Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-xm8r8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-26T04:05:56.653Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Chapter 8 - A World Full of Associations

Rules and Community Values in Early Roman Egypt*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 May 2023

Vincent Gabrielsen
Affiliation:
University of Copenhagen
Mario C. D. Paganini
Affiliation:
Österreichische Akademie der Wissenschaften, Wien

Summary

This chapter investigates the nature of the relations between the rules of professional associations and the shaping of community values in early Roman Egypt.

Type
Chapter
Information
Private Associations in the Ancient Greek World
Regulations and the Creation of Group Identity
, pp. 179 - 195
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Introduction

This chapter investigates the nature of the relations between the rules of professional associations and the shaping of community values in early Roman Egypt.

The ancient world was full of associations. From West to East, in urban as well as rural centres, individuals gathered in more or less formalised groups, each displaying specific purposes and connotations, and over time the associative model, or fenomeno associativo, was widespread across all of the Mediterranean countries – and beyond.Footnote 1 Being part of a group reflected a primary human desire, thus providing individuals with a sense of belonging and contributing to the shaping of one’s social identity. Multiple reasons, social and cultural as well as political and economic, lie behind the development of this phenomenon.Footnote 2 The religious element, in particular, was common to all types of ancient associations.Footnote 3 Some groups had a very distinctive religious character, as their main purpose revolved around the worship of a particular deity; in modern scholarship, these are generally referred to as ‘religious associations’.Footnote 4 Economy, broadly speaking, also played a role in the formation and evolution of associations; indeed, individuals sharing the same occupation are attested to have formed what today we usually call professional or trade associations.Footnote 5 The separation between religious and professional associations, however, was not definite and the boundaries between the two groups were rather blurred.Footnote 6 Religious elements were to be found in associations that had a prominent economic character and vice versa, as we shall see later in this chapter.

Associations with a more pronounced professional (or economic) focus grew in number during the early Roman period.Footnote 7 The evidence shows that such groups normally had a well-defined internal structure and sets of regulations, nomoi, which governed individual behaviour as well as communal activities. From Roman Egypt three sets of regulations have survived, all coming from the same village, Tebtynis, in the Fayum (ancient Arsinoite district), and dated to the mid-first century AD: of a non-identified association; of the apolysimoi of the imperial estate of Claudius, that is, imperial farmers who were exempt from certain liturgies; and of the salt merchants (halopolai).Footnote 8 The three nomoi were formally recorded at the local record office (grapheion), which reflected a common practice among associations; indeed, the contemporary register of contract titles attests the registration of several nomoi for the year AD 45/6 (see discussion below).Footnote 9

Thanks to the availability of a significant number of contemporary documents from the same site, we are also well informed about the social, economic and administrative environment in which these associations operated and their rules functioned.Footnote 10 This gives us a unique opportunity to explore the issues that are put forward in this volume: the place of association rules in the local community and their role in producing and shaping social values.

The aim of this chapter is twofold: first, to identify the values embedded in the regulations of the professional associations of early Roman Egypt and establish how far these values reflected those of the local community; second, to determine whether these rules aimed to create a well-ordered society (and whether they succeeded in doing so).

Regulations of Associations in Roman Egypt

In Egypt, associations had a long-standing tradition, which can be traced back to the Saite period.Footnote 11 As mentioned in the introduction, in the Roman period there was a proliferation of associations with a more professional characterisation, and it is remarkable to note that in Egypt many of these groups operated in rural communities. In the first century AD in the village of Tebtynis only there were at least eighteen associations that displayed a professional character; they exhibited a high level of specialisation and professionalism, mainly to do with textile production (weavers, dyers, fullers, cloak-makers, cloak-beaters and wool merchants) and metal work (coppersmiths and goldsmiths).Footnote 12 The role and importance of these groups have not gone unnoticed. Recent studies have focussed in particular on their economic dimension, suggesting that membership in a formalised group provided protection and clear financial advantages.Footnote 13 In this period, associations were private and voluntary enterprises, which means that there was no formal imposition on individuals to band together.Footnote 14 Nevertheless, a large proportion of the population participated in associations, and this was not a phenomenon limited to Egypt. Usually these groups were headed by a president, who was elected by the majority of the members and was in charge of enforcing the rules.Footnote 15 However, some particularly large associations, like the public farmers (demosioi georgoi) and the fishermen (halieis), had a board of officials called elders (presbyteroi), as the management of their activities would have been more demanding and in this way duties could be shared.Footnote 16 In the daily administration they were assisted by a secretary (grammateus).Footnote 17

In the Roman period Egyptian associations had sets of rules which were agreed upon by the majority of the members and formally registered at the record office, as confirmed by the case of mid-first-century Tebtynis.Footnote 18 As notarial agreements (demosioi chrematismoi), these documents were legally binding. This means that members of an association committed to the compliance of the rules from a private as well as legal perspective; in other words, violation of rules could result in formal legal action, should the association deem it necessary, even though internal resolution of disputes seems to have been the preferred method for members (see below).Footnote 19

Boak was the first to note that the procedure by which associations’ rules were validated voluntarily by their members was to be found in the Athenian private associations before Alexander the Great and suggested that their ‘contractual basis was introduced into Egypt under Greek influence’.Footnote 20 The traditional view holds that the nomoi had a one-year validity.Footnote 21 While this seems to have been the norm in the Ptolemaic period, this was definitely not the case under the Romans.Footnote 22 As I suggested elsewhere, the president was in charge for one year, whereas the rules had a variable validity, which could be longer than one year.Footnote 23 The role of the president, with his power to enforce the association rules and collect fees and fines, was not necessarily or exclusively one of social prestige, but could also be a burden. Normally, presidents had other occupations to keep them busy; an example is given by Petheus son of Petheus, president and secretary of the weavers of Kerkesoucha Orous.Footnote 24 His daily schedule must have been quite hectic: as a weaver, he was engaged in textile production; as a president and secretary of an association, he had to perform regular administrative and other social tasks. Although in the ancient world occupational patterns were normally rather fluid, the involvement in different roles and activities of varying degrees of responsibility must have been demanding; therefore, the temporary nature of an association president’s mandate would have made this role more attractive. It is likely that the annual turnover of presidents also contributed to ensuring that a certain level of fairness was kept in the internal set-up of the group and in the management of the various activities. In this way, no one would have been given the chance to establish and foster long-term power relations.

The rules, on the other hand, did not need to be modified every year; the president was in charge of their enforcement, and in the case of violation he had the authority to arrest the defaulter (enechyrazein) and ‛hand him over’ (paradidonai), most likely to the local authorities.Footnote 25 The main purpose of these regulations was to create a social and administrative order within whose boundaries individuals could operate and interact with each other; this also created what we might call a ‘sub-legal’ system within the established judicial system.Footnote 26 Although associations, in the role of their president, had the right to enforce their rules, there is no evidence suggesting that they had their own judicial system. Instead, it appears that members tended to favour, when possible, internal resolution of disputes, as recently noted by Cameron Hawkins and Philip Venticinque.Footnote 27 The fact that nomoi were registered at the record office means that the central government was informed of the associations’ affairs, but also, and most importantly, that the associations were making a conscious effort to align themselves and their rules with the state’s practice of registration.Footnote 28 In general, this attitude of conforming to the values of the central power was typical of associations in the Roman East.Footnote 29

For the Ptolemaic period, we have several rules of religious associations in Demotic from Tebtynis.Footnote 30 Using the network model theorised by Charles Tilly, Andrew Monson interpreted the ethical rules of these groups as a vehicle to create an institutionalised trust network that would facilitate cooperation between members.Footnote 31 In his view, economic reasons were secondary to social relations when joining an association. Was this still true in the Roman period? Did rules of associations and their underlying values change over time, adapting to new socio-economic and political circumstances? And finally, can the network model still be applied to the so-called professional associations of the Roman period? The following sections will attempt to answer these questions.

The Evidence

The village of Tebtynis provides us with particularly valuable evidence about rules of associations: three full sets of regulations and a notarial register dated to AD 45/6 in which at least six other associations recorded their rules. Of these, the title of only two is given: of the shepherds (poimenes) and of the builders (oikodomoi).Footnote 32 The surviving three sets of rules regulated three separate types of associations, each reflecting a specific dimension of the local community; some of the rules are in common, some others are unique to each group. All three ordinances include a provision regarding the election of an annual president who was given the power to enforce the laws of the association, a provision on the attendance of monthly banquets and a number of provisions on the prosecution of lawbreakers, which varied from one group to another (Table 8.1).Footnote 33 They also include a number of ethical rules, which regulated the social relations between the members and set the correct line of conduct. These constituted a well-ingrained tradition in Egyptian associations, and their presence in the ordinances of the Roman period attests to a line of continuity in the life of these groups.Footnote 34 The rules of an ethical nature are prominent in the ordinance of the non-identified association. The nomos of this group exhibits an essentially convivial character. Their explicit purpose was to hold monthly banquets to which all members had to contribute through the payment of dues. According to Boak, the reference to the purchase of a flock of sheep as an event to be celebrated might suggest the possibility that we are dealing here with the association of the cattle graziers (probatoktenotrophoi). However, this is not a convincing argument. In this document it is clear that the purchase of a flock has the same value as the purchase of a property (to eggaion), and in the same provision other events are envisaged as occasions for celebration. It is possible that members of this group engaged in some type of collective activity (economic or administrative) and that their rules, though not directly regulating this particular aspect of communal life, facilitated these non-convivial operations.

Table 8.1. Common features in the regulations of the first-century Tebtynis associations

ProvisionsNon-identified associationApolysimoi of the imperial estate of ClaudiusSalt merchants
Election of a presidentYesYesYes
Main payment of membersMonthly contribution (set at 12 dr.)Poll-tax and expensesTrade taxes
Main purpose of the associationMonthly banquetsPayment of poll-tax and expensesPayment of trade taxes and division of areas for sale of salt and gypsum
Monthly banquetsYes (12th)Yes (8th)Yes (25th)
Prosecution of misbehaving membersYesYesYes
Attendance of meetingsNon-attendance punished by finesNon-attendance punished by finesNon-attendance punished by fines
Arrangement of seating plan at banquetsYes (Fine: 3 ob.)NoNo
Prosecution or defamation of membersYes (Fine: 8 dr.)NoNo
Intrigue and corruption of a member’s homeYes (Fine: 60 dr.)NoNo
Payment for birth, marriage, purchase of property, of sheep and of cattleYesNoNo
Mutual supportFailure punished by fines (8 dr.)NoNo
Mutual assistance for debtYesYesNo
Attendance at a member’s funeralYes (Fines: 4 dr. for not shaving; 4 dr. for not attending)Yes (Fine: 4 dr. for not attending)No

That conviviality was the main feature of this association is also suggested by the number of provisions on social gatherings and ethical behaviour, mutual support and respect, which are not to be found in the other two extant nomoi. Members were required to follow a good conduct and to make a financial contribution when another member married, had a child and bought a property, cattle or a flock of sheep; members were also expected to help a fellow member in trouble and to be considerate when taking seats at a banquet, and were forbidden to prosecute and to corrupt a fellow member. Finally, a provision was included regulating behaviour in the event of a member’s death, whereby members had to shave, feast for one day and contribute with 1 drachma and two loaves of bread each. The importance of these ethical rules is reflected in their respective fines, which ranged from a minimum of 3 obols for shoving other members at the banquets, to 8 drachmas for denying help to a fellow member, for prosecuting him or slandering him, to a maximum of 60 drachmas for intriguing against a member or corrupting his home. It emerges clearly that fines were directly proportional to the seriousness of the violation, thus revealing the values that the group perceived as of the utmost importance and that therefore should not be infringed. For this association, it was the act of scheming against another member (hyponomeuein) or corrupting his home (oikophthoreuein) that was viewed as the most appalling offence of all, with a fine of 60 drachmas. By ensuring good conduct and mutual respect, ethical rules encouraged the creation and maintenance of strong relations of trust and solidarity. The inclusion in the nomos of such rules (and associated fines) combined with a monthly fee of 12 drachmas per member and occasional additional contributions made membership of this group rather costly. As Philip Venticinque has noted, an annual membership of 144 drachmas would have been sufficient to support a family of four for a year, thus suggesting that members were relatively well off.Footnote 35 The enforcement of fines that added to the members’ financial burden no doubt would have been a good way to ensure proper behaviour.

In the nomos of the apolysimoi and in that of the salt merchants, rules on social behaviour are limited to provisions on mutual support in case of debt and attendance of funerals for the former and to participation of meetings only for the latter. An early provision states the main purpose for the apolysimoi, that is, to pay their share of the poll-tax (laographia) and other expenses (dapanai) to their president.Footnote 36 This rule is of particular significance, for two reasons: first, because it highlights the administrative and practical aspect of their gathering into a formalised group; second, because it reveals that members of this group were not exempt from the main capitation tax, but from liturgies.Footnote 37 Paying taxes as a collective was not without advantages, mainly because it avoided that members must deal directly with tax collectors.Footnote 38 Another noteworthy aspect of their regulations is the formalised link with the emperor Claudius; a provision required that members hold a party on the eighth day of each month, in honour of the emperor’s birthday, with the president providing drinks for the celebrations and toasts. No provision is to be found that regulated other collective activities of the group, but some entries listed in the contemporary register of contract titles suggest that the apolysimoi occasionally made contracts as a collective. One contract, for example, mentions the ‛group of apolysimoi’ (plethos apolysimon).Footnote 39 A group of apolysimoi is also attested, jointly with the cattle graziers, in two affidavits (cheirographiai) registered at the record office in AD 45/6.Footnote 40 It is unclear whether these apolysimoi are to be identified with the apolysimoi of the estate of Claudius or with the farmers of another estate, but it is interesting to note that the two associations had shared interests (perhaps leasing of pasture land) and engaged in collective actions (one of the affidavits mentions the maintenance of some canals). The association of the apolysimoi with an imperial estate and their potential collaboration with groups of professional cattle breeders suggest that their activities included farming and livestock grazing. It is not surprising that these activities were not officially regulated by a nomos, as they were in fact ‘state’ activities, whose main terms were dictated by the Roman government and therefore there was no need, or freedom, for enforcing specific rules. However, the fact that the imperial farmers made contracts as a collective guaranteed some degree of flexibility in their economic enterprises. The rules of their associations did not give instructions as to how make bid applications or any other type of contracts, but facilitated these transactions by introducing a provision on debt, whereby members were given security for a set period of time (thirty or sixty days) in case they incurred in a private debt of up to 100 drachmas. Membership itself served as a protective measure in financial dealings.

A provision on debt is missing in the nomos of the salt merchants, but nine out of twelve regulations deal with the arrangement for the distribution of salt and gypsum among the members in the Fayum region. The reason behind the lack of a clause on debt probably lies in the fact that the salt merchants already enjoyed rights and privileges that other traders did not have, which was reflected in the careful subdivision of areas among the members. The sale of salt, at least in the Fayum, constituted a government concession, and salt merchants were required to submit bidding applications (anaphoria) to the state in order to acquire this right, as is attested by the local record office evidence dated to AD 45/6.Footnote 41 Membership in an association aimed at strengthening the position of the salt merchants in the various activities connected with their trade, from the application process to the sale of the finished product.Footnote 42 For the association to work efficiently, precise rules were needed as how to divide the market among the members.Footnote 43 This was all the more important due to the presence in the area of other groups of the same type, namely, the salt merchants of Talei and Theogonis and those of Ibion Eikosipentarouron.Footnote 44 The inclusion of legally binding rules on the subdivision of localities for the sale of salt must be seen as a way to regulate the competition and to set defined and clear parameters by which each member was required to abide. Needless to say, failure to do so resulted in the payment of fees, which was probably a good deterrent for misbehaving members.

While the expectation in all three sets of rules that members attended monthly meetings is a good indication of the strong social character of these groups, some associations felt the need to add rules that regulated more closely the ethical behaviour of their members. The exact nature of each of these associations is difficult to ascertain. If we go by the content of their nomoi and their titles, we may conclude that the non-identified association was a convivial club, while the apolysimoi and the salt merchants constituted more professional groups. This distinction, however, is not a fair reflection of the realities behind these groups. As Vincent Gabrielsen pointed out, associations that did not display in their title an occupational connotation did not necessarily lack an economic role in the community and, therefore, should not be excluded from our economic analysis.Footnote 45

The regulations of the exempt farmers of the imperial estate of Claudius and those of the salt merchants reveal two fundamental dimensions of communal life in the early Roman period: first, the desire to fit into the new Roman administrative system, which is clearly shown by the formalised commitment of the apolysimoi to pay taxes collectively; second, the social values of conviviality and sociability, which are the reflection of a society where personal relations were central, and trust among individuals was continuously fostered.

A significant aspect of communal life that emerges from the three sets of regulations is geographical mobility. Members of associations regularly travelled from their village of residence to other villages of the region and to the district capital, Ptolemais Euergetis, in order to attend monthly meetings in the context of which social networks were established and maintained. Reasons to travel outside Tebtynis were either business or participation in religious festivals and other social events; the salt merchants, for example, who held the concession for the sale of salt and gypsum in Tebtynis and nearby villages, were expected to travel around the district and have business relations with merchants and other buyers living outside Tebtynis. Provisions on meetings in the nomoi clearly attest this type of mobility. Members of the three associations were required to attend all the meetings called by the president, which could take place in the village, in a place outside the village or in the district capital. Although the nature of these meetings is not specified, variation in fines for failing to attend them suggests that their importance depended on their location, and those happening in the district capital were of particular significance: between 1 and 2 drachmas if the meeting was in the village, 4 drachmas if it was outside the village, 4 and 8 drachmas if it was in the district capital.Footnote 46 It appears that the non-identified association was less mobile; its members did not have meetings in other villages and the fine for missing a meeting in Ptolemais Euergetis was lower (4 instead of 8 drachmas). We do not know how far members of other associations established social or economic relations with individuals in other villages and in the district capital, but the very fact that some of their meetings took place outside Tebtynis, where the association was based, unveils the existence of a net of connections between Tebtynis, its neighbouring villages and Ptolemais Euergetis. It is most likely that one of the purposes of their meetings and banquets was that of providing the members with the possibility of networking, which would have facilitated potential economic dealings by creating trust networks.

An important fact to be noted is the inclusion of ethical rules in the ordinance of the non-identified association, which are missing in the other two ordinances (the exempt farmers of the imperial estate of Claudius do have provisions for mutual assistance and funerals, but none on ethical behaviour). Does this mean that these values were less important for the purpose of being a member of a professional association? Did the salt merchants not value the contribution of ethical rules? As membership in an association was not mutually exclusive, it is possible that those who were part of a more professional association also joined a social club, like that of the non-identified association, in order to enjoy the privileges of mutual support. Certain rules were agreed upon by the members on the basis of their particular needs, which clearly differed from one group to another. The relations between members of a professional association seem to have relied on rules that were dictated by conscious economic decisions more than on social rules, suggesting that the members were aware that this group was in fact an economic enterprise.

Table 8.1 includes a list of provisions to be found in the three surviving sets of regulations (of the non-identified association, of the apolysimoi and of the salt merchants), thus revealing which terms were common to all, which were common to two associations only and, finally, which terms were unique to one association only. It emerges clearly that, although associations were free to devise their personalised sets of rules according to their own needs, they all shared three core provisions – election of a president, obligation to attend monthly banquets and prosecution of lawbreakers – which can be regarded as the distinctive markers of an officially recognised association, at least in the Roman period.

The World of Professional Associations: A Well-Ordered Society?

The regulations of associations that survived from early Roman Egypt reveals the existence of a set of social values that underpinned the behaviour and activities of these groups and the relations between their members. These values were of two types: ethical (solidarity, trust and sociability) and practical (mobility and desire to integrate into the Roman administrative and economic framework). The fact that a large number of people joined one or more of these associations confirms that these values were not unique to specific groups but reflected those of the entire community. Although the percentage of individuals who were members of specific formalised groups cannot be calculated, the evidence from Tebtynis gives us a pretty good idea of the magnitude of this phenomenon. Assuming that each association had an average of twenty to thirty members, I calculated elsewhere that 10 to 15 per cent of the male population in the village might have belonged to an association.Footnote 47

Trust and solidarity were not simply theoretical notions, but core values at the base of the contractual economy of Roman Egypt. Mobility too was not a prerogative of members of associations, but a phenomenon widely attested among all strata of the population. Traders and craftsmen, for example, were not the only social groups who travelled around their own region and beyond. Shepherds too, who, incidentally, might have formed an association, occasionally had to relocate their flocks to different areas (sometimes outside their own district) to find pastures; state officials, slaves and freedmen who worked in administrative roles regularly travelled on business, and many individuals of Hellenic descent resided half-time in the district capital, half-time in the village, therefore making frequent journeys between their two residences.Footnote 48

The increase of professional associations under the Romans was not a product of chance, but a phenomenon strictly connected with the proliferation of state concessions, which in many cases replaced the old Ptolemaic monopolies.Footnote 49 This new situation led to the development of ad hoc rules that reflected the new needs of these groups’ members. The case of the salt merchants in this respect is illustrative, as it shows the necessity to regulate a specific economic activity – the distribution of salt and gypsum – within a wide region and was not a unique case. As the evidence from first-century Tebtynis shows, many economic enterprises were now organised as state concessions and revolved around a relevant association: the fishermen, the builders, the weavers, the dyers, the cattle graziers and so on.Footnote 50

The nomoi of these groups have not come down to us, but the example of the salt merchants suggests that some of their rules also covered their economic dimension. Such associations most likely had regulations that covered the financial aspects of their business; the weavers, for example, paid their trade tax (cheironaxion) collectively, a condition that was probably included in their nomos.

The values introduced by the new rules reflected primarily the need of the individuals to acquire enhanced support and protection in the bidding procedure.Footnote 51 The old social and ethical rules, conversely, were not abandoned, as they were strongly embedded in institutionalised social networks.

In this respect, the nomoi of the Roman period associations reflect a community that was different from the one in place in the Ptolemaic period. This society had new needs and concerns; the livelihood of families and individuals depended now on an economic set-up mainly based on an organised system of licence fees that required initiative and resourcefulness on the part of the bidders. State concessions enhanced competition and gave individuals the possibility to be involved actively and voluntarily in a number of activities. It was a chance for more profit, but it also meant financial risk. The associative model, based on those ethical values that had characterised the Egyptian society for a long time, proved to be a useful way to deal with this new scenario.

The economic situation in Egypt rapidly changed from the first to the second century AD.Footnote 52 Associations were put under stricter control and soon were required to perform administrative duties on behalf of the state.Footnote 53 The change in the administrative and economic set-up would have led inevitably to a change in community values – in many cases, fear was probably more prominent than desire for profit, and ethical and protectionist norms might have had a privileged place in associations’ nomoi. The character of associations and their rules adapted to the increasingly and ever-changing society, demonstrating not only that they were a fundamental social institution, but also that they were flexible and easily adjustable to different situations. Some rules, however, did not disappear, for example, the ones related to burial of members and members’ relatives.Footnote 54 While various political and economic contingencies gradually modified the ancient Egyptian society, community values that mirrored the new needs of the individuals (to conform to the Roman administration) emerged. This was an attempt on the part of associations to align their values (and those of their own community) with the values of the central authority. Things, of course, did not always run smoothly. Conflicts and disagreements can be seen in petitions in which members of associations filed complaints in matters of taxation, an inevitable result considering that by the second century AD associations became fully involved in the administrative state machinery.Footnote 55

The creation of ad hoc rules that would conform to new circumstances confirms the willingness of associations to survive and maintain a certain order in which they could exist. From this point of view, it could be argued that rules were established to create a well-ordered society; whether members of associations were influenced or inspired by the Greek idea of ‘good order’, is, however, difficult to prove. Though deeply ingrained in the native Egyptian strata of the population, associations had a long tradition that combined both Egyptian and Greek models; ‘good order’ might have been embedded in the Greek model, but there is no clear evidence. More likely, the reason why associations, with their rules, strove to achieve a social order lies in their need for preservation. The associative model provided a useful social (and, to an extent, economic) framework that their members did not want to give up. They created rules that allowed their associations to function the best way possible under different political, administrative and economic scenarios.

It is very tempting to suggest that the values that were at the core of professional associations in the early Roman period and beyond, that is, trust, solidarity and mutual support, had a universal character. These were to be found in Egypt well before Christianity and continued to be an integral part of the identity and rules of associations in later periods and in different regions outside Egypt.Footnote 56 In her analysis of medieval craft guilds and market order in the sixteenth century, Mougeot points out that ‘although they conveyed the values required to set up an economy of exchange, these craft guilds remained influenced by the values of mutual assistance which was a feature of primitive society’.Footnote 57 Their rules of conduct, which regulated ethical behaviour to ensure good business, were approved by the legal authorities. Admittedly, late antique and medieval associations were different from earlier institutionalised groups. However, members still found a way to preserve the ethical values that were at the core of their own establishment.Footnote 58

Footnotes

* I am grateful to the editors for the invitation to give a first version of this chapter at a stimulating conference in Athens in 2014 and for offering helpful feedback to the version submitted here. I also thank the anonymous readers for careful comments and criticisms and for pointing out to me new bibliography, which has helped clarify several issues. All remaining errors are my own.

1 On the associative model, see Cracco Ruggini Reference Cracco Ruggini1971: 59–64 and Reference Bowman1976. On the origins of associations there is a vast bibliography; see, for example, Poland Reference Poland1909 and Waltzing Reference Waltzing1895–1900. See also De Salvo Reference De Salvo1992: 373–4 for associations in Italy (collegia) and van Nijf Reference van Nijf1997 for a tradition of associations in the East. For Egypt, see Boak Reference Boak1937b, San Nicolò Reference San Nicolò1972 and Muhs Reference Muhs2001. For associations as global Eurasian phenomenon, see Evers in Chapter 10.

3 See also Carbon in Chapter 4.

4 On religious associations in Egypt, see in general de Cenival Reference de Cenival1972.

5 For a definition of professional associations, see Cracco Ruggini Reference Cracco Ruggini1971: 64–5: ‘Collectivity of men who gather together with a common and permanent objective (or at least felt as such in the conscience of the members), which represents the ideological link at the base of the continuity of this system. This objective establishes another characteristic feature (of the associations), that is, their stable organisation, independent from any change which members might experience’ (the translation is mine). See also Cracco Ruggini Reference Cracco Ruggini1973: 272–3. Some scholars use the definition of ‘trade associations’; see, for example, Gibbs Reference Gibbs2008, Reference Gibbs2011 and Reference Arnaoutoglou, Gabrielsen and Thomsen2015.

6 For a discussion of terminology, see Gabrielsen Reference Gabrielsen and Tiersch2016a: 131–2.

7 The general consensus holds that the Romans did not create professional associations, but took advantage of the associative model for their own administrative purposes. See, for example, van Minnen Reference van Minnen1987: 53. Van Nijf Reference van Nijf1997: 8 also notes that ‘the associations of the Greek East did not spring into existence ex nihilo, although Waltzing suggests that professional associations were a conscious innovation, imported by the Romans together with their own political institutions’.

8 P.Mich. V 243 (AD 14–37), 244 (AD 43) and 245 (AD 47).

9 P.Mich. II 123 recto.

10 A large number of documents of various types and several archival groups survive from Tebtynis in the first two centuries AD, including the archive of the record office (grapheion), the archive of Kronion son of Cheos (see Foraboschi Reference Foraboschi1971) and the archive of the descendants of Patron (see Bagnall Reference Bagnall1973 and Kehoe Reference Kehoe1992: 74–92). It is the first-century record office archive that provides the best evidence regarding the community in which the rules of associations were established. See Husselman Reference Husselman and Samuel1970 and Langellotti Reference Langellotti, Derda, Łajtar and Urbanik2016a.

11 See Gibbs Reference Gibbs, Gabrielsen and Thomsen2015: 242, with previous bibliography in n. 2. The most common Greek term for association is synodos, but koinon and plethos are also well attested. For an analysis of the terminology employed by associations in the Ptolemaic period, see now Paganini Reference Paganini, Di Natale and Basile2018.

12 For a list of associations in early Roman Tebtynis, see Langellotti Reference Langellotti2016b: 113–15. For a list of professional associations in the Roman East, see Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2002: 29–30; also Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2005: 213–16, who collects the evidence related to associations in the late first century BC and first century AD. For a general overview and discussion of different types of associations in Roman Egypt, with a focus on the first two centuries AD, see now Paganini Reference Paganini, Langellotti and Rathbone2020c. On professions and craft specialisation in the Eastern Mediterranean under the Romans, see Ruffing Reference Ruffing2008.

13 See, for example, Gibbs Reference Gibbs2011 and Verboven Reference Verboven2011.

14 Wilson Reference Cotter1996: 9–10.

15 In the papyri, the president is usually referred to as hegoumenos. Other terms, such as epimeletes, kephalaiotes and prostates, are also used.

16 See, for example, P.Mich. V 313 and PSI VIII 901. Kruse Reference Kruse, Langellotti and Rathbone2020 suggests that under special circumstances the elders and the president could have co-existed.

17 The same structure is to be found in associations of royal farmers of the Ptolemaic period. See also Gibbs Reference Gibbs, Gabrielsen and Thomsen2015: 251, who also notes the existence of an overlapping terminology between state officials and officials of trade associations.

18 P.Mich. V 243, ll. 13–14; V 244, ll. 45–6; V 247, ll. 17–18; V 248, ll. 8–9. See Boak Reference Boak1937b, Gibbs Reference Gibbs2011 and Venticinque Reference Venticinque2016: 77–85.

19 See, for example, Venticinque Reference Venticinque2016: 58–60.

20 Boak Reference Boak1937b: 220.

21 Boak Reference Boak1937b: 213.

22 Monson Reference Monson, Frosen, Prola and Salmenkivi2007: 770–1. For the Ptolemaic period, there is, however, at least one exception – the association of the weavers of Coptos who engraved their regulations in Demotic to be valid ‛forever and eternally’: Short Texts I 158 (22 Tybi = 19 January 30 BC).

24 P. Mich. II 121 verso, III l. 13 = recto IV vi. See also Langellotti Reference Langellotti, Derda, Łajtar and Urbanik2016a: 1731–2.

25 Right to arrest: P.Mich. V 244, ll. 19–20 and 245, ll. 37–42; right to exact pledges: P.Mich. V 243, l. 3. Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2002: 43 notes that these provisions regarding the president’s power were also to be found in Greece in the second century, concluding that they might have been a Roman introduction. However, a similar role (i.e. chasing of defaulters and collection of fees and fines) is attested for the ‛representatives of the house’ as outlined in the Ptolemaic Demotic regulations, which may speak against the idea of a Roman introduction (at least for Egypt).

26 Gibbs Reference Gibbs, Gabrielsen and Thomsen2015: 258–60 examined the relationship between state laws and regulations of trade associations in the Ptolemaic period. He points out that ‘the notion of internal jurisdiction was very important. Disputing members would presumably seek redress through the nomoi that all members had agreed upon, before going to the state to resolve the issues.’

27 Hawkins Reference Hawkins2016: 118–19; Venticinque Reference Venticinque2016: 58–60. For Roman Egypt, see in particular the clause included in the unnamed association, P.Mich. V 243, ll. 6–7: ‛If anyone prosecutes another or defames him, let him be fined eight drachmas’ (transl. Boak).

28 Recent scholarship has argued that the Roman legislation which issued bans and restrictions on associations was not implemented in Egypt. For an overview of state restrictions on associations, see Cotter Reference Cotter1996 and Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2002: 30–6; for a discussion of the application of Roman legislation in Egypt in the first century AD, see Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2005, who argues that in this province the government, in the person of the prefect Flaccus, took temporary measures only towards the Alexandrian associations. See also Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2002.

29 Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2002: 29. The inclusion in the Gnomon of the Idios Logos of a regulation mentioning a fine of 500 drachmas for members of associations has been used to argue in favour of a hostile attitude of the state towards such groups. However, given the existence of a large number of associations in the Roman world, recent scholarship has proposed that fines against associations were limited to specific contingencies and are not to be regarded as a means to discourage the formation of new formalised groups; see now Venticinque Reference Venticinque2016: 176–8. The Gnomon was a collection of rules concerning legal status, inheritance, marriage etc. compiled first under Augustus; see BGU V 1210 and P.Oxy. XLII 3014.

30 For a list of Demotic rules of associations in the Ptolemaic period, see Arlt and Monson 2011: 211. Cf. Table 1.1 in Chapter 1. See also Monson Reference Monson2006, Reference Monson, Frosen, Prola and Salmenkivi2007 and Muhs Reference Muhs2001. For a study of trade associations in the Ptolemaic period see now Gibbs Reference Gibbs, Gabrielsen and Thomsen2015.

31 Monson Reference Monson2006. See also Venticinque Reference Venticinque2010, esp. 277, for the use of the network model to suggest that ethical rules aimed at reinforcing familial bonds between members.

32 Shepherds: P.Mich. II 123 recto, XVI l. 12 (23 May 46); builders: P.Mich. II 123 recto, XVII l. 39 (17 June 46). One set of regulations is submitted by a certain Psosneus who is said to be an oil-producer, which suggests that he was a member of the relevant association and acting on its behalf (P.Mich. II 123 recto, VI l. 18, 28 October 45). For the other regulations, see P.Mich. II 123 recto, IX l. 45 (2 January 46), X l. 6 (4 January 46) and XI l. 36 (30 January 46).

33 Boak Reference Boak1937b provided a clear analysis of the three Greek nomoi from Tebtynis and compared the rules of Greek and Demotic texts. For a critique of the dichotomy Greek–Egyptian in Ptolemaic associations, see Paganini Reference Paganini, Chrubasik and King2017. See also Muhs Reference Muhs2001, esp. 4–5, who supports the generally accepted view that there was an independent Egyptian tradition of religious associations, which can be seen in the very early evidence for associations in Egypt. This tradition would have been later adopted by Greek-speakers in the formation of the so-called professional associations. Rules about social behaviour are to be found also in associations outside Egypt; see, for example, the case of the Iobacchoi of Athens (e.g. Moretti Reference Moretti1986). Gibbs Reference Gibbs, Gabrielsen and Thomsen2015: 248–9 points out that the early professional associations in the Hellenistic Mediterranean had a distinctive organisational structure ‘that was preferred among all others’, and that this structure is partly reflected in the nomoi. He suggests that there might have been a common institution that was derived from Greek precedents, and this Greek model ‘could be grafted onto existing traditional indigenous institutions’.

34 Venticinque Reference Venticinque2010: 286 suggests that behind these regulations there is the association’s concern to protect ‘the reputation for reliability and trustworthiness of the guild’. See also Arnaoutoglou Reference Arnaoutoglou2002: 43, who thinks that the purpose of rules on ethical behaviour was to keep social turmoil under control ‘without any immediate cost to the Roman administration’.

35 Venticinque Reference Venticinque2016: 14–15.

36 P.Mich. V 244, ll. 2–7: ‛Having met together, the undersigned men of Tebtynis, apolysimoi of an estate of Tiberius Claudius Caesar Augustus Germanicus Imperator, voted unanimously to elect one of their number, an excellent man, Kronion, son of Herodes, to be superintendent for one year from the month Sebastos of the coming fourth year of Tiberius Claudius Caesar Augustus Germanicus Imperator, the same Kronion to collect the public revenues of the poll-tax of the same apolysimoi and all the expenses of the said association’ (transl. Boak). It is worth noting that paying taxes collectively was a novelty in Egypt and seems to have been connected with formalised associations; see van Minnen Reference van Minnen1987: 48–56. It was not, however, a Roman introduction; see, for example, the payment of the eisphora, a direct tax paid in periods of particular needs, like war, in Classical Athens: Christ Reference Christ2007b.

37 Boak, Introduction to P.Mich. V 244. See also P.Gen. II 91.

39 P.Mich. II 123 recto, XX l. 44.

40 P.Mich. II 123 recto, III l. 40 and VIII l. 26. See Parassoglou Reference Parassoglou1978: 61 and n. 67; also Langellotti Reference Langellotti2016b: 122–4.

41 Written bids by salt merchants are attested in P.Mich. II 123 recto, VII l. 27 (15 November 45), P.Mich. II 123 recto, XXI l. 40 (14 August 46) and P.Mich. II 123 recto, XXII l. 27 (23 August 46). For an up-to-date discussion of anaphoria as written bids, see now Langellotti Reference Langellotti2016b: 129–34. On the sale of salt in the Greek world, see Carusi Reference Carusi2008, esp. 207–14 on Graeco-Roman Egypt. She notes that it is still unclear to what extent the production of salt was under state control during the Roman period and how its exploitation was managed. See also Wallace Reference Wallace1938: 183–4 and Adams Reference Adams2013: 273.

42 Gabrielsen Reference Gabrielsen, Droß-Krüpe, Föllinger and Ruffing2016b: 92–5 argues against the consensus that holds that the salt merchants were a professional association, suggesting instead that they formed a sort of partnership. Whether or not the salt merchants constituted what we call a regular association, it is impossible to ascertain; it is conceivable, however, that other associations also functioned like the salt merchants, meaning that this was not a unique case, but rather the manifestation of a wider phenomenon (i.e. formation of associations with a more economic character).

43 The list of current members appended to the nomos of salt merchants is damaged and shows only the ages and distinctive marks of five signatories, which might mean that the association had only five members, including the president. These regulations are stated in P.Mich. V 245, ll. 9–34: ‘And (they have decided) that all alike shall sell salt in the aforesaid village of Tebtynis, and that Orseus alone has obtained by lot the sole right to sell gypsum in the aforesaid village of Tebtynis and in the adjacent villages, for which he shall pay, apart from the share of the public taxes which falls to him, an additional sixty-six dr. in silver; and that the said Orseus has likewise obtained by lot Kerkesis, alone to sell salt therein, for which he shall likewise pay an additional eight dr. in silver. And that Harmiusis also called Belles, son of Harmiusis, has obtained by lot the sole right to sell salt and gypsum in the village of Tristomos also called Boukolos, for which he shall contribute, apart from the share of the public taxes which falls to him, five additional dr. in silver. Upon condition that they shall sell the good salt at the rate of two and one-half obols, the light salt at two obols, and the lighter salt at one and one-half obol, by our measure or that of the warehouse. And if anyone shall sell at a lower price than these, let him be fined eight dr. in silver for the common fund and the same for the public treasury. And if any of them shall be found to have sold more than a stater’s worth of salt to a merchant, let him be fined eight dr. in silver for the common fund and the same for the public treasury. But if the merchant shall intend to buy more than four drachmas’ worth, all must sell to him jointly. And if anyone shall bring in gypsum and shall intend to sell it outside, it must be left on the premises of Orseus, son of Harmiusis, until he takes it outside and sells it’ (transl. Boak).

44 Talei and Theogonis: P.Mich. II 123 recto, XXI l. 40; Ibion Eikosipentarouron: P.Mich. II 123 recto, XXII l. 27.

46 On regulation of compulsory participation in associations, see Eckhardt in Chapter 3.

47 Langellotti Reference Langellotti2016b: 119.

49 Wallace Reference Wallace1938: 181–3.

50 Gibbs Reference Gibbs, Gabrielsen and Thomsen2015: 261–2 suggests that the trade associations of the Ptolemaic period would have been involved in the system of state monopolies, whereby contractors, through an auction, would agree to produce a fixed amount of product at a fixed price. In the Roman period, state concessions replaced the Ptolemaic monopolies, allowing for more flexibility in an open market.

51 See Arnaoutoglou in Chapter 6 for the impact of the Romans on Athenian associations.

52 For Roman Asia, Harland Reference Harland2003: esp. 89–112 argues that associations participated fully in ‘civic vitality’ and were not to be seen as ‘compensatory phenomena in a period of civic decline’. Cf. Cracco Ruggini Reference Cracco Ruggini and Pippidi1976. See also Gillihan Reference Gillihan2012, whose analysis of the Dead Sea scrolls reaches similar conclusions.

53 See, for example, Stud.Pal. IV pp. 70–1 (Ptolemais Euergetis, AD 73) and P.Tebt. II 287 (Tebtynis, AD 161–9)

54 Craft guilds in late Medieval England, for example, provided their members with two types of religious activities: Sunday gatherings at church and postmortem services (funerals and burials). These were well-structured organisations with rules that regulated both ethical conduct and administrative and economic activities of their members. See also Richardson Reference Richardson2005: esp. 149 and 156–63.

56 See also Evers in Chapter 10. Carrié Reference Carrié, Carrié and Lizzi Testa2002: 311 pointed out that professional associations in late antiquity were characterised not only by the fiscal obligations to which they were subjected, but also by ‘sociability, conviviality, and cultural practice’. Hughes Reference Hughes1974: 61–2 suggested erroneously that medieval guilds, ‘many of which had as their most notable feature the sharing of a common meal’, were based on familial feelings, which found their roots in the Bible. In fact, feelings of familiarity are to be found in ancient associations well before the advent of Christianity.

57 Mougeot Reference Mougeot2003: 170; also Richardson Reference Richardson2005: 140 notes that ‘the rational-choice approach to the analysis of organization behavior suggests the performance of an organization (such as a guild) depends upon the rules by which it operates and how effectively those rules are enforced. Rules encourage individuals to contribute toward collective goals and discourage them from taking advantage of their colleagues.’ For a comparison between ancient associations and medieval guilds, see van Nijf Reference van Nijf1997: 11–18, in which the similarities between the two institutions are stressed. See also Carrié Reference Carrié, Carrié and Lizzi Testa2002: 328–31.

58 See Rosser Reference Rosser2015: 37–87.

Figure 0

Table 8.1. Common features in the regulations of the first-century Tebtynis associations

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×