Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Home
  • This chapter is unavailable for purchase
  • Print publication year: 2009
  • Online publication date: June 2012

6 - VOTING

Summary

In our normative analysis, we have until now considered personal decisions in markets (or, in the case of externalities, personal behavior in the absence of markets or in creating markets). The personal decisions were accompanied – and influenced – by public finance and public-policy decisions. Governments made the decisions about public finance and public policy, whereas people made the personal decisions that determined their own personal outcomes. In this chapter, we study collective decisions about public finance and public finance made by voting. People do not, therefore, determine their own personal outcomes by making personal decisions. Personal outcomes are determined through the collective outcome of decisions of voting.

Because the probability of one person's vote being decisive in large voting populations is effectively zero, the reason why people vote may not be that they expect to influence the outcome of voting. Voting may be expressive: voters may express themselves by identifying with a policy or with a candidate, as they might, for example, cheer for and identify with a sports team and be happy or sad according to whether “their” team wins; or, by expressing support for a candidate or political party, a voter may be communicating with and seeking approval from other people. People may also vote as an act of civic duty: they have been taught that taking the time to vote is correct pro-social behavior. Their utility from voting may be from democratic participation. We shall return to the question of why people vote.

Literature notes
The median voter and majority voting
Merrill, S., and Grofman, B., 1999. A Unified Theory of Voting: Directional and Proximity Spatial Models. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge U.K.
Condorcet, M., 1785. Essai sur l'Application de l'Analyse à la Probabilité des Decisions Rendues á la Pluraliste des Voix. Paris.
Nitzan, S., and Paroush, J., 1985. Collective Decision Making: An Economic Outlook. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge U.K.
Buchanan, J. M., and Tullock, G., 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor MI.
Guttman, J. L., 1998. Unanimity and majority rule: The calculus of consent reconsidered. European Journal of Political Economy 14:189–207.
May, K. O., 1952. A set of independent, necessary and sufficient conditions for simple majority decision. Econometrica 20:680–4.
Mueller, D. C., 2003. Public Choice III. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge U.K.
Wickström, B.-A., 1986. Optimal majorities for decision rules of varying importance. Public Choice 48:273–90.
Bergstrom, T. C., 1979. When does majority rule provide public goods efficiently?Scandinavian Journal of Economics 81:217–26.
Bowen, H. R., 1946. The interpretation of voting in the allocation of economic resources. Quarterly Journal of Economics 58:27–48. Reprinted in K. J. Arrow and T. Scitovsky (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Richard D. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 115–32.
Black, D., 1948. On the rationale of group decision making. Journal of Political Economy 56:23–36. Reprinted in K. J. Arrow and T. Scitovsky (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Richard D. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 133–46.
Congleton, R. D., and Tollison, R. D., 1999. The stability-inducing properties of very unstable coalitions: Avoiding the downward spiral of majoritarian rent seeking. European Journal of Political Economy 15:193–205.
Riker, W., 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. Yale University Press, New Haven CT.
Tullock, G., 1981. Why so much stability?Public Choice 37:189–202.
Buchanan, J. M., 1954. Social choice, democracy, and free markets. Journal of Political Economy 62:114–23.
Kochin, M. S., and Kochin, L. A., 1998. When is buying votes wrong?Public Choice 97:645–62.
Bernholz, P., 1977. Prisoners' dilemma, logrolling, and cyclical group preferences. Public Choice 29:73–86.
Stratmann, T., 1992. The effects of logrolling on Congressional voting. American Economic Review 82:1162–76.
Buchanan, J. M., and Faith, R. L., 1987. Secession and the limits of taxation: Towards a theory of internal exit. American Economic Review 77:1023–31.
Kollman, K., Miller, J. H., and Page, S. E., 1997. Political institutions and sorting in a Tiebout model. American Economic Review 87:977–92.
Persson, T., Roland, G., and Tabellini, G., 1997. Separation of powers and political accountability. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112:1163–202.
Davidson, S., Fry, T. R. L., and Jarvis, K., 2006. Direct democracy in Australia: Voter behavior in the choice between a constitutional monarchy and a republic. European Journal of Political Economy 22:86–73.
Karahan, G. R., and Shughart, W. F. II, 2004. Under two flags: Symbolic voting in the State of Mississippi. Public Choice 118:105–24.
Mayer, W., 1984. Endogenous tariff formation. American Economic Review 74:970–85.
Weck-Hannemann, H., 1990. Protectionism in direct democracy. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146:389–418.
Political competition
Feld, L. P., and Kirchgässner, G., 2000. Direct democracy, political culture, and the outcome of economic policy: A report on the Swiss experience. European Journal of Political Economy 16:287–306.
Nurmi, H., 1999. Voting Paradoxes and How to Deal with Them. Springer, Berlin.
Ostrogorski, M., 1903. La démocratie et l'organisation des partis politiques. Calmann-Levy, Paris (2 volumes).
Downs, A., 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. Harper and Row, New York.
Hotelling, H., 1929. Stability in competition. Economic Journal 39:41–57.
Roemer, J., 2001. Political Competition: Theory and Applications. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.
Selten, R., 1971. Anwendungen der Spieltheorie auf die Politische Wissenschaft. In Maier, H. (Ed.), Politik und Wissenschaft. C. H. Beck, München, pp. 287–320.
Ursprung, H. W., 1991. Economic policies and political competition. In Hillman, A. L. (Ed.), Markets and Politicians: Politicized Economic Choice. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston and Dordrecht, pp. 1–26.
Brennan, G., and Hamlin, A., 1998. Expressive voting and electoral equilibrium. Public Choice 95:149–75.
Bandyopadhyay, S., and Oak, M. P., 2008. Coalition governments in a model of parliamentary democracy. European Journal of Political Economy 24:554–61.
Baron, D., and Diermeier, D., 2001. Elections, governments and parliaments under proportional representation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116:933–67.
Brams, S., and Fishburn, P. C., 1986. Approval Voting. Birkhäuser, Boston.
Nurmi, H., 1987. Comparing Voting Systems. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht.
Voting on income redistribution
Tullock, G., 1959. Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy 67:571–9. Reprinted in Arrow, K. J. and Scitovsky, T. (Eds.), 1969. Readings in Welfare Economics. Richard D. Irwin, Homewood IL, pp. 169–78.
Rae, D. W., 1969. Decision rules and individual values in constitutional choice. American Political Science Review 63:40–56.
Taylor, M. J., 1969. Proof of a theorem on majority rule. Behavioral Science 14:228–31.
Bowles, R., and Jones, P., 1991. Political participation and the limits to redistribution. European Journal of Political Economy 7:127–39.
Meltzer, A. H., and Richard, S. F., 1981. A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy 89:914–27.
Harms, P., and Zink, S., 2003. Limits to redistribution: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy 19:651–68.
Benabou, R., and Ok, E. A., 2001. Social mobility and the demand for redistribution: The POUM (prospect of upward mobility) hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116:447–87.
Hirschman, A. O., 1973. The changing tolerance for income inequality in the course of economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 87:544–66.
Fuest, C., and Thum, M., 2001. Immigration and skill formation in unionized markets. European Journal of Political Economy 17:557–73.
Hansen, J. D., 2003. Immigration and income redistribution in welfare states. European Journal of Political Economy 19:735–46.
Roemer, J. E., 1998. Why the poor do not appropriate the rich: An old argument in new garb. Journal of Public Economics 70:399–426.
Owen, G., and Grofman, B., 1984. To vote or not to vote: The paradox of nonvoting. Public Choice 42:311–25.
Glazer, A., 1987. A new theory of voting: Why vote when millions of others do. Decision and Theory 22:257–70.
Guttman, J. L., Hilger, N., and Shachmurove, Y., 1994. Voting as investment vs. voting as consumption: New evidence. Kyklos 47:197–207.
Schuessler, A. A., 2000. A Logic of Expressive Choice. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ.
Heckelman, J. C., 1995. The effects of the secret ballot on voter turnout rates. Public Choice 82:107–24.
Matsusaka, J. G., and Palda, F., 1999. Voter turnout: How much can we explain?Public Choice 98:431–46.
Breyer, F., and Ursprung, H. W., 1998. Are the rich too rich to be appropriated? Economic power and the feasibility of constitutional limits to redistribution. Public Choice 94:135–56.
Abrams, B. A., and Settle, R. F., 1999. Women's suffrage and the growth of the welfare state. Public Choice 100:289–300.
Aidt, T. S., and Dallal, B., 2008. Female voting power: The contribution of women's suffrage to the growth of social spending in Western Europe (1869–1960). Public Choice 134:391–417.
Edlund, L., and Pande, R., 2002. Why have women become left-wing? The political gender gap and the decline in marriage. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117:917–61.
Husted, T. A., and Kenny, L. W., 1997. The effect of the expansion of the franchise on the size of government. Journal of Political Economy 105:54–82.
Lott, J. R., and Kenny, L. W., 1999. Did women's suffrage change the size and scope of government?Journal of Political Economy 107:1163–98.
Wilson, J. Q., 2002. The Marriage Problem: How Our Culture Has Weakened Families. Harper Collins, New York.
Mueller, D., 2003. Interest groups, redistribution and the size of government. In Winer, S. L. and Shibata, H. (Eds.), Political Economy and Public Finance. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham U.K., pp. 123–46.
Frey, B. S., and Pommerehne, W. W., 1982. How powerful are public bureaucrats as voters?Public Choice 38:253–62.
Frey, B. S., 1971. Why do high-income people participate more in politics?Public Choice 11:101–5.
Milanovic, B., 2000. The median-voter hypothesis, income inequality, and income distribution: An empirical test with the required data. European Journal of Political Economy 16:367–410.
Stigler, G., 1970. Director's law of public income distribution. Journal of Law and Economics 13:1–10.