Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vvkck Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T22:58:44.183Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

10 - The Collective Responsibility of Military Officers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 September 2009

Mark Osiel
Affiliation:
University of Iowa
Get access

Summary

How, then, might the law help create and cultivate within modern armies the institutional characteristics enabling them to steer clear of mass atrocity? Much can be said in ready response to this question. First, militaries in many developed countries increasingly lure enlistees by promising instruction in technical skills marketable on departure. Those attracted on this basis are more susceptible to environmental clues about the changing costs and benefits of military membership than conscripts or those enlisting for patriotic motives.

Still, much of an officer's investment in years of demanding training becomes costs unrecoverable on leaving the corps. Most of the human capital acquired within combat positions in particular is firm-specific. It is unique to warfare; little demand exists for it in the peacetime economy. There also is no market among states for the services of a distinguished officer. It is axiomatic that he may sell these services only to his country of citizenship; few states need – or even insist on – covenants not to compete in employment contracts with their officers. Each state thus enjoys monopsony power over such laborers, whom it consequently binds with long-term contracts of adhesion. Private military contractors like Blackwater absorb only the smallest fraction of retired officers.

In short, alternative labor markets are few and mobility opportunities correspondingly limited. The high costs to an officer of exit from the corps enhance its collective capacity to sanction his deviance – hence also to deter it ex ante.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Levy, Yagil, “Soldiers as Laborers: a Theoretical Model,” 36 Theory & Society187 (2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalshoven, Frits, “Belligerent Reprisals,” 21 Neth. Y.B. Int'l L. 43 (1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Eric A., “A Theory of the Laws of War,” 70 U. Chi. L. Rev. 297, 301–6 (2003)Google Scholar
Garfinkel, Harold, “Conditions of Successful Degradation Ceremonies,” 61 Am. J. Soc. 420, 422–3 (1956)Google Scholar
Kahan, Dan, “Social Meaning and the Economic Analysis of Crime,” 27 J. Leg. Stud. 609 (1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pettit, Philip, “Virtus Normativa: Rational Choice Perspectives,” 100 Ethics 725, 745 (1990)Google Scholar
Kahan, Dan M., “Social Influence, Social Meaning, and Deterrence,” 83 Va. L. Rev. 349, 354 (1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Eric A., “The Regulation of Groups: The Influence of Legal and Non-Legal Sanctions on Collective Action,” 63 U. Chi. L. Rev. 133, 142 (1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinson, Daryl, “Collective Sanctions,” 56 Stan. L. Rev. 345, 419–22 (2003)Google Scholar
Gen, Brig. Charles, A.Dunlap, Jr, “The Role of the Lawyer in War,” 4 Chi. J. Int'l L. 479, 489 (2003)Google Scholar
Barry, John et al., “The Roots of Torture,” Newsweek, May 24, 2004, at 28, 32Google Scholar
Mendoza, Martha, “No Gun Ri: A Cover-Up Exposed,” 38 Stan. J. Int'l L. 153 (2002)Google Scholar
Kahl, Colin H., “How We Fight,” 85 Foreign Affairs, 83, 99, Nov./Dec. 2006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weinstein, Ian, “Regulating the Market for Snitches,” 47 Buff. L. Rev. 563, 583–4 (1999)Google Scholar
David, Roman, “Lustration Laws in Action: The Motives and Evaluation of Lustration Policy in the Czech Republic and Poland (1989–2001),” 28 Law & Soc. Inquiry 387, 405–7 (2003)Google Scholar
Carver, Charles S. et al., “Responsiveness to Threats and Incentives, Expectancy of Recurrence, and Distress and Disengagement: Moderator Effects in Women with Early Stage Breast Cancer,” 68 J. Consulting & Clinical Psychol. 965 (2000)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Milligan, Kevin, “Subsidizing the Stork: New Evidence on Tax Incentives and Fertility,” Nat'l Bureau of Econ. Res., Working Paper No. 8845 (2002)
Alchian, Armen A. & Demsetz, Harold, “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization,” 62 Am. Econ. Rev. 777, 779–80 (1972)Google Scholar
Shils, Edward A. & Janowitz, Morris, “Cohesion and Disintegration in the Wehrmacht in World War II,” 12 Pub. Opinion Q. 280 (1948)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Mark R., “Army Transformation and the Junior Officer Exodus,” 31 Armed Forces & Soc'y 63, 66 (2004)Google Scholar
Magnarella, Paul, “The Background and Causes of the Genocide in Rwanda,” 3 J. Int'l Crim. Justice 801, 821 (2005)Google Scholar
Cave, Damien, “Missing in Action: The War Heroes,” N.Y. Times, Aug. 7, 2005, § 4, at 1Google Scholar
Deci, Edward L., Ryan, Richard M., et al., “A Meta-Analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation,” 125 Psychol. Bulletin627 (1999)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frey, Bruno & Jegen, Reto, “Motivation Crowding Theory,” 15 J. Econ. Surveys589 (2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst & Falk, Armin, “Psychological Foundations of Incentives,” 46 Euro. Econ. Rev. 687 (2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahan, Dan, “The Logic of Reciprocity: Trust, Collective Action, and the Law,” 102 Mich. L. Rev. 71, 79 (2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst & Gachter, Simon, “Reciprocity and Economics: The Economic Implications of Homo Reciprocans,” 42 Eur. Econ. Rev. 845 (1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×