Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-68945f75b7-6sdl9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-09-02T11:23:27.179Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 October 2018

Douglas E. Stevens
Affiliation:
Georgia State University
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Social Norms and the Theory of the Firm
A Foundational Approach
, pp. 194 - 210
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abdel-Rahim, H., and Stevens, D.. 2018. The effect of information system precision on honesty in managerial reporting: A re-examination of information asymmetry effects. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 64(1): 3143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abdel-Rahim, H., Hales, J., and Stevens, D.. 2018. Financial Reporting Disaggregation and Discretion Effects on Manager Opportunism: An Experimental Examination of Trustworthiness and Honesty. Georgia State University Working Paper.Google Scholar
Abernathy, W., and Hayes, R.. 1980. Managing our way to economic decline. Harvard Business Review, (July–August): 6777.Google Scholar
Adams, D., and Maine, E.. 1998. Business Ethics for the 21st Century. Mountain View, CA: Mayfield Publishing.Google Scholar
Ahmed, A., Schneible, R., and Stevens, D.. 2003. An empirical analysis of the effects of online trading on stock price and trading volume reactions to earnings announcements. Contemporary Accounting Research, 20(3): 413439.Google Scholar
Alchian, A., and Demsetz, H.. 1972. Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62(5): 777795.Google Scholar
Allen, R. 2009. The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvey, J. 2007. The ‘new view’ of Adam Smith and the development of his views over time. In New Perspectives on Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Cockfield, Geoff, Firth, Ann, and Laurent, John (eds.). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 6683.Google Scholar
American Association of Collegiate Schools of Business. 1933. Proceedings of the Fifteenth Annual Meeting. Fifteenth Annual Meeting of the AACSB, Lexington, KY, Summer.Google Scholar
American Association of Collegiate Schools of Business. 1936. Proceedings of the Eighteenth Annual Meeting. Eighteenth Annual Meeting of the AACSB, Boston, MA, April 22, 23, 24, and 25.Google Scholar
Antle, R., and Eppen, G.. 1985. Capital rationing and organizational slack in capital budgeting. Management Science, 31(2): 163174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antle, R., and Fellingham, J.. 1995. Information rents and preferences among information systems in a model of resource allocation. Journal of Accounting Research, 33(Supplement): 4158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antle, R., and Fellingham, J.. 1997. Models of capital investments with private information and incentives: A selective review. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 24(7–8): 887908.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arce, D. 2006. Taking corporate culture seriously: Group effects in the trust game. Southern Economic Journal, 73(1): 2736.Google Scholar
Arce, D. 2007. Is agency theory self-activating? Economic Inquiry, 45(4): 708720.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. 1962. The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29(3): 155173.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. 1974. The Limits of Organization. New York, NY: Norton, York.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. 1985. The economics of agency. In Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, Pratt, J. W. and Zeckhauser, R. J. (eds.). Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 3751.Google Scholar
Atiase, R. 1985. Predisclosure information, firm capitalization, and security price behavior around earnings announcements. Journal of Accounting Research, 23(1): 2136.Google Scholar
Aumann, R. 1976. Agreeing to disagree. The Annals of Statistics, 4(6): 12361239.Google Scholar
Backhouse, R. 2009. Friedman’s 1953 essay and the marginalist controversy. In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy. Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 217240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baiman, S. 1990. Agency research in managerial accounting: A second look. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 15(4): 341371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, R. 2013. Accounting informs investors and earnings management is rife: Two questionable beliefs. Accounting Horizons, 27(4): 847853.Google Scholar
Ball, R., and Shivakumar, L.. 2008. How much new information is there in earnings? Journal of Accounting Research, 46(5): 9751016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, R., and Brown, P.. 1968. An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers. Journal of Accounting Research, 6(2): 159178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, R., and Brown, P.. 2014. Ball and Brown (1968): A retrospective. The Accounting Review, 89(1): 126.Google Scholar
Bamber, L. 1986. The information content of annual earnings releases: A trading volume approach. Journal of Accounting Research, 24(1): 4056.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bamber, L. 1987. Unexpected earnings, firm size, and trading volume around quarterly earnings announcements. The Accounting Review, 62(3): 510532.Google Scholar
Bamber, L., Barron, O., and Stevens, D.. 2011. Trading volume around earnings announcements and other financial reports: Theory, research design, empirical evidence, and directions for future research. Contemporary Accounting Research, 28(2): 431471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bamber, L., and Cheon, Y.. 1995. Differential price and volume reactions to accounting earnings announcements. The Accounting Review, 70(3): 417441.Google Scholar
Bamber, L., Jiang, J., and Wang, I.. 2010. What’s my style? The influence of top managers on voluntary corporate financial disclosure. The Accounting Review, 85(4): 11311162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barbalet, J. 2005. Smith’s sentiments (1759) and Wright’s passions (1601): The beginnings of sociology. British Journal of Sociology, 56(2): 171189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barbalet, J. 2007. The moon before the dawn: A seventeenth-century precursor of Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments. In New Perspectives on Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Cockfield, Geoff, Firth, Ann, and Laurent, John (eds.). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 84105.Google Scholar
Barron, O., Kim, O., Lim, S., and Stevens, D.. 1998. Using analysts’ forecasts to measure properties of analysts’ information environment. The Accounting Review, 73(4): 421433.Google Scholar
Barron, O., and Qu, H.. 2014. Information asymmetry and the ex ante impact of public disclosure quality on price efficiency and the cost of capital: Evidence from a laboratory market. The Accounting Review, 89(4): 12691297.Google Scholar
Barron, O., Schneible, R., and Stevens, D.. 2018. The changing behavior of trading volume reactions to earnings announcements: Evidence of the increasing use of accounting earnings news by investors. Contemporary Accounting Research, Forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, W. 1959. Business Behavior, Value and Growth. New York, NY: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Beauchamp, T., and Bowie, N.. 2004. Ethical theory and business practice. In Ethical Theory and Business, 7th edition. Beauchamp, T. and Bowie, N. (eds.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Beaver, W. 1968. The information content of annual earnings announcements. Journal of Accounting Research, 6(Supplement): 6792.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L., and Fried, J.. 2003. Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3): 7192.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L., and Fried, J.. 2004. Pay Without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L., and Fried, J.. 2005. Executive compensation at Fannie Mae: A case study of perverse incentives, nonperformance pay, and camouflage. Journal of Corporate Law, 30(4): 807822.Google Scholar
Bennis, W., and O’Toole, J.. 2005. How business schools lost their way. Harvard Business Review, (May): 96–104.Google Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., and McCabe, J.. 1995. Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1): 122142.Google Scholar
Bergstresser, D., and Philippon, T.. 2006. CEO incentives and earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics, 80(3): 511529.Google Scholar
Berle, A., and Means, G.. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York, NY: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bernard, V., and Thomas, J.. 1989. Post-earnings-announcement drift: Delayed price response or risk premium? Journal of Accounting Research, 27(Supplement): 136.Google Scholar
Bernard, V., and Thomas, J.. 1990. Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 13(4): 305340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, M. 2001. A Perilous Progress: Economists and Public Purpose in Twentieth-Century America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, W. 2004. The Birth of Plenty: How the Prosperity of the Modern World Was Created. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Berry, C. 2003. Sociality and socialization. In The Cambridge Companion to The Scottish Enlightenment. Broadie, Alexander (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 243257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, C. 2006. Smith and science. In The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith. Haakonssen, K. (ed.). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 112135.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C. 2006. The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C., Xiao, E., and Muldoon, R.. 2011. Trustworthiness is a social norm, but trusting is not. Politics, Philosophy and Economics, 10(2): 170187.Google Scholar
Blay, A., Gooden, E., Mellon, M., and Stevens, D.. 2017. The usefulness of social norm theory in empirical business ethics research: A review and suggestions for future research. Journal of Business Ethics, Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Blay, A., Gooden, E., Mellon, M., and Stevens, D.. 2018. Can social norm activation improve audit quality? Evidence from an experimental audit market. Journal of Business Ethics, Forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloomfield, R. 1996. The interdependence of reporting discretion and informational efficiency in laboratory markets. The Accounting Review, 71(4): 493511.Google Scholar
Bloomfield, R. 2010. Traditional vs. Behavioral Finance. Cornell University Johnson School Research Paper Series #22-2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloomfield, R., Libby, R., and Nelson, M.. 1999. Confidence and the welfare of less-informed investors. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 24(8): 623647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloomfield, R., and Wilks, T.. 2000. Disclosure effects in the laboratory: Liquidity, depth, and the cost of capital. The Accounting Review, 75(1): 1341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowie, N., and Duska, R.. 1990. Business Ethics, 2nd edition. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Bowie, N., and Freeman, R.. 1992. Ethics and agency theory: An introduction. In Ethics and Agency Theory: An Introduction, Bowie, N. E. and Freeman, R. E. (eds.). New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 322.Google Scholar
Brandt, R. 1979. A Theory of the Good and the Right. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Brennan, M. 1994. Incentives, rationality and society. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 7(2): 3139.Google Scholar
Brink, A., Hobson, J., and Stevens, D.. 2017. The effect of high power financial incentives on excessive risk-taking behavior: An experimental examination. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 29(1): 1329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadie, A. 2003. Introduction. In The Cambridge Companion to The Scottish Enlightenment. Broadie, Alexander (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, J., Evans, J., and Moser, D.. 2009. Agency theory and participative budgeting experiments. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 21(1): 317345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, L. 1993. Earnings forecasting research: Its implications for capital markets research. International Journal of Forecasting, 9(3): 295320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, L., Griffin, P., Hagerman, R., and Zmijewski, M.. 1987. An evaluation of alternative proxies for the assessment of unexpected earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 9(2): 159193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckle, H. 1864. History of Civilization in England. New York, NY: D. Appleton and Co.Google Scholar
Burgstahler, D. 1987. Inference from empirical research. The Accounting Review, 62(1): 203214.Google Scholar
Burk, K. 2007. Old World, New World: Great Britain and America from the Beginning. New York, NY: Atlantic Monthly Press.Google Scholar
Burns, J. 2009. Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bushman, R., and Smith, A.. 2001. Financial accounting information and corporate governance. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 32(1–3): 237333.Google Scholar
Caginalp, G., Porter, D., and Smith, V.. 2001. Financial bubbles: Excess cash, momentum, and incomplete information. Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets, 2(2): 8099.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. 2003. Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, J. 2007. Why would corporations behave in socially responsible ways? An institutional theory of corporate social responsibility. Academy of Management Review, 32(3): 946967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, R., and Skinner, A.. 1981. General Introduction. In An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, the Glasgow Edition, Campbell, R. H. and Skinner, A. S. (eds.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 160.Google Scholar
Campbell, T. 1971. Adam Smith’s Science of Morals. London, UK: Alan & Unwin Ltd.Google Scholar
Chamberlin, E. 1933. The Theory of Monopolistic Competition: A Re-orientation of the Theory of Value. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chambers, R. 1973. Observation as a method of inquiry—The background of securities and obscurities. Abacus, 9(2): 156175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, A. Jr. 1977. The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Chow, C., Cooper, J., and Waller, W.. 1988. Participative budgeting: Effects of a truth-inducing pay scheme and information asymmetry on slack and performance. The Accounting Review, 63(1): 111122.Google Scholar
Christensen, D. 2016. Corporate accountability reporting and high-profile misconduct. The Accounting Review, 91(2): 377399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, P. 2007. Adam Smith, religion and the Scottish Enlightenment. In New Perspectives on Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Cockfield, Geoff, Firth, Ann, and Laurent, John (eds.). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 4765.Google Scholar
Coase, R. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16): 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cockfield, G., Firth, A., and Laurent, J.. 2007. Introduction. In New Perspectives on Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Cockfield, Geoff, Firth, Ann, and Laurent, John (eds.). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 110.Google Scholar
Coleman, J. 1990. Foundations of Social Choice Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Collins, D., and Hribar, P.. 2000. Earnings-based and accrual-based market anomalies: One effect or two? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 29(1): 101123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, J. 1932. The problem of correlating law, economics, and ethics. Wisconsin Law Review, 3: 326.Google Scholar
Cournot, A. 1838. Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth, N. T. Bacon (Trans.). New York, NY: A. M. Kelley, 1960.Google Scholar
Cox, J. 2004. How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46(2): 260281.Google Scholar
Cox, J., and Deck, C.. 2005. On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3): 623635.Google Scholar
Cox, J., Kerschbamer, R., and Neururer, D.. 2016. What is trustworthiness and what drives it? Games and Economic Behavior, 98: 197218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cready, W., and Hurtt, D.. 2002. Assessing investor response to information events using return and volume metrics. The Accounting Review, 77(4): 891909.Google Scholar
Crowther, D., and Carter, C.. 2002. Legitimating irrelevance: Management education in higher education institutions. The International Journal of Educational Management, 16: 268278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cyert, R., and March, J.. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Davidson, B., and Stevens, D.. 2013. Can a code of ethics improve manager behavior and investor confidence? An experimental study. The Accounting Review, 88(1): 5174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, A., Guenther, D., Krull, L., and Williams, B.. 2016. Do socially responsible firms pay more taxes? The Accounting Review, 91(1): 4768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, J., Hecht, G., and Perkins, J.. 2003. Social behaviors, enforcement, and tax compliance dynamics. The Accounting Review, 78(1): 3969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demmert, H., and Klein, D.. 2003. Experiment on entrepreneurial discovery: An attempt to demonstrate the conjecture of Hayek and Kirzner. Journal of Economics and Behavioral Organization, 50(3): 295310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demski, J. 2003. Corporate conflicts of interest. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(2): 5172.Google Scholar
Demski, J., and Feltham, G.. 1978. Economic incentives in budgetary control systems. The Accounting Review, 53(2): 336359.Google Scholar
Dhaliwal, D., Li, O., Tsang, A., and Yang, Y.. 2011. Voluntary nonfinancial disclosure and the cost of equity capital: The initiation of corporate social responsibility reporting. The Accounting Review, 86(1): 59100.Google Scholar
Dobbin, R., and Zorn, D.. 2005. Corporate malfeasance and the myth of shareholder value. In Political Power and Social Theory, Volume 17, Davis, D. E. (ed.). Greenwich, NY: Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 179198.Google Scholar
Douthit, J., and Stevens, D.. 2015. The robustness of honesty concerns on budget proposals when the superior has rejection authority. The Accounting Review, 90(2): 467493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Douthit, J., and Majerczyk, M.. 2017. Subordinate perceptions of the superior and agency costs: Theory and evidence. Georgia State University Working Paper.Google Scholar
Douthit, J., Schwartz, S., Stevens, D., and Young, R.. 2017. The effect of endogenous contract selection on budgetary slack: An experimental examination of trust, distrust, and trustworthiness. Georgia State University Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyreng, S., Hanlon, M., and Maydew, E.. 2010. The effects of executives on corporate tax avoidance. The Accounting Review, 85(4): 11631189.Google Scholar
Dyreng, S., Mayew, W., and Williams, C.. 2012. Religious social norms and corporate financial reporting. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 39(7–8): 845875.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, R., and Hébert, R.. 2014. A History of Economic Theory & Method, Sixth Edition. Long Grove, IL: Waveland Press.Google Scholar
Elster, J. 1989. Social norms and economic theory. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(4): 99117.Google Scholar
Emmons, W., and Sierra, G.. 2004. Incentives askew? Regulation, 27(4): 2228.Google Scholar
Evans, J., Hannan, R., Krishnan, R., and Moser, D.. 2001. Honesty in managerial reporting. The Accounting Review, 76(4): 537559.Google Scholar
Falk, A., Fehr, E., and Fischbacher, U.. 2003. On the nature of fair behavior. Economic Inquiry, 41(1): 2026.Google Scholar
Fama, E. 1965. The behavior of stock-market prices. Journal of Business, 38(1): 34105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E. 1970. Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2): 383417.Google Scholar
Fama, E., Fisher, L., Jensen, M., and Roll, R.. 1969. The adjustment of stock prices to new information. International Economic Review, 10(1): 121.Google Scholar
Uncovered, Fannie. September 23, 2004. Wall Street Journal, Review and Outlook. Retrieved from: http://www.wsj.com.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Gӓchter, S., and Kirchsteiger, G.. 1997. Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device: Experimental evidence. Econometrica, 65(4): 833860.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Kirchler, E., Weichbold, A., and Gӓchter, S.. 1998. When social norms overpower competition: Gift exchange in experimental labor market. Journal of Labor Economics, 16(2): 324351.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., and Schmidt, K.. 1999. A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Review of Economics, 114(3): 817868.Google Scholar
Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission. 2011. The Financial Crisis Report: Final Report of the National Commission on the Causes of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the United States. New York, NY: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Firth, A. 2007. Adam Smith’s moral philosophy as ethical self-formation. In New Perspectives on Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Cockfield, Geoff, Firth, Ann, and Laurent, John (eds.). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 106123.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, U. 2007. z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2): 171178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, P., and Huddart, S.. 2008. Optimal contracting with endogenous social norms. American Economic Review, 98(4): 14591475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fligstein, N. 1990. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Flood, M. 1952. Some experimental games. Research Memorandum RM-789, RAND Corporation, June.Google Scholar
Flood, M. 1958. Some experimental games. Management Science, 5(1): 526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J., Savin, N., and Sefton, M.. 1994. Fairness in simple bargaining experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 6(3): 347369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, G, Olsen, C., and Shevlin, T.. 1984. Earnings releases, anomalies, and the behavior of security returns. The Accounting Review, 59(4): 574603.Google Scholar
Fourcade, M., and Khurana, R.. 2013. From social control to financial economics: The linked ecologies of economics and business in twentieth century America. Theory and Society, 42(2): 121159.Google Scholar
Frank, R., Gilovich, T., and Regan, D.. 1993. Does studying economics inhibit cooperation? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(2): 159171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. 1994. How intrinsic motivation is crowded out and in. Rationality and Society, 6(3): 334352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B., and Jegen, R.. 2001. Motivation crowding theory. Journal of Economic Surveys, 15(5): 589611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, D., and Sunder, S.. 1994. Experimental Methods: A Primer for Economists. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1953. The methodology of positive economics. In Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1970. The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. New York Times Magazine (September 13).Google Scholar
Friedman, M., and Friedman, R.. 1998. Two Lucky People: Memoirs. Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Gao, F., Lisic, L., and Zhang, I.. 2014. Commitment to social good and insider trading. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 57(2): 149175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geanakoplos, J. 1992. Common knowledge. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(1): 5382.Google Scholar
Ghoshal, S. 2005. Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning and Education, 4(1): 7591.Google Scholar
Gillette, A., Stevens, D., Watts, S., and Williams, A.. 1999. Price and volume reactions to public information releases: An experimental approach incorporating traders’ subjective beliefs. Contemporary Accounting Research, 16(3): 437479.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gode, D., and Sunder, S.. 1993. Allocative efficiency of markets with zero intelligence traders: Markets as a partial substitute for individual rationality. Journal of Political Economy, 101(1): 119137.Google Scholar
Gonedes, N., and Dopuch, N.. 1974. Capital market equilibrium, information production, and selecting accounting techniques: Theoretical framework and review of empirical work. Journal of Accounting Research, 12 (Supplemental): 48129.Google Scholar
Gordon, R. 1948. Short-period price determination in theory and practice. American Economic Review, 38 (June): 265288.Google Scholar
Gordon, R., and Howell, J.. 1959. Higher Education for Business. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griswold, C. 1999. Adam Smith and the Virtues of Enlightenment. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, S., and Stiglitz, J.. 1980. On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review, 70(3): 393408.Google Scholar
Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., and Schwarze, B.. 1982. An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(4): 367388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J., and Lawson, R.. 2003. The concept and measurement of economic freedom. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3): 405430.Google Scholar
Haakonssen, K. 2006. Introduction: The coherence of Smith’s thought. In The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith, Haakonssen, Knud (ed.). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 121.Google Scholar
Haakonssen, K., and Winch, D.. 2006. The legacy of Adam Smith. In The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith, Haakonssen, Knud (ed.). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 366394.Google Scholar
Hands, D. 2009. Did Milton Friedman’s positive methodology license the formalist revolution? In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy. Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 143164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannan, L. 2005. The combined effect of wages and firm profit on employee effort. The Accounting Review, 80(1): 167188.Google Scholar
Hannan, L., Kagel, J., and Moser, D.. 2002. Partial gift exchange in experimental labor market: Impact of subject population differences, productivity differences, and effort requests on behavior. Journal of Labor Economics, 20(4): 923951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haskell, T. 1977. The Emergency of Professional Social Science: The American Social Science Association and the Nineteenth-Century Crisis of Authority. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. 1967. Studies in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. 1988. The Fatal Conceit. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayes, R., and Wheelwright, S.. 1984. Restoring our Competitive Edge: Competing Through Manufacturing. New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Healy, P. 1985. The effect of bonus schemes on accounting decisions: Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(1–3): 85107.Google Scholar
Heilbroner, R. 1999. The Worldly Philosophers: The Lives, Times, and Ideas of the Great Economic Thinkers. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hilsenrath, J. 2009. Plan aims to curb dangerous risk. The Wall Street Journal, Friday, October 23.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. 2011. Do the benefits of reducing accounting complexity persist in markets prone to bubble? Contemporary Accounting Research, 28(3): 957989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobson, J., Mellon, M., and Stevens, D.. 2011. Determinants of moral judgments regarding budgetary slack: An experimental examination of pay scheme and personal values. Behavioral Research in Accounting, 23(1): 87107.Google Scholar
Hoi, C., Wu, Q., and Zhang, H.. 2013. Is corporate social responsibility (CSR) associated with tax avoidance? Evidence from irresponsible CSR activities. The Accounting Review, 88(6): 20252059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horngren, C., Datar, S., and Rajan, M.. 2018. Horngren’s Cost Accounting: A Managerial Emphasis, 16th edition. Hoboken, NJ: Pearson.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, L. 1945. Review (The Theory of Economic Behavior). American Economic Review, 35(5): 909925.Google Scholar
Isaacson, W. 2003. Benjamin Franklin: An American Life. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Jackson, D. 1994. Jackson Personality Inventory—Revised Manual. Port Huron, MI: Sigma Assessment Systems, Inc.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. 1983. Organization theory and methodology. The Accounting Review, 58(2): 319339.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. 2001. Corporate budgeting is broken—let’s fix it. Harvard Business Review, (November): 94101.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. 2002. Value maximization, stakeholder theory, and the corporate objective function. Business Ethics Quarterly, 12(2): 235256.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. 2008. Forward. In Moral Markets: The Critical Role of Values in the Economy. Zak, Paul J. (ed.). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, ixx.Google Scholar
Jensen, M., and Meckling, W.. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305360.Google Scholar
Jensen, M., and Murphy, K.. 1990. Performance pay and top management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98(2): 225263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jevons, W. 1871. The Theory of Political Economy. London, UK: Penguin, 1970.Google Scholar
Johnson, H. 1971. The Keynesian Revolution and the Monetarist Counter-Revolution. American Economic Review, 61(2): 91106.Google Scholar
Johnson, H., and Kaplan, R.. 1987. Relevance Lost: The Rise and Fall of Management Accounting. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Jones, T. 1991. Ethical decision making by individuals in organizations: An issue-contingent model. Academy of Management Review, 16(2): 366395.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., and Thaler, R.. 1986. Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. American Economic Review, 76(4): 728741.Google Scholar
Kaplan, R., and Norton, D.. 1996. The Balanced Scorecard: Translating Strategy into Action. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Khurana, R. 2007. From Higher Aims to Hired Hands: The Social Transformation of American Business Schools and the Unfulfilled Promise of Management as a Profession. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Khurana, R., and Spender, J.. 2012. Herbert A. Simon on what ails business schools: More than “A problem in organizational design.” Journal of Management Studies, 49(3): 619639.Google Scholar
Kim, O., and Verrecchia, R.. 1991. Trading volume and price reactions to public announcements. Journal of Accounting Research, 29(2): 302321.Google Scholar
Kim, O., and Verrecchia, R.. 1997. Pre-announcement and event-period private information. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24(3): 395419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Y., Park, M., and Wier, B.. 2012. Is earnings quality associated with corporate social responsibility? The Accounting Review, 87(3): 761796.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, R., Smith, V., Williams, A., and Van Boening, M.. 1992. The robustness of bubbles and crashes in experimental stock markets. In Nonlinear Dynamics and Evolutionary Economics. Prigogine, I., Day, R., and Chen, P. (eds.). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 183200.Google Scholar
Koford, K., and Penno, M.. 1992. Accounting, principal-agent theory, and self-interested behavior. In Ethics and Agency Theory: An Introduction. Bowie, Norman and Edward Freeman, R. (eds.). New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 127142.Google Scholar
Kohlberg, L. 1969. Stage and sequence: The cognitive-developmental approach to socialization. In Handbook of Socialization Theory and Research, Goslin, D., (ed.). Chicago, IL: Rand McNally, 347480Google Scholar
Kohlberg, L. 1976. Moral states and moralization: The cognitive developmental approach. In Moral development and behavior, Lickona, T. (ed.). New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston, 3153.Google Scholar
Kothari, S. 2001. Capital markets research in accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31(1–3): 105231.Google Scholar
Kuang, X., and Moser, D.. 2009. Reciprocity and the effectiveness of optimal agency contracts. The Accounting Review, 84(5): 16711694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, H. 2004. Introduction. In Theory of Games and Economic Behavior: Sixtieth-Anniversary Edition. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kuhn, T. 1962. The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Lakoff, G. 2009. The Political Mind: A Cognitive Scientist’s Guide to Your Brain and Its Politics. New York, NY: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Lambert, J. 1891. Two Thousand Years of Guild Life. Hull, England: A. Brown & Sons.Google Scholar
Lambert, R. 2001. Contracting theory and accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 32(1–3): 387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larcker, D., and Tayan, B.. 2013. A Real Look at Real World Corporate Governance. San Bernardino, CA: David Larcker and Brian Tayan.Google Scholar
Leeson, R. 2000. The Eclipse of Keynesianism: The Political Economy of the Chicago Counter Revolution. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitt, A. 1998. A question of integrity: Promoting investor confidence by fighting insider trading. Speech given at the SEC Speaks Conference, February 27.Google Scholar
Levitt, A. 1999. Quality information: The lifeblood of our markets. Speech given at The Economic Club of New York, October 18.Google Scholar
Libby, R., Bloomfield, R., and Nelson, M.. 2002. Experimental research in financial accounting. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 27(8): 775811.Google Scholar
Lowenstein, R. 2000. When Genius Failed: The Rise and Fall of Long-Term Capital Management. New York, NY: Random House.Google Scholar
Lucchetti, A., Enrich, D., and Lublin, J.. 2009. Fed hits banks with sweeping pay limits: Thousands of firms affected in plan meant to discourage risky bets; Small-town institutions “pay for the sins” of big players. The Wall Street Journal, Friday, October 23.Google Scholar
Luft, J. 1997. Fairness, ethics and the effect of management accounting on transaction costs. Journal of Management Accounting, 9: 199216.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. 2006. An Engine, Not a Camera. How Financial Models Shape Markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A. 1995. Explaining the Economic Performance of Nations. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. 2001. The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris, France: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mäki, U. 2009a. Reading the methodological essay in twentieth-century economics: Map of multiple perspectives. In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy. Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 4767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mäki, U. 2009b. Unrealistic assumptions and unnecessary confusions: rereading and rewriting F53 as a realist statement. In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy. Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 90116.Google Scholar
Marchand, R. 1998. Creating the Corporate Soul: The Rise of Public Relations and Corporate Imagery in American Big Business. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Marris, R. 1964. The Economic Theory of Managerial Capitalism. New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Marsden, G. 1994. The Soul of the American University: From Protestant Establishment to Established Nonbelief. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1890 (8th ed. 1920). Principles of Economics. London, UK: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1925. Memorials of Alfred Marshall, Pigou, A. C. (ed.). London, UK: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Mayer, T. 2009. The influence of Friedman’s methodological essay. In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy. Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 119142.Google Scholar
McGuire, S., Omer, T., and Sharp, N.. 2012. The impact of religion on financial reporting irregularities. The Accounting Review, 87(2): 645673.Google Scholar
Mehta, P. 2006. Self-interest and other interests. In The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith, Haakonssen, Knud (ed.). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 246269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miles, E. 2016. The Past, Present, and Future of the Business School. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P., and Stokey, N.. 1982. Information, trade and common knowledge. Journal of Economic Theory, 26(1): 1727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, J. 1836. On the definition of political economy. In Collected Works of John Stuart Mill: Essays on Economics and Society, Robson, J. M. (ed.). Toronto, ON: University of Toronto Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Mill, J. 1848. Principles of Political Economy, Ashley, W. J. (ed.). New York, NY: A. M. Kelly, 1965.Google Scholar
Mitnick, B. 1974. The theory of agency: The concept of fiduciary rationality and some consequences. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Pennsylvania. University Microfilms No. 74–22, 881.Google Scholar
Mitnick, B. 1992. The theory of agency and organizational analysis. In Ethics and Agency Theory: An Introduction, Bowie, Norman and Edward Freeman, R. (eds.). New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 7596.Google Scholar
Mittendorf, B. 2006. Capital budgeting when managers value both honesty and perquisites. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 18: 7795.Google Scholar
Moody, J. 1946. The Long Road Home: An Autobiography. New York, NY: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Morgan, M. 2006. Economic man as model man: Ideal types, idealization and caricatures. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28(1): 127.Google Scholar
Morse, J., and Bower, A.. December 30, 2002. Sherron Watkins: The party crasher. Time, 160 (27). Retrieved from: http://content.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,1003992,00.html.Google Scholar
Moser, D., and Martin, P.. 2012. A broader perspective on corporate social responsibility research in accounting. The Accounting Review, 87(3): 797806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neeman, Z. 1996. Common beliefs and the existence of speculative trade. Games and Economic Behavior, 16(1): 7796.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noe, T., and Rebello, M.. 1994. The dynamics of business ethics and economic activity. American Economic Review, 84(3): 531547.Google Scholar
Nohria, N. 2002. Changing Fortunes: Remaking the Industrial Corporation. New York, NY: Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Noreen, E. 1988. The economics of ethics: A new perspective on agency theory. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13(4): 359369.Google Scholar
North, D. 1991. Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1): 97112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D., and Weingast, B.. 1989. Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49(4): 803832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ouchi, W. 1981. Theory Z: How American Business Can Meet the Japanese Challenge. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Ӧzler, Ş. 2012. Adam Smith and dependency. Psychoanalytic Review, 99(3): 333358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parker, R. 1986. The development of the accountancy profession in Britain in the early twentieth century. Academy of Accounting Historians Monograph. Tuscaloosa, AL: University of Alabama.Google Scholar
Partnoy, F. 2003. Infectious Greed: How Deceit and Risk Corrupted the Financial Markets. London, UK: Profile Books.Google Scholar
Pedersen, O. 1997. The First Universities: Studium Generale and the Origins of University Education in Europe. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Penno, M. 2017. A theory of assurance: Balancing costly formal control with tone at the top. University of Iowa Working Paper.Google Scholar
Perelman, M. 1989. Adam Smith and dependent social relations. History of Political Economy, 21(3): 503520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pfeffer, J., and Fong, C.. 2002. The end of business schools? Less success than meets the eye. Academy of Management Learning and Education, 1(1): 7895.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillipson, N. 2010. Adam Smith: An Enlightened Life. New Haven & London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, F. 1959. The Education of American Businessmen: A Study of University-College Programs in Business Administration. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Pincus, S. 2009. 1688: The First Modern Revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Plott, C. 1982. Industrial organization theory and experimental economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 20(4): 14851527.Google Scholar
Podolny, J. 2009. The buck stops (and starts) at business school. Harvard Business Review (June): 6267.Google Scholar
Popper, K. 1934. The Logic of Scientific Discovery. New York, NY: Routledge Classics, 2002.Google Scholar
Porter, L., and McKibbin, L.. 1988. Management Education and Development: Drift or Thrust into the 21st Century? New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Posner, E. 2000. Law and Social Norms. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pratt, J., and Zeckhauser, R.. 1985. Principals and agents: An overview. In Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, Pratt, J. W. and Zeckhauser, R. J. (eds.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 135.Google Scholar
Prendergast, C. 1999. The provision of incentives in firms. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(1): 763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. 1993. Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. The American Economic Review, 83(5): 12811302.Google Scholar
Rajan, R., and Zingales, L.. 2004. Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists: Unleashing the Power of Financial Markets to Create Wealth and Spread Opportunity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rankin, F., Schwartz, S., and Young, R.. 2008. The effect of honesty and superior authority on budget proposals. The Accounting Review, 83(4): 10831099.Google Scholar
Raphael, D., and Macfie, A.. 1982. Introduction. In The Theory of Moral Sentiments, 6th edition, Raphael, D. D. and Macfie, A. L. (eds.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 152.Google Scholar
Rasmusen, E. 1990. Games and Information: An Introduction to Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, Inc.Google Scholar
Readings, B. 1996. The University in Ruins. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Reder, M. 2009. Appraisal of evidence in economic methodology. In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy, Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 165188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reeder, J. 1997. Introduction. In On Moral Sentiments: Contemporary Responses to Adam Smith. Reeder, J. (ed.). Bristol, UK: Thoemmes Press, vii–xxi.Google Scholar
Reuben, J. 1996. The Making of the Modern University: Intellectual Transformation and the Marginalization of Morality. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Revell, J. 2003. Mo’money, fewer problems; Is it a good idea to get rid of the $1 million CEO pay ceiling? Fortune, March 31: page 34.Google Scholar
Ripley, A. December 30, 2002. Cynthia Cooper: The night detective. Time, 160 (27). Retrieved from: http://content.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,1003990,00.html.Google Scholar
Romer, P. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5): 10021037.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, S. 1973. The economic theory of agency: The principal’s problem. American Economic Review, 63(2): 134139.Google Scholar
Ross, S. 1989. Discussion: Intertemporal asset pricing. In Theory of Valuation, Bhattacharya, S. and Constantinides, G. (eds.). Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Littlefield. 8596.Google Scholar
Roth, A. 1995. Introduction to experimental economics. In The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (eds.). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, L. 2005. Economic theory and experimental economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(1): 65107.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sass, S. 1982. The Pragmatic Imagination: A History of the Wharton School, 1881–1981. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scaff, L. 2011. Max Weber in America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1954. History of Economic Analysis, Schumpeter, E. B. (ed.). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Scott, R. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Scully, G. 1988. The institutional framework and economic development. Journal of Political Economy, 96(3): 652662.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1977. Rational fools: A critique of the behavioral foundations of economics theory. Philosophy and Public Affairs, 6(4): 317344.Google Scholar
Serrano, D., and Bonilla, J.. 2009. The politics of positivism: Disinterested predictions from interested agents. In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy. Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 189213.Google Scholar
Shils, E., and Altbach, P.. 1997. The Order of Learning: Essays on the Contemporary University. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R.. 1997. A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of Finance, 52(2): 737783.Google Scholar
Siegel, S. 1959. Theoretical models of choice and strategy behavior: Stable state behavior in the two-choice uncertain outcome situation. Psychometrika, 24(4): 303316.Google Scholar
Siegel, S., and Fouraker, L.. 1960. Bargaining and Group Decision Making-Experiments in Bilateral Monopoly. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Simon, H. 1945. Review. American Journal of Sociology, 50(6): 558560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. 1955. A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1): 99118.Google Scholar
Sinclair, T. 2005. The New Masters of Capital: American Bond Rating Agencies and the Politics of Creditworthiness. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Skapinker, M. 2008. Why business ignores the business schools. Financial Times, January 8.Google Scholar
Sliwka, D. 2007. Trust as a signal of a social norm and the hidden costs of incentive schemes. The American Economic Review, 97(3): 9991012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sloan, R. 1996. Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows about future earnings? The Accounting Review, 71(3): 289316.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1759 (6th ed., 1790). The Theory of Moral Sentiments, the Glasgow Edition, Raphael, D. D. and Macfie, A. L. (eds.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 1982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. 1762–1763. Lectures on Jurisprudence, the Glasgow Edition, Meek, R. L., Raphael, D. D., and Stein, P. G. (eds.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, 1982.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1776 (6th ed., 1791). An Inquiry Into The Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, the Glasgow Edition, Campbell, R. H. and Skinner, A. S. (eds.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 1981.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1795. The history of astronomy. In Essays on Philosophical Subjects, the Glasgow Edition, Wightman, W. P. D. (ed.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 1982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. 1962. An experimental study of competitive market behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 70(2): 111137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. 1976. Experimental economics: Induced value theory. American Economic Review, 66(2): 274279.Google Scholar
Smith, V. 1982. Microeconomic systems as an experimental science. American Economic Review, 72(5): 923955.Google Scholar
Smith, V. 2003. Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics. Les Prix Nobel, Stockholm, SE: Nobel Foundation. Reprinted in American Economic Review, 93(3): 465508.Google Scholar
Smith, V. 2008. Rationality in Economics: Constructivist and Ecological Forms. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V., Suchanek, G., and Williams, A.. 1988. Bubbles, crashes, and endogenous expectations in experimental spot asset markets. Econometrica, 56(5): 11191151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snowdon, B., and Vane, H.. 1999. Conversations with Leading Economists. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Soll, J. 2014. The Reckoning: Financial Accountability and the Rise and Fall of Nations. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Song, H. 1995. Adam Smith as an early pioneer of institutional individualism. History of Political Economy, 27(3): 425448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, M., and Zeckhauser, R.. 1971. Insurance, information and individual action. American Economic Review, 61(2): 380387.Google Scholar
Squires, S., Smith, C., McDougall, L., and Yeack, W.. 2003. Inside Arthur Andersen: Shifting Values, Unexpected Consequences. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Stevens, D. 2002. The effects of reputation and ethics on budgetary slack. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 14: 153171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stevens, D. 2011. Rediscovering Adam Smith: How The Theory of Moral Sentiments can explain emerging evidence in experimental economics. Adam Smith Working Papers Series 2011:04, University of Glasgow, UK.Google Scholar
Stevens, D., and Thevaranjan, A.. 2010. A moral solution to the moral hazard problem. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 35(1): 125139.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. 1961. The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, 69(3): 213225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. 1971a. Smith’s travels on the ship of the state. History of Political Economy, 3(2): 265277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. 1971b. The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1): 321.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. 1982. The Economist as Preacher and Other Essays. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sunder, S. 1997. Theory of Accounting and Control. Mason, OH: South-Western Cengage Learning.Google Scholar
Sunder, S. 2016. Rethinking financial reporting: Standards, norms and institutions. Foundations and Trends in Accounting, 11(1–2): 1118.Google Scholar
Tenbrunsel, A., and Messick, D.. 1999. Sanctioning systems, decision frames, and cooperation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(4): 684707.Google Scholar
Thomas, C. 2002. The rise and fall of Enron: When a company looks too good to be true, it usually is. Journal of Accountancy, 193(4): 4148.Google Scholar
Thorpe, D. 2007. Science and its applications in The Theory of Moral Sentiments. In New Perspectives on Adam Smith’s The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Cockfield, Geoff, Firth, Ann, and Laurent, John (eds.). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 124140.Google Scholar
Toffler, B. 2003. Final Accounting: Ambition, Greed, and the Fall of Arthur Andersen. New York, NY: Broadway Books.Google Scholar
Verrecchia, R. 2001. Essays on disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 32 (1–3): 97180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veysey, L. 1965. The Emergence of the American University. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Von Neumann, J., and Morgenstern, O.. 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Waller, W. 1988. Slack in participative budgeting: The joint effect of a truth-inducing pay scheme and risk preferences. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13(1): 8798.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walters, A. 1987. Friedman, Milton. In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Vol 2. London, UK: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Watts, R., and Zimmerman, J.. 1978. Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards. The Accounting Review, 53(1): 112134.Google Scholar
Watts, R., and Zimmerman, J.. 1986. Positive Accounting Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, Inc.Google Scholar
Wheeler, J. 1970. Accounting theory and research in perspective. The Accounting Review, 45(1): 110.Google Scholar
Wightman, W. 1982. Introduction. In Essays on Philosophical Subjects, the Glasgow Edition, Wightman, W. P. D. (ed.). Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund, Inc., 527.Google Scholar
Williams, A. 1980. Computerized double-auction markets: Some initial experimental results. Journal of Business, 53(3): 235258.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1964. The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in a Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization. New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1993. Opportunism and its critics. Managerial and Decision Economics, 14(2): 97107.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 2009. Friedman (1953) and the theory of the firm. In The Methodology of Positive Economics: Reflections on the Milton Friedman Legacy, Mäki, Uskali (ed.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 241256.Google Scholar
Wilson, E. 1998. Consilience. New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Wittrock, B. 1993. The modern university: The three transformations. In The European and American University since 1800, S. Rothblatt and B. Wittrock (eds.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Young, M. 1985. Participative budgeting: The effects of risk-aversion and asymmetric information on budgetary slack. Journal of Accounting Research, 23(2): 829842.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Douglas E. Stevens, Georgia State University
  • Book: Social Norms and the Theory of the Firm
  • Online publication: 11 October 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108525824.010
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Douglas E. Stevens, Georgia State University
  • Book: Social Norms and the Theory of the Firm
  • Online publication: 11 October 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108525824.010
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Douglas E. Stevens, Georgia State University
  • Book: Social Norms and the Theory of the Firm
  • Online publication: 11 October 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108525824.010
Available formats
×