Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-tj2md Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T23:59:32.338Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

EIGHT - Agricultural Distortions in the Transition Economies of Asia and Europe

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2011

Scott Rozelle
Affiliation:
Stanford University
Johan F.M. Swinnen
Affiliation:
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven in Belgium
Kym Anderson
Affiliation:
University of Adelaide
Get access

Summary

Until in the late 1970s, a large share of the globe – from the center of Europe to the southeast reaches of Asia – was under Communist rule. The lives of more than 1.5 billion people were directly controlled by Communist leaders. Under this rule, agricultural incentives were massively distorted. The leaders of the Soviet Bloc and China were committed to Socialist ideology and designed their economies to be insulated from the world and its markets.

Since then, there have been dramatic changes in these countries. Yet there are large differences between these transition countries in the extent and the nature of their remaining price distortions. In 1978, China embarked on its economic reform path by introducing the household responsibility system (HRS) in agriculture. A few years later, Vietnam followed. Both countries reduced price distortions and reallocated key land rights from collective farms to rural households. In the initial years, however, market forces played little role and only became important later on. Other communist regimes did not follow this path in the 1980s. Only a series of timid reforms were tried out in the former Soviet Union during the 1970s and 1980s. However, in the 1990s, many nations of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) and the former Soviet Union (FSU) implemented a series of bold policy reforms that often went far beyond the reforms that had been implemented in China and Vietnam.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anderson, K. (ed.) (2009), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, 1955–2007, London:Palgrave Macmillan and Washington DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Anderson, K., Hayami, Y. and Others (1986), The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: East Asia in International Perspective, Boston and London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Anderson, K. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (eds.) (2008), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies, Washington DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Anderson, K. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2009), “Eastern Europe and Central Asia,” Ch. 6 in Anderson, K. (ed.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, 1955–2007, London: Macmillan, Palgrave and Washington DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Athukorala, P., Huong, P.L. and Thanh, V.T. (2009), “Vietnam,” Ch. 8 in Anderson, K. and Martin, W. (eds.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Asia, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Bacchetta, M. and Drabek, Z. (2002), “Effects of WTO Accession on Policy-Making in Sovereign States: Preliminary Lessons from the Recent Experience of Transition Countries,” WTO Staff Working Paper DERD-2002–02, Geneva.
Baffes, J. (2009), “Benin, Bukina Faso, Chad, Mali and Togo,” Ch. 18 in Anderson, K. and Masters, W. (eds.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Africa, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Brada, J.C. and Wädekin, K. (eds.) (1988), Socialist Agriculture in Transition: Organizational Response to Failing Performance, Boulder: Westview Press.
Ciaian, P. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2008), “Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in New EU Member Countries,” pp 53–90 in Anderson, K. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (eds.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Gorter, H. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2002), “Political Economy of Agricultural Policies”, pp. 2073–2123 in Gardner, B.L. and Rausser, G.C. (eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 2B: Agricultural and Food Policy, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Ellman, M. (1988), “Contract Brigades and Normless Teams in Soviet Agriculture,” pp. 23–33 in Brada, J.C. and Wädekin, K (eds.), Socialist Agriculture in Transition: Organizational Response to Failing Performance, Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Gray, K.R. (ed.) (1990), Soviet Agriculture: Comparative Perspectives, Ames: Iowa State University Press.
Huang, J. and Chen, C. (1999), “Effect of Trade Liberalization on Agriculture in China: Institutional and Structural Aspects,” CGPRT Working Paper Series, Paper Number 42, United Nations, ESCAP Centre for Research and Development of Coarse Grains, Pulses, Roots and Tuber Crops, Bogor, Indonesia.
Huang, J., Liu, Y., Martin, W. and Rozelle, S. (2009), “Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in China”, Ch. 3 in Anderson, K. and Martin, W. (eds.) Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Asia, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Huang, J., Rozelle, S. and Chang, M. (2004), “The Nature of Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in China and Implications of WTO Accession,”World Bank Economic Review 18(1): 59–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, D.G. and Brooks, K.M. (eds.) (1983), Prospects for Soviet Agriculture in the 1980s, Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
Lardy, N. (1983), Agriculture in China's Modern Economic Development, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lin, J.Y. (1992), “Rural Reforms and Agricultural Growth in China,”American Economic Review 82(1): 34–51.Google Scholar
McMillan, J. and Naughton, B. (1992), “How to Reform a Planned Economy: Lessons from China,”Oxford Review of Economic Policy 8: 130–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macours, K. and Swinnen, J. (2002), “Patterns of Agrarian Transition,”Economic Development and Cultural Change 50(2): 365–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A. (2003), The World Economy: Historical Statistics, Paris: OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oi, J. (1989), “Market Reforms and Corruption in Rural China,”Studies in Comparative Communism 22(2/3): 221–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, A., Jin, H., Rozelle, S. and Huang, J. (2002), “Market Emergence and Transition: Transition Costs, Arbitrage, and Autarky in China's Grain Market,”American Journal of Agricultural Economics 84(1): 67–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pingali, P.L. and Xuan, V. (1992), “Vietnam: Decollectivization and Rice Productivity Growth,”Economic Development and Cultural Change 40(4): 697–718.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pomfret, R. (2008), “Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Kazakhstan,” pp. 219–64 in Anderson, K. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (eds.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Putterman, L. (1993), Continuity and Change in China's Rural Development, New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qian, Y. and Weingast, B.R. (1997), “Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives,”Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(4): 83–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roland, G. (2000), Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Rozelle, S. (1996), “Gradual Reform and Institutional Development: The Keys to Success of China's Rural Reforms,” pp. 197–220 in McMillan, J. and Naughton, B. (eds.), Reforming Asian Socialism: The Growth of Market Institutions, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Rozelle, S., Huang, J. and Otsuka, K. (2008), “Agriculture in China's Development,” pp. 467–505 in Brandt, L. and Rawski, T. (eds.), China's Great Economic Transformation, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Rozelle, S. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2004), “Success and Failure of Reform: Insights from the Transition of Agriculture,”Journal of Economic Literature 42(2): 404–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A. (1997), “Government in Transition,”European Economic Review 41(3–5): 385–410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sicular, T. (1988), “Plan and Market in China's Agricultural Commerce,”Journal of Political Economy 96 (2): 283–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sicular, T. (1995), “Redefining State, Plan, and Market: China's Reforms in Agricultural Commerce,”China Quarterly 144: 1020–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. (1994), “A Positive Theory of Agricultural Protection,”American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76(1): 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. (1996), “Endogenous Price and Trade Policy Developments in Central European Agriculture”, European Review of Agricultural Economics 23(2): 133–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. (ed.) (1997), The Political Economy of Agrarian Reform in Central and Eastern Europe, Ashgate: Aldershot.
Swinnen, J.F.M. (2002), “Transition and Integration in Europe: Implications for Agricultural and Food Markets, Policy and Trade Agreements,”The World Economy 25(4): 481–501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. and Heinegg, A. (2002), “On the Political Economy of Land Reform in the Former Soviet Union,”Journal of International Development 14(4): 1019–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. and Rozelle, S. (2006), From Marx and Mao to the Market, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cramon–Taubadel, S., Nivyevskiy, O., der Malsburg, E.E., and Movchan, V. (2008), “Ukraine,” pp. 175–217 in Anderson, K. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (eds.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Bank, World (1992), China: Strategies for Reducing Poverty in the 1990s, Washington DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Wurfel, D. (1993), “Doi Moi in Comparative Perspective,” pp. 165–207 in Turley, W. and Selden, M. (eds.), Reinventing Vietnamese Socialism: Doi Moi in Comparative Perspective, Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Yang, D. (1996), Calamity and Reform in China: State, Rural Society, and Institutional Change Since the Great Leap Famine, Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×