Causes and Consequences of Elite-Level Conflict.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 35(4): 761–770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnold, Douglas. 1990. Logic of Congressional Action. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and Gertner, Robert. 1989. “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules.” Yale Law Journal 99: 87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, Michael, and McCarty, Nolan. 2013. “Causes and Consequences of Polarization.” In Negotiating Agreement in Politics, eds. Martin, Cathie Jo and Mansbridge, Jane. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association: 19–53.Google Scholar
Baron, David, and Ferejohn, John. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83(4): 1181–1206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, Mindy. 2003. “Principled Negotiating: Breeding Success and Protecting Public Interests behind Closed Doors.” Georgetown Journal of Law and Policy 1: 431–444.Google Scholar
Bessette, Joseph M. 1994. The Mild Voice of Reason: Deliberative Democracy and American National Government. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Binder, Sarah A. 2003. Stalemate: Causes and Consequences of Legislative Gridlock. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Blake, Aaron. 2013. “Corker: My Border Security Deal Is ‘Almost Overkill.'” Washington Post, June 20. Retrieved July 31, 2013, from www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/post-politics/wp/2013/06/20/corker-my-border-security-deal-is-almost-overkill/?wprss=rss_politics&wpisrc=nl_wonk_b.
Brandt, Evan. 2013. “Toomey Doubts Second Senate Gun-Control Vote Any Time Soon.” The Times Herald (Norristown, PA), May 1.
Canes-Wrone, Brandice. 2001. “The President's Legislative Influence from Public Appeals.” American Journal of Political Science 45(2): 313–329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and Terry, William C.. 2008. “Legislative Productivity in the 93rd–105th Congresses.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 33(4): 603–618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, George. 2003. On Deaf Ears. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Evans, C. Lawrence. 2011. “Congressional Committees.” In The Oxford Handbook of the American Congress, eds. Schickler, Eric and Lee, Frances E.. New York: Oxford University Press: 396–425.Google Scholar
Evans, Diana. 2004. Greasing the Wheels: Using Pork Barrel Projects to Build Majority Coalitions in Congress. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Follett, Mary Parker. [1925]1942. “Constructive Conflict.” In Dynamic Administration: The Collected Papers of Mary Parker Follett, eds. Metcalf, H. C. and Urwick, L.. New York: Harper: 30–49.Google Scholar
Gilmour, John B. 1995. Strategic Disagreement: Stalemate in American Politics. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul E.. 2005. Off Center: The Republican Revolution and the Erosion of American Democracy. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hibbing, John, and Theiss-Morse, Elizabeth. 1995. Congress as Public Enemy. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hulse, Carl, and Nagourney, Adam. 2010. “Senate G.O.P. Leader Finds Weapon in Unity.” New York Times, March 16, A13.
Kaiser, Robert. 2013. Act of Congress: How America's Essential Institution Works, and How It Doesn't. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Karol, David. 2009. Party Position Change in American Politics: Coalition Management. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kernell, Samuel. 2006. Going Public. 4th edition. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1995. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. 2nd edition. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith, and Rivers, Douglas. 1988. “The Analysis of Committee Power: An Application to Senate Voting on the Minimum Wage.” American Journal of Political Science 32(4): 1151–1174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Frances E. 2009. Beyond Ideology: Politics, Principles, and Partisanship in the U.S. Senate. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Frances E. 2013. “Presidents and Party Teams: The Politics of Debt Limits and Executive Oversight.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 43 (December): 775.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lesniewski, Niels. 2013. “Reid Dismisses Baucus' Tax Overhaul Efforts.” CQ/Roll Call, July 25. Retrieved July 31, 2013, from http://blogs.rollcall.com/wgdb/reid-dismisses-baucus-tax-reform-efforts/.
Malecha, Gary Lee, and Reagan, Daniel J.. 2012. The Public Congress: Congressional Deliberation in a New Media Age. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Martin, Cathie Jo. 2013. “Conditions for Successful Negotiation: Lessons from Europe.” In Negotiating Agreements in Politics, eds. Martin, Cathie Jo and Mansbridge, Jane. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association: 121–143.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David. 2005. Divided We Govern: Party Control, Lawmaking, and Investigations, 1946–2002. 2nd edition. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
O'Keefe, Ed, and Johnson, Jenna. 2013. “No Filibuster Deal, but Senators Agree They Should Meet More Often.” Washington Post, July 15. Retrieved July 31, 2013, from http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/post-politics/wp/2013/07/15/no-filibuster-deal-but-senators-agree-they-should-meet-more-often/.
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1997. Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 2013. “NOMINATE and Related Data.” Voteview.com, Department of Political Science, University of Georgia. Retrieved August 8, 2013, from http://voteview.com/downloads.asp.
Riker, William. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Cindy Simon. 1998. When Women Lead: Integrative Leadership in State Legislatures. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sellers, Patrick. 2010. Cycles of Spin: Strategic Communication in the U.S. Congress. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sinclair, Barbara. 2006. Party Wars: Polarization and the Politics of National Policy Making.Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.Google Scholar
Sinclair, Barbara. 2012. Unorthodox Lawmaking: New Legislative Processes in the U.S. Congress. 4th edition. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Steven S. 2007. Party Influence in Congress. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sorauf, Frank J. 1992. Inside Campaign Finance: Myths and Realities. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Volden, Craig, and Wiseman, Alan E.. 2009. “Legislative Effectiveness in Congress.” Typescript. Ohio State University.
Volden, Craig, Wiseman, Alan E., and Wittmer, Dana E.. 2013. “When Are Women More Effective Lawmakers than Men?American Journal of Political Science 57(2): 326–341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wawro, Gregory. 2000. Legislative Entrepreneurship in the House. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Waxman, Henry, with Green, Joshua. 2009. The Waxman Report: How Congress Really Works. New York: Twelve.Google Scholar
Yglesias, Matthew. 2011. “Eric Cantor Takes Bargaining Positions out of Context, Poisoning the Atmosphere of Future Negotiations.” Think Progress. Retrieved July 31, 2013, from http://thinkprogress.org/yglesias/2011/07/12/267092/eric-cantor-takes-bargaining-positions-out-of-context-poisoning-the-atmosphere-of-future-negotiations/.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×