Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-tj2md Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T00:00:57.643Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Comment 2.2

from 2 - Innovation in the Informal Economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 October 2016

Erika Kraemer-Mbula
Affiliation:
Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa
Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
Affiliation:
World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), Switzerland and Sciences Po, Paris

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
Hidden Engine of Innovation?
, pp. 93 - 96
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Comment 2.2

  • Fred Gault

  • UNU-MERIT and TUT-IERI

This chapter introduces a new field of research, the study of innovation in the informal economy. It goes beyond the literature on the informal economy as an object of study and literature on entrepreneurship that does address the informal economy, but not so much the role of innovation. The literature on national systems of innovation has concentrated on developed and formal economies, although there are efforts to look at innovation systems in the context of development (Lundvall, Joseph, Chaminade and Wang Reference Lundvall, Joseph, Chaminade and Wang2009).

To fill this gap, the chapter looks at the characteristics of innovators, the types of innovations and the differences between innovation in the informal and the formal economies. Significantly, it does this in a way that supports measurement of the activities through surveys and case studies. This draws on experience of measuring the introduction of new or significantly improved goods or services onto the market (formal or informal) and the development of new or significantly improved processes that get goods or services to market in a better way (the transformation of inputs into outputs and their delivery, the organization of the business and the use of business practices, and the development of existing markets or the discovery of new ones).

While these four types of innovations – product (goods or services) and three types of processes – are found in the Oslo Manual, the Manual also observes that “informality is not a favorable context for innovation” (OECD/Eurostat 2005, p. 137). But the authors of this chapter show that innovation does happen in the informal sector and that its characteristics can be identified.

What is different in the informal sector is the emphasis on problem-solving and learning by doing, interacting and using rather than the formal generation of knowledge through R&D, leading to new products and processes and the protection of intellectual property through formal instruments. Skills, absorptive capacity for knowledge and technological capabilities are limited, and “firms” are small, yet there is innovation that goes beyond just innovation for survival.

This raises a number of issues that need to be understood in order to develop our understanding of innovation in the informal economy. How big are the entities that engage in innovation? What are they? What linkages exist between them and other groups and institutions, both formal and informal? What characteristics does the market have (if indeed there is a market)? And what are the implications of all this for policy?

The fieldwork reported in this book finds that the bulk of firms in the informal economy are micro-firms that may just be a means of surviving for the entrepreneurs; then come the “constrained gazelles” with limited resources; and then the few high-growth firms. Such a classification supports a differentiation of the analysis of the dynamics of firm activity in the informal sector. Of course, this distribution of firm size is also found in developed and formal economies, where 90 percent of firms will have fewer than twenty employees and the activity of innovation is size-dependent: generally large firms have a higher propensity to innovate.

However, there is a question about what is a firm in the informal sector. It could be a sole proprietorship, a family group, a faith group or some other group whose members have a reason for coming together to engage in an economic activity. As the group operates in the informal economy, it is unlikely to be registered and it is difficult to study using conventional survey methods. While formal firms sell to markets at economic prices, informal firms may be motivated by other things – providing employment to the community or serving some other element of the common good.

This brings the concept of “market” into question, and that is an issue in measuring innovation. For there to be innovation, the Oslo Manual requires that the new or significantly improved product be put on the market or that the new or significantly improved process (of any of the three types discussed) gets product to market in a better way (see Chapter 8 of this book). This question of the role of the market does not just arise in the informal economy, it is present when dealing with public sector activities; these may be identical to the innovation activities specified in the Oslo Manual, but, when it comes to the activity of innovation, the connection with the market is not there. The same problem arises when consumers modify goods or services to meet their own needs, as they do not bring their product to market and, in spite of an extensive literature on “user innovation” (von Hippel Reference von Hippel2005), the consumers are not innovators according to the Oslo Manual.

The discourse around public sector innovation (Bloch Reference Bloch and Gault2013) and consumer innovation (de Jong and von Hippel Reference de Jong, von Hippel and Gault2013) led me to suggest that the phrase “introduced on the market” in paragraph 150 of the Oslo Manual be replaced by “made available to potential users” (Gault Reference Gault2012). This would allow an institution in the public sector to be classified as an innovator, and the same would hold for consumers so long as they share the product or knowledge of the product with potential users. I raise the point again here as it also has applications in the study of the informal economy when the “innovation” is transferred through non-market transactions.

Firms or groups of like-minded people can innovate and can make their product available. As in the formal economy, they are actors in a system, where the firm interacts with other firms and consumers and is acted upon by framework conditions that may present barriers or opportunities for the firm to thrive. Understanding these linkages with other institutions and accounting for education and skills, culture, health and history is part of understanding an innovation system, and innovation systems are present in informal economies just as they are in the formal economy. The actors may be smaller, the human and financial resources more limited, and the barriers greater, but the actors engage in their activities and are influenced by their linkages, giving rise to short-term outcomes and longer-term social and economic impacts. Understanding this is part of the creation of a subject that addresses innovation in the informal economy, and which studies the science of innovation policy (Gault Reference Gault, Husbands Fealing, Lane, Marburger and Shipp2011).

At this point, one might ask why this subject is being created and what use the new knowledge created will serve. The response is the generation of better policies to promote innovation in the informal economy – or at least not get in its way. Such policy matters and grows in proportion to the amount of GDP generated by the informal economy. Without policy dealing with innovation in the informal economy, there is a risk of “misleading, asymmetrical or ineffective innovation strategies” (Kraemer-Mbula and Wamae Reference Kraemer-Mbula and Wamae2010). This provides substantial justification for the creation of a new subject dealing with innovation in the informal sector, and this chapter is a step in that direction.

References

Bloch, C. 2013. “Measuring innovation in the public sector,” in Gault, F. (ed.) Handbook of Innovation Indicators and Measurement. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA, Edward Elgar, pp. 403–19.Google Scholar
de Jong, J.P.E. and von Hippel, E. 2013. “User innovation: business and consumers,” in Gault, F. (ed.) Handbook of Innovation Indicators and Measurement. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA, Edward Elgar, pp. 109–32.Google Scholar
Gault, F. 2011. “Developing a science of innovation policy internationally,” in Husbands Fealing, K., Lane, J.I., Marburger, J.H. III and Shipp, S.S. (eds.) The Science of Science Policy: A Handbook. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press, pp. 156182.Google Scholar
Gault, F. 2012. “User innovation and the market,” Science and Public Policy 39: 118–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kraemer-Mbula, E. and Wamae, W. 2010. Innovation and the Development Agenda. Paris, OECD Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lundvall, B-A., Joseph, K.J., Chaminade, C. and Wang, J. (eds.) 2009. Handbook of Innovation Systems and Developing Countries: Building Domestic Capabilities in a Global Setting. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD/Eurostat 2005. Oslo Manual: Guidelines for Collecting and Interpreting Innovation Data, third edition (The Measurement of Scientific and Technological Activities). Paris, OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
von Hippel, E. 2005. Democratizing Innovation. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Comment 2.2
  • Edited by Erika Kraemer-Mbula, Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa, Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
  • Book: The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
  • Online publication: 20 October 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316662076.007
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Comment 2.2
  • Edited by Erika Kraemer-Mbula, Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa, Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
  • Book: The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
  • Online publication: 20 October 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316662076.007
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Comment 2.2
  • Edited by Erika Kraemer-Mbula, Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa, Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
  • Book: The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
  • Online publication: 20 October 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316662076.007
Available formats
×