Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-dfsvx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-29T04:49:56.099Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 January 2024

John B. Davis
Affiliation:
Marquette University, Wisconsin and Universiteit van Amsterdam
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Identity, Capabilities, and Changing Economics
Reflexive, Adaptive, Socially Embedded Individuals
, pp. 246 - 278
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2024

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adams, Ernest W. (1975) The Logic of Conditionals, Dordrecht and Boston: Reidel.Google Scholar
Addo, Fenaba R. and Darity, William A., Jr. (2021) “Disparate Recoveries: Wealth, Race, and the Working Class after the Great Recession,” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 695 (1): 173192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ainslie, George (1992) Picoeconomics: The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States within the Person, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George and Kranton, Rachel (2000) “Economics and Identity,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3): 715753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George and Kranton, Rachel (2002) “Identity and Schooling: Some Lessons for the Economics of Education,” Journal of Economic Literature 40 (4): 1167–201.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George and Kranton, Rachel (2005) “Identity and the Economics of Organizations,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19 (1): 932.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George and Kranton, Rachel (2010) Identity Economics: How Identity Shapes Our Work, Wages, and Well-Being, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Allais, Maurice (1953) “Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école Américaine,” Econometrica 21 (4): 503546.Google Scholar
Allen, Amy (2016) “Feminist Perspectives on Power,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Fall Edition), Edward N. Zalta, ed., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2016/entries/feminist-power/Google Scholar
Ali, Omer, Darity, William A., Jr., Janz, Avra and Sánchez, Marta (2021) “The Association between Wealthy Inequality and Socioeconomic Outcomes,” American Economic Review 111 (May): 211215.Google Scholar
Ambrosino, Angela, Cedrini, Mario and Davis, John B. (2021) “The Unity of Science and Disunity of Economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 45 (4): 631654.Google Scholar
Ambrosino, Angela, Fontana, Magda and Azzurra Gigante, Anna (2018) “Shifting Boundaries. In Economics: The Institutional Cognitive Strand and the Future of Institutional Economics,” Journal of Economic Surveys 32 (3): 761791.Google Scholar
Andersen, Hans Christian (1837) “Kejserens nye Klæder,” in Fairy Tales Told for Children, translated as “The Emperor’s New Clothes,” The Complete Andersen (1949), translated by Jean Hersholt, New York; 1949.Google Scholar
Andre, Peter and Falk, Armin (2021) “What’s Worth Knowing? Economists’ Opinions about Economics,” CRC TR 224 Discussion Paper Series crctr224_2021_308, University of Bonn and University of Mannheim, Germany.Google Scholar
Angner, Eric (2012) A Course in Behavioral Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Angner, Eric (2018) “What Are Preferences?Philosophy of Science 85: 660681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angner, Eric (2019) “We’re All Behavioral Economists Now,” Journal of Economic Methodology 26 (3): 195207.Google Scholar
Angrist, Joshua and Pischke, Jörn-Steffen (2010) “The Credibility Revolution in Economics: How Better Research Design Is Taking the Con out of Econometrics,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (2): 330.Google Scholar
Angrist, Joshua, Azoulay, Pierre, Ellison, Glenn, Hill, Ryan and Feng Lu, Susan (2017) “Economic Research Evolves: Fields and Styles,” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 107 (5): 293297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Annet, Anthony (2018) “Modern Economics Should Return to Its Roots,” Finance and Development 55/1, IMF; 5456. www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2018/03/pdf/point2.pdf; accessed 31 March 2021.Google Scholar
Archer, Margaret (1995) Realist Social Theory: A Morphogenetic Approach, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Arestis, Philip, Charles, Aurelie and Fontana, Giuseppe (2014) “Identity Economics Meets Financialisation: Gender, Race, and Occupational Stratification in the US Labour Market,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 38 (6): 14711491.Google Scholar
Aristotle, (1984) “De Interpretatione,” in The Complete Works of Aristotle, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, Chapter 9.Google Scholar
Arthur, Brian (2009) The Nature of Technology: What It Is and How It Evolves, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Arthur, Brian (2015) Complexity and the Economy, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Arthur, Brian (2021) “Foundations of Complexity Economics,” Nature Reviews Physics 3 (February): 136145.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bacharach, Michael (2006) Beyond Individual Choice: Teams and Frames in Game Theory, Gold, N. and Sugden, R., eds., Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger and Cherrier, Béatrice (2017) “The Age of the Applied Economist: The Transformation of Economics Since the 1970s,” History of Political Economy 49 (Supplement): 133.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger and Cherrier, Béatrice, eds. (2017) The Transformation of Economics Since the 1970s, Durham and London: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Badiei, Sina and Grivaux, Agnès, eds. (2022) The Positive and the Normative in Economic Thought, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ballet, Jérôme, Bazin, Damien, Dubois, Jean-Luc and Mahieu, François-Régis (2014) Freedom, Responsibility and Economics of the Person, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Banerjee, Abhijit V. (1992) “A Simple Model of Herd Behaviour,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (3): 797817.Google Scholar
Banerjee, Abhijit and Duflo, Esther (2012) Poor Economics, New York: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Barker, Drucilla and Feiner, Susan (2004). Liberating Economics: Feminist Perspectives on Families, Work, and Globalization, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Baujard, Antoinette and Gilardone, Muriel (2020) “Reconciling Agency and Impartiality: Positional Views as the Cornerstone of Sen’s Idea of Justice,” Economics Working Paper from Condorcet Center for Political Economy at CREM-CNRS, 2020–03-ccr, Condorcet Center for Political Economy.Google Scholar
Baumeister, Roy and Vohs, Kathleen (2007) “Realistic Group Conflict Theory,” Encyclopedia of Social Psychology 2: 725726.Google Scholar
Beck, Lukas (2022) “Why We Need to Talk About Preferences: Economic Experiments and the Where-Question,” Erkenntnis. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10670-022-00590-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary (1957) The Economics of Discrimination, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary (1981) A Treatise on the Family, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press; enlarged edition, 1991.Google Scholar
Bellamy, Edward (1889) Looking Backward: 2000–1887, Boston: Houghton Mifflin and Co.Google Scholar
Belluz, Julia (2015) “Nobel Winner Angus Deaton Talks about the Surprising Study on White Mortality He Just Co-Authored,” Vox 7 November.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland and Tirole, Jean (2002) “Self-Confidence and Personal Motivation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(3): 871915.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland and Tirole, Jean (2003) “Self-Knowledge and Self-Regulation: An Economic Approach,” in Brocas, I. and Carrillo, J., eds., The Psychology of Economic Decisions: Volume 1: Rationality and Well-Being, Oxford: Oxford University Press: 137167.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland and Tirole, Jean (2004) “Willpower and Personal Rules,” Journal of Political Economy 12 (4): 848–86.Google Scholar
Berg, Nathan and Gigerenzer, Gerd (2010) “As-If Behavioral Economics: Neoclassical Economics in Disguise?History of Economic Ideas 18 (1): 133166.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas (2008) “Behavioral Welfare Economics,” NBER Working Paper Series, no. 14622 (December).Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas (2016) “The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly: A Unified Approach to Behavioral Welfare Economics,” Benefit Cost Analysis 7: 1268.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Rangel, Antonio (2007) “Toward Choice-Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics,” American Economic Review 97 (2): 464470.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Rangel, Antonio (2008) “Choice-Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics,” in Caplin, A. & Schotter, A., eds., The Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 155192.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Rangel, Antonio (2009) “Beyond Revealed Preference: Choice-Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (1): 51104.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Taubinsky, Dmitry (2018) “Behavioral Public Economics,” in Bernheim, B. D., Douglas, B., DellaVigna, S. and Laibson, D., eds., Handbook of Behavioral Economics – Foundations and Applications 1, 1st edition, Amsterdam: North-Holland: 381516.Google Scholar
Bertalanffy, Ludwig von (1968) General Systems Theory: Foundations, Development, Applications, New York: George Braziller.Google Scholar
Bikhchandani, Sushil, Hirschleifer, David and Welch, Ivo (1998) “Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (3): 151–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken (2009) Rational Decisions, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Blumer, Herbert (1958) “Race Prejudice as a Sense of Group Position,” Pacific Sociological Review 1 (1): 37.Google Scholar
Bögenhold, Dieter (2021) “Economics in the Social Science Spectrum: Evolution and Overlap with Different Academic Areas,” Atlanta Economics Journal 49: 335347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boland, Lawrence (1981) “On the Futility of Criticizing the Neo-classical Maximization Hypothesis,” American Economic Review 71 (5): 1031–36.Google Scholar
Bolander, Thomas (2107) “Self-Reference,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, Fall edition, E. N. Zalta, ed., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2017/entries/self-reference//Google Scholar
Boldyrev, Ivan and Ushakov, Alexey (2016) “Adjusting the Model to Fit the World: Constructive Mechanisms in Postwar General Equilibrium Theory,” Journal of Economic Methodology 23(1): 3856.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. (1969) “Economics as a Moral Science,” American Economic Review 59 (1): 112.Google Scholar
Boumans, Marcel (1999) “Built-in Justification,” in Mary, M. and Morrison, M., eds., Models as Mediators, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 6696.Google Scholar
Boumans, Marcel (2001) “Measure for Measure: How Economists Model the World into Numbers,” Social Research 68 (2): 427453.Google Scholar
Boumans, Marcel and Herfeld, Catherine (2022) “Progress in Economics,” in Shan, Y., ed., New Philosophical Perspectives on Scientific Progress, London: Routledge: 224244.Google Scholar
Boumans, Marcel and Herfeld, Catherine (2023) “Progress in Economics,” in Shan, Yafeng, ed., New Philosophical Perspectives on Scientific Progress, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bratman, Michael (1993) “Shared Intention,” Ethics 104 (1): 97113.Google Scholar
Bréban, Laurie and Gilardone, Muriel (2020) “A Missing Touch of Adam Smith in Amartya Sen’s Account of Public Reasoning: The Man Within for the Man Without,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 44 (2): 257283.Google Scholar
Brewer, Marilyn (2001) “The Many Faces of Social Identity: Implications for Political Psychology,” Political Psychology 22: 115125.Google Scholar
Brewer, Marilyn and Gardner, Wendy (1996) “Who Is This ‘We’? Levels of Collective Identity and Self-Representations,” Journal of Personal and Social Psychology 71 (1): 8393.Google Scholar
Brisset, Nicolas (2016) “Economics Is Not Always Performative: Some Limits for Performativity,” Journal of Economics Methodology 23 (2): 160184.Google Scholar
Brocas, Isabelle and Carrillo, Juan (2014) “Dual-Process Theories of Decision-Making,” Journal of Economic Psychology 41: 4554.Google Scholar
Bromley, Daniel W. (2019) Possessive Individualism: A Crisis of Capitalism, New York: Oxford.Google Scholar
Brubaker, Rogers and Cooper, Frederick (2000) “Beyond ‘Identity’,” Theory and Society 29: 147.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James (1965) “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” Economica 32 (125): 114.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James and Tullock, Gordon (1965) The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Bureau of Labor Statistics (2016) “Women’s Earning 83 Percent of Men’s, But Vary by Occupation,” www.bls.gov/opub/ted/2016/womens-earnings-83-percent-of-mens-but-vary-by-occupation.htm, January 15 (accessed 19 May 2019).Google Scholar
Burnazoglu, Merve (2021) “An Identity-Based Matching Theory Approach to Integration,” Forum for Social Economics 50 (1): 108123.Google Scholar
Buss, Sarah and Westlund, Andrea (2008) “Personal Autonomy”, The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring Edition), E. N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2018/entries/personal-autonomy/Google Scholar
Byrne, Ruth (2016) “Counterfactual Thought,” Annual Review of Psychology 67 (1): 135157.Google Scholar
Byrne, Ruth (2005) The Rational Imagination: How People Create Alternatives to Reality, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Byrne, Ruth (2007) “Precis of The Rational Imagination: How People Create Alternatives to Reality,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 30: 439480.Google Scholar
Callon, Michel (1998) “The Embeddedness of Economic Markets in Economics,” in Callon, M., ed., The Laws of the Markets, Oxford: Blackwell: 157.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin, Issacharoff, Samuel, Loewenstein, George, O’Donoghue, Ted. and Rabin, Matthew (2003) “Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for ‘Asymmetric Paternalism’,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151 (3), 1211–45.Google Scholar
Candlish, Stewart. and Wrisley, George (2014) “Private Language,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, E. N. Zalta, ed., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2014/entries/private-language/Google Scholar
Caplin, Andrew and Schotte, Andrew, eds. (2008) The Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics: A Handbook, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Case, Anne and Deaton, Angus (2020) Deaths of Despair and the Future of American Capitalism, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cat, Jordi (2017) “The Unity of Science,” in Zalta, E. N., ed, The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Fall Edition), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2017/entries/scientific-unity/.Google Scholar
Chelwa, Grieve, Hamilton, Darrick and Stewart, James (2022) “Stratification Economics: Core Constructs and Policy Implications,” Journal of Economic Literature 60 (2): 377399.Google Scholar
Chen, Shu-Heng and Wang, Shu G. (2011) “Emergent Complexity in Agent-Based Computational Economics,” Journal of Economic Surveys 25 (3): 527546.Google Scholar
Cherrier, Beatrice (2017) “Classifying Economics: A History of the JEL Codes,” Journal of Economic Literature 55 (2): 545579.Google Scholar
Chetty, Raj, Grusky, David, Hell, Maximilian, Hendren, Nathaniel, Manduca, Robert and Narang, Jimmy (2017) “The Fading American Dream: Trends in Absolute Income Mobility Since 1940,” Science 356 (6336): 398406.Google Scholar
Chetty, Raj, Hendren, Nathaniel, Jones, Maggie and Porter, Sonya (2018) “Race and Economic Opportunity in the United States: An Intergenerational Perspective,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 24441 (March).Google Scholar
Chen, Shu-Heng (2012) “Varieties of Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Historical and an Interdisciplinary Perspective,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Chen, Shu-Heng (2016) Agent-Based Computational Economics: How the Idea Originated and Where It Is Going, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Chester, Lynne and McMaster, Robert (2023) “Understanding Social Stratification: The Case of Energy Injustice,” Forum for Social Economics, DOI: 10.1080/07360932.2023.2191294Google Scholar
Chick, Victoria and Dow, Sheila (2005) “The Meaning of Open Systems,” Journal of Economic Methodology 12 (3): 363381.Google Scholar
Christakis, Nicholas (2019) Blueprint: The Evolutionary Origins of A Good Society, New York: Little Brown Spark.Google Scholar
Clancey, William (1997) Situated Cognition: On Human Knowledge and Computer Representations, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, Andy (1997) Being There: Putting Brain, Body, and World Together Again, Cambridge: MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Clark, Andy (2018) Supersizing the Mind: Embodiment, Action, and Cognitive Extension, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, Andy and Chalmers, David (1998) “The Extended Mind,” Analysis 58 (1): 719.Google Scholar
Clifford, James and Marcus, George E., eds. (1986) Writing Culture: The Poetics and Politics of Ethnography, School of American Research Advanced Seminar, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald (1937) “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica 4 (16): 386405.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald (1988) The Firm, the Market, and the Law, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Colander, David, Holt, Richard, and Rosser, Barkley (2004) “The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics,” Review of Political Economy 16 (4): 485499.Google Scholar
Colander, David, Holt, Richard and Rosser, Barkley, Jr. (2006) “The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics,” Review of Political Economy 16 (4): 485499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David and Kupers, Roland (2014) Complexity and the Art of Public Policy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Colander, David and Su, Huei-Chun (2015) “Making Sense of Economists’ Positive-Normative Distinction,” Journal of Economic Methodology 22 (2): 157170.Google Scholar
Colander, David and Su, Huei-Chun (2018) How Economics Should be Done. Essays on the Art and Craft of Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Collins, Randall (1994) Four Sociological Traditions, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Coyle, Diane (2014) GDP: A Brief but Affectionate History. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Crenshaw, Kimberle (1991) “Demarginalizing the Intersection of Race and Sex: A Black Feminist Critique of Antidiscrimination Doctrine, Feminist Theory, and Antiracist Politics,” in Barlett, K. T. and Kennedy, R., eds., Feminist Legal Theory: Readings in Law and Gender, Boulder, CO: Westview Press: 139–168.Google Scholar
Crespo, Ricardo (2020a) “Identity: Individual and Social, and a Theory of a ‘Polymorphic’ but Unique Identity,” in Dolfsma, W., Hands, D. W. and McMaster, R., eds., History, Methodology and Identity for the 21st Century, London: Routledge: 5166.Google Scholar
Crespo, Ricardo (2020b) The Nature and Method of Economic Sciences: Evidence, Causality, and Ends, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Crespo, Ricardo and José Llach, Juan (2006) “Conceptions of Human Beings Implicit in Economics and in The Practice of Economic Policy,” in Malinvaud, E. and Glendon, M., eds., Conceptualization of the Person in Social Sciences, Vatican City: The Pontifical Academy of Sciences, Acta 11, Vatican City: 447–97.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., (2005) “Stratification Economics: The Role of Intergroup Inequality,” Journal of Economics and Finance 29 (2): 144153.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., (2009) “Stratification Economics: Context Versus Culture and the Reparations Controversy,” Kansas Law Review 57: 795811.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., (2022) “Position and Possessions: SE and Intergroup Inequality,” Journal of Economic Literature 60 (2): 127.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., Hamilton, Darrick and Stewart, James B. (2015) “A Tour de Force in Understanding Intergroup Inequality: An Introduction to Stratification Economics,” The Review of Black Political Economy, 42 (1–2): 16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., Hamilton, Darrick, Mason, Patrick, Price, Gregory, Davila, Alberto, Mora, Marie and Stockley, Sue (2017) “Stratification economics: A General Theory of Intergroup In-equality,” in Flynn, A., Homberg, S., Warren, D. and Wong, F., eds., The Hidden Rules of Race, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: pp. 3551.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., Hamilton, Darrick, Paul, Mark, Aja, Alan, Price, Anne, Moore, Antonio and Chiopris, Caterina (2018) “What We Get Wrong About Closing the Racial Wealth Gap,” Durham, NC: Samuel DuBois Cook Center on Social Equity and Oakland, CA: Insight Center for Community Economic Development (April).Google Scholar
Darity, William A. and Mullen, A. Kirsten (2020) From Here to Equality: Reparations for Black Americans in the Twenty-First Century, Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., Mullen, A. Kirsten and Slaughter, Marvin (2022) “The Cumulative Costs of Racism and the Bill for Black Reparations,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 36 (2): 99122.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., Mason, Patrick L. and Stewart, James B. (2006) “The Economics of Identity: The Origin and Persistence of Racial Identity Norms,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 60 (3): 283305.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha (2009) “Facts and Values in Modern Economics,” in Kincaid, H. and Ross, D., eds., The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy of Economics, Oxford: Oxford University Press: 580640Google Scholar
Davis, John B. (1988) “Looking Backward: Looking Forward,” Forum for Social Economics 17 (2): 1322.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. (2003a) “Collective intentionality, complex economic behavior, and valuation,” Protosociology 18–19:163183.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2003b) The Theory of the Individual in Economics: Identity and Value, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2006) “The Turn in Economics: Neoclassical Dominance to Mainstream Pluralism?Journal of Institutional Economics 2 (1): pp. 120.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2007a) “Akerlof and Kranton on Identity in Economics: Inverting the Analysis,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 31 (3): 349362.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2007b) “Identity and Commitment: Sen’s Fourth Aspect of the Self,” in Peter, F. and Schmid, B., eds., Rationality and Commitment, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007: 313335.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2008) “The Turn in Recent Economics and Return of Orthodoxy,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 32 (3): 349366.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2009a) “The Capabilities Conception of the Individual,” Review of Social Economy 67 (December 2009): 413429.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2009b) The Theory of the Individual in Economics: Identity and Value, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2011) Individuals and Identity in Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2012a) “Rawlsian individuals: Justice, experiments, and complexity,” Journal of Economic Issues 46 (3): 729743.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2012b) “The Change in Sraffa’s Philosophical Thinking,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 36 (6): 13421356.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2012c) “The Idea of Public Reasoning,” Journal of Economic Methodology 19 (2): 169172.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2013a) “Economics Imperialism under the Impact of Psychology: The Case of Behavioral Development Economics,” Economia 3 (1): 119138, https://doi.org/10.4000/oeconomia.638Google Scholar
Davis, John (2013b) “Soros’s Reflexivity Concept in a Complex World: Cauchy Distributions, Rational Expectations, and Rational Addiction,” Journal of Economic Methodology 20 (4): 368376.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2014) “Social Capital and Social Identity: Trust and Conflict,” in Christoforou, A. and Davis, J. B., eds., Social Capital: Social Values, Power, and Social Identity, London: Routledge, 2014: 98112.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2015a) “Agency and the Process Aspect of Capability Development: Individual Capabilities, Collective Capabilities, and Collective Intentions,” Filosofía de la Economía 4: 524.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2015b) “Economists’ Odd Stand on the Positive-Normative Distinction: A Behavioral Economics View,” in DeMartino, G. and McCloskey, D., eds., Oxford University Press Handbook on Professional Economic Ethics: Views from the Economics Profession and Beyond, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2015c) “Stratification Economics and Identity Economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 39 (5): 12151229.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2017a) “Hodgson, Cumulative Causation, and Reflexive Economic Agents,” in Gagliardi, F. and Gindis, D., eds., Institutions and the Evolution of Capitalism, Essays in Honour of Geoffrey M. Hodgson, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar: 7891Google Scholar
Davis, John (2017b) “Is Mainstream Economics a Science Bubble?Review of Political Economy 29: 4: 523538.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2018a) “Agent-Based Modeling’s Open Methodology Approach: Simulation, Reflexivity, and Abduction,” Oeconomia 8–4 (2018): 509529.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2018b) “Behavioral Economics and the Positive-Normative Distinction: Sunstein’s Choosing Not to Choose and Behavioral Economics Imperialism,” Revue Éthique et Économique 15 (1): 115.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2018c) “Comment on White on the Relationship Between Economics and Ethics,” Annals of the Fondazione Luigi Einaudi 52 (2): 5768.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2018d) “Extending Behavioral Economics’ Methodological Critique of Rational Choice Theory to Include Counterfactual Reasoning,” Journal of Behavioral Economics and Policy 2 (2): 59.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2018e) “Sraffa on the Open Vs. ‘Closed Systems’ Distinction and Causality,” Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 35B: 153170.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2019a) “Economics and Economic Methodology in a Core-Periphery World,” Brazilian Journal of Political Economy 39 (3): 408426.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2019b) “Specialization, Fragmentation, and Pluralism in Economics,” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 26 (2): 271293.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2019c) “Stratification Economics as an Economics of Exclusion,” Journal of Economics, Race, and Policy 2 (3): 163172.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2020a) “Belief Reversals as Phase Transitions and Economic Fragility: A Complexity Theory of Financial Cycles with Reflexive Agents,” Review of Evolutionary Political Economy 1 (1): 6784.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2020b) “Change and Continuity in Economic Methodology and Philosophy of Economics,” Revue de Philosophie Économique/Review of Economic Philosophy 21(2): 187210.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2021) “Deepening and Widening Social Identity Analysis in Economics,” Erasmus Journal of Economics and Philosophy 14 (2): 8798.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2022) “A General Theory of Social Economic Stratification: Stigmatization, Exclusion, and Capability Shortfalls,” Review of Evolutionary Political Economy 3: 3 (2022): 493513.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2023a) “Sheila Dow’s Open Systems Methodology,” in Negru, I. and Hawkins, P., eds., Economic Methodology, History and Pluralism, London: Routledge: 3147.Google Scholar
Davis, John (2023b) “What are Reflexive Economic Agents? Position-Adjustment, SLAM, and Self-Organization,” Chen, P., Elsner, W. and Pyka, A., eds., Handbook of Complexity Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. and Klaes, Matthias (2003) “Reflexivity: Curse or Cure?Journal of Economic Methodology 10 (3): 329352.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. and McMaster, Robert (2017) Health Care Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. and Koutsobinas, Theodore (2021) “Counterfactual Thinking and Attribute Substitution in Economic Behavior,” Review of Behavioral Economics 8 (1): 123.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. and Wells, Tom (2016) “Transformation without Paternalism,” Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 17: 3: 360376.Google Scholar
Dekker, Erwin and Remic, Blaž (2019) “Two Types of Ecological Rationality: or How to Best Combine Psychology and Economics,” Journal of Economic Methodology 26 (4): 291306.Google Scholar
Dekker, Erwin and Kuchar, Pavel (2019) “Lachmann and Shackle: On the Joint Production of Interpretation Instruments,” Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 37B, 2542.Google Scholar
DeMartino, George and McCloskey, Deirdre (2015) Oxford University Press Handbook on Professional Economic Ethics: Views from the Economics Profession and Beyond, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Deneulin, Severine (2008) “Beyond Individual Freedom and Agency: Structures of Living Together,” in Comim, F., Qizilbash, M. and Alkire, S., eds., The Capability Approach: Concepts, Measures and Applications, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press: 105–24.Google Scholar
Dennett, Daniel (1987) The Intentional Stance, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Denzin, Norman (1970) “Strategies of Multiple Triangulation,” in Denzin, N., ed., The Research Act in Sociology: A Theoretical Introduction to Sociological Method, New York: McGraw-Hill: 297313.Google Scholar
Dequech, David (2007–2008) “Neoclassical, Mainstream, Orthodox, and Heterodox Economics, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 30 (2): 279302.Google Scholar
De Vroey, Michel and Pensieroso, Luca (2021) “Grounded in Methodology, Certified by Journals: The Rise and Evolution of a Mainstream in Economics,” LIDAM Discussion Papers IRES 2021015, Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de Recherches Economiques et Sociales (IRES).Google Scholar
Dold, Malte F. and Schubert, Christian (2018) “Toward a Behavioral Foundation of Normative Economics,” Review of Behavioral Economics 5 (3–4): 221241.Google Scholar
Dostoyevsky, Fyodor (1918) “Notes from Underground,” in Garnett, Constance, ed., White Nights and Other Stories, trans. Constance Garnett, London: Heinemann.Google Scholar
Dow, Sheila (2004) “Structured Pluralism,” Journal of Economic Methodology 11 (3): 275–90.Google Scholar
Dow, Sheila (2015) “Addressing Uncertainty in Economics and the Economy,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 39 (1): 3347.Google Scholar
Dow, Sheila (2021) “Economic Methodology, The Philosophy of Economics and the Economy: Another Turn?Journal of Economic Methodology 28 (1): 4653.Google Scholar
Downward, Paul and Mearman, Andrew (2007) “Retroduction as Mixed-Methods Triangulation in Economic Research: Reorienting Economics into Social Science,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 31 (1): 7799.Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, Stavros A. (2022) “The Conceptual Resilience of the Atomistic Individual in Mainstream Economic Rationality,” Review of Political Economy, DOI: 10.1080/09538259.2022.2144721Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, Stavros A. (2023) “Value Judgements, Positivism and Utility Comparisons in Economics,” Journal of Business Ethics, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-023-05395-zGoogle Scholar
Dutt, Amitava (2017) “Heterodox Theories of Economic Growth and Income Distribution: A Partial Survey,” Journal of Economic Surveys 31 (5): 12401271.Google Scholar
Elder-Vass, Dave (2011) “Top-down Causation and Social Structures,” Interface Focus 6 (2): 8290.Google Scholar
Emery, Nina, Markosian, Ned and Sullivan, Meghan (2020) “Time,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Winter Edition), E. N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/win2020/entries/time/; accessed 14 February 2021.Google Scholar
Engelen, Bart (2017)”A New Definition of and Role for Preferences in Positive Economics,” Journal of Economic Methodology 24 (3): 254273.Google Scholar
Engelmann, Dirk and Strobel, Martin (2004) “Inequality Aversion, Efficiency, and Maximin Preferences in Simple Distribution Experiments,” American Economic Review 94 (4): 857869.Google Scholar
Erasmo, Valentina (2021) “Rights, Capabilities and Recognition: An Alternative Reading of Amartya Sen and Paul Ricoeur’s ‘Dialogue’,” Critical Hermeneutics 5(2): DOI 10.13125/CH/4673Google Scholar
Erasmo, Valentina (2022) “Amartya Sen’s Earlier Conception of Economic Agents through the Origins and Development of his Capability Approach (1970–1993),” PhD Thesis Summary, Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics 15 (1): 184–193, https://doi.org/10.23941/ejpe.v15i1.596Google Scholar
Evans, Peter (2002) “Collective capabilities, Culture and Amartya Sen’s Development as Freedom,” Studies in Comparative International Development, 37 (2): 5460.Google Scholar
Favereau, Judith (2016) “On the Analogy Between Field Experiments in Economics and Clinical Trials in Medicine,” Journal of Economic Methodology 23 (2): 203222, DOI: 10.1080/1350178X.2016.1157202Google Scholar
Feduzi, Alberto, Faulkner, Phil, Runde, Jochen, Cabantous, Laure and Loch, Christopher (2022) “Heuristic Methods for Updating Small World Representations in Strategic Situations of Knightian Uncertainty,” Academy of Management Review 47 (3): 402424.Google Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Fischbacher, U. (2002) “Why Social Preferences Matter: The Impact of Non-Selfish Motives on Competition, Cooperation and Incentives,” The Economic Journal 112 (478), C1–C33.Google Scholar
Fine, Ben and Milonakis, Dimitris (2009) From Economics Imperialism to Freakonomics: The Shifting Boundaries between Economics and Other Social Sciences, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
de Finetti, Bruno (1937) “La Prevision: Ses lois logique, Ses Sources Subjectives,” Annales de l’Institut Henri Poincare 7:168.Google Scholar
Fiori, Stefano (2011) “Forms of Bounded Rationality: The Reception and Redefinition of Herbert A. Simon’s Perspective,” Review of Political Economy 23 (4): 587612.Google Scholar
Fleetwood, Steve (2008) “Structure, Institution, Agency, Habit, and Reflexive Deliberation,” Journal of Institutional Economics 4 (2): 183203.Google Scholar
Fleetwood, Steve (2021) “A Definition of Habit for Socio-Economics,” Review of Social Economy 79 (2): 131165.Google Scholar
Fleming, Peter and Spicer, André (2007) Contesting the Corporation: Struggle, Power and Resistance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Fleurbaey, Marc and Blanchet, Didier (2013) Beyond GDP: Measuring Welfare and Assessing Sustainability, Oxford: Oxford University Press, https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199767199.001.0001Google Scholar
Foley, Robert and Gamble, Clive (2009) “The Ecology of Social Transitions in Human Evolution,” Philosophical Transaction of the Royal Society B (Biological Sciences) 364: 32673279.Google Scholar
Fourcade, Marion, Ollion, Etienne and Algan, Yann (2015) “The Superiority of Economists,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 29 (1): 89113.Google Scholar
Frankfurt, Harry (1971) “Freedom of the Will and the Concept of a Person,” Journal of Philosophy 68 (1): 520.Google Scholar
Frederick, Shane, Loewenstein, George and O’Donoghue, Ted (2002) “Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review,” Journal of Economic Literature 40 (2): 351401.Google Scholar
Fuller, Chris (2013) “Reflexivity, Relative Autonomy, and the Embedded Individual in Economics,” Journal of Institutional Economics 9 (1): 109129.Google Scholar
Fuller, Chris (2020) “Uncertainty, Insecurity, Individual Relative Autonomy and the Emancipatory Potential of Galbraithian Economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 44 (1): 229246.Google Scholar
Gale, Richard, ed. (1967) The Philosophy of Time, Garden City, NY: Anchor Doubleday: 6585.Google Scholar
Gallagher, Shaun (2013) “The Socially Extended Mind,” Cognitive Systems Research 25–26: 412.Google Scholar
Gasper, Des (2004) The Ethics of Development. From Economism to Human Development, Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas (1971) The Entropy Law and Economic Process, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gibson, James (1977) “The Theory of Affordances,” in Shaw, R. and Bransford, J., eds., Perceiving, Acting, and Knowing, Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum: 6782.Google Scholar
Gibson, James (1979) The Ecological Approach to Visual Perception, Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Giedeman, Daniel (2018) “Introduction to the Special Issue: The Effects of the 2007–2009 Financial Crisis and the Great Recession Across Racial and Ethnics Groups,” Journal of Economics, Race, and Policy 1 (2–3): 4546.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd (2008) “Why Heuristics Work,” Perspectives on Psychological Science 3 (1): 2029.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd (2019) “Axiomatic rationality and ecological rationality,” Synthese 198 (4): 35473564.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd (2021) “Embodied Heuristics,” Frontiers in Psychology 12: article 711289.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd, Todd, Peter and the ABC Research Group (1999) Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd and Selten, Reinhard, eds. (2001) Bounded Rationality: The Adaptive Toolbox, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Margaret (1990) “Walking Together: A Paradigmatic Social Phenomenon,” Midwest Studies in Philosophy, vol. 15: 1–14.Google Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak and Schmeidler, David (2001) A Theory of Case-Based Decisions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak, Andrew, Postlewaite, Schmeidler, David (2009) “Is it always rational to satisfy Savage’s axioms?Economics and Philosophy 25: 285296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola (2003) Modeling Rational Agents. From Interwar Economics to Early Modern Game Theory, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Giovanola, Benedetta (2009) “Re-Thinking the Anthropological and Ethical Foundation of Economics and Business: Human Richness and Capabilities Enhancement,” Journal of Business Ethics 88 (3): 431444; DOI 10.1007/s10551-009-0126-9Google Scholar
Goffman, Erving (1963) Stigma: Notes on the Management of a Spoiled Identity, New York, Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Gold, Natalie and Sugden, Robert (2007) “Theories of Agency,” in Peter, F. and Bernhard Schmid, H., eds., Rationality and Commitment, Oxford: Oxford University Press: 280312.Google Scholar
Gramsci, Antonio (1971 [1930]) Selections from the Prison Notebooks of Antonio Gramsci, ed. and trans. Quintin Hoare and Geoffrey Nowell-Smith, London: Lawrence & Wishart.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1985) “Economic Action and Social Structure: The problem of Embeddedness,” The American Journal of Sociology 91 (3): 481510.Google Scholar
Grayot, James (2019) “From Selves to Systems: On the Interpersonal and Intraneural Dynamics of Decision Making,” Journal of Economic Methodology 26 (3): 208227.Google Scholar
Grayot, James (2020) “Dual Process Theories in Behavioral Economics and Neuroeconomics: A Critical Review,” Review of Philosophy and Psychology 11 (1): 105136.Google Scholar
Greeno, James (1994) “Gibson’s Affordances.” Psychological Review 101(2): 336342.Google Scholar
Greeno, James and Moore, Joyce (1993) “Situativity and Symbols: Response to Vera and Simon,” Cognitive Science 17 (1): 4959.Google Scholar
Greski, Leonard (2009) “Business Capability Modeling: Theory & Practice,” Architecture and Governance Magazine 5 (7): 14.Google Scholar
Grunberg, Emile and Modigliani, Franco (1954) “The Predictability of Social Events,” Journal of Political Economy 62: 465478.Google Scholar
Grüne-Yanoff, Till, Marchionni, Caterina and Feufel, Markus (2018) “Toward a Framework for Selecting Behavioural Policies: How to Choose Between Boosts and Nudges,” Economics and Philosophy 34 (2): 243266.Google Scholar
Grüne-Yanoff, Till and Hertwig, Ralph (2016) “Nudge Versus Boost: How Coherent are Policy and Theory?Minds and Machines, 26(1–2): 149183.Google Scholar
Guala, Francesco (2008) “Paradigmatic Experiments: The Ultimatum Game from Testing to Measurement Device,” Philosophy of Science 75 (5): 658669, https://doi.org/10.1086/594512Google Scholar
Guala, Francesco (2012) “Are Preferences for Real,” in Lehtinen, A. and Yilkoski, P., eds., Economics for Real, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Guala, Francesco (2019) “Preferences: Neither Behavioral nor Mental,” Economics and Philosophy 35 (3): 383401.Google Scholar
Gul, Faruk and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang (2008) “The Case for Mindless Economics,” in Caplin, A. and Scotter, A., eds., The Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics: A Handbook, New York, Oxford University Press: 339.Google Scholar
Gutwald, Rebecca, Leßmann, Ortrud, Masson, Torsten and Rauschmayer, Felix (2014) “A Capability Approach to Intergenerational Justice? Examining the Potential of Amartya Sen’s Ethics with Regard to Intergenerational Justice,” Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 15 (4): 355368.Google Scholar
Haggbloom, Steven J., Renee Warnick, Renee, Warnick, Jason E., Jones, Vinessa K., Yarbrough, Gary L., Russell, Tenea M., Borecky, Chris M., McGahhey, Reagan, Powell, John L. (2002) “The 100 Most Eminent Psychologists of the 20th Century,” Review of General Psychology 6 (2): 139152.Google Scholar
Hamermesh, Daniel (2013) “Six Decades of Top Economics Publishing: Who and How?Journal of Economic Literature 51(1): 162172.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (1990) “Grunberg and Modigliani, Public Predictions and the New Classical Macroeconomics,” Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 7: 207223.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (2001) Reflection without Rules: Economic Methodology and Contemporary Science Theory, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (2008) “Introspection, Revealed Preference, and Neoclassical Economics: A Critical Response to Don Ross on the Robbins-Samuelson Argument Pattern,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 30 (4): 453478.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (2012a) “Normative Rational Choice Theory: Past, Present, and Future,” Voprosy Economiki, N.P. Redaktsiya zhurnala “Voprosy Economiki”, vol. 10.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (2012b) “The Positive–Normative Dichotomy and Economics,” in Mäki, U., ed., Philosophy of Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier: 219239.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (2014) “Paul Samuelson and Revealed Preference Theory,” History of Political Economy 46 (1): 85116.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (2020) “Libertarian Paternalism: Taking Econs Seriously,” International Review of Economics 67 (4): 419441.Google Scholar
Hansson, Sven Ove and Grüne-Yanoff, Till (2022) “Preferences,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring Edition), Edward N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2022/entries/preferences/.Google Scholar
Hardin, Garrett (1968) “The Tragedy of the Commons,” Science 162 (3859): 12431248.Google Scholar
Harris, Cheryl. (1993) “Whiteness as Property,” Harvard Law Review 106 (8) (June):17091791.Google Scholar
Harrison, Glenn W. (1980) “The Stock-Flow Distinction: A Suggested Interpretation,” Journal of Macroeconomics 2 (2): 111125.Google Scholar
Haslam, Alex (2018) “War and Peace and Summer Camp,” Nature 556 (17 Apr.): 306307.Google Scholar
Hatfield, Gary (2021) “Sense Data,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, Fall edition, E. N. Zalta, ed., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2021/entries/sense-data/.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel (2012) Preference, Value, Choice, and Welfare, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel (2023) “Hands on Nudging,” in Davis, J. B., Caldwell, B., Mäki, U. and Sent, E-M., eds., Wade Hands as an Historian and Philosopher of Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel and Welch, Brynn (2010) “Debate: To Nudge or Not to Nudge,” Journal of Political Philosophy 18 (1): 123136.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel, McPherson, Michael, Satz, Debra (2016) Economic Analysis, Moral Philosophy, and Public Policy, 3rd ed., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Heckman, James and Moktam, Sidharth (2020) “Publishing and Promotion in Economics: The Tyranny of the Top Five,” Journal of Economic Literature 58 (2): 419470.Google Scholar
Hédoin, Cyril (2022) “Persons, Values and Consent: A Philosophy & Economic Perspective on Social Moral Choice,” book manuscript.Google Scholar
Herrmann-Pillath, Carsten (2012) “Institutions, Distributed Cognition and Agency: Rule-Following as Performative Action,” Journal of Economic Methodology 19 (1): 2142, DOI: 10.1080/1350178X.2012.661066Google Scholar
Herrmann-Pillath, Carsten (2013) Foundations of Economic Evolution: A Treatise on the Natural Philosophy of Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Herrmann-Pillath, Carsten and Boldyrev, Ivan (2014) Hegel, Institutions and Economics: Performing the Social. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hertwig, Ralph and Grüne-Yanoff, Till (2017) “Nudging and Boosting: Steering or Empowering Good Decisions,” Perspectives on Psychological Science 12 (6): 973986.Google Scholar
Heukelom, Floris (2015) “A History of the Allais Paradox,” British Journal for the History of Science 48 (1): 147169.Google Scholar
Hintikka, Jaakko (1973) Logic, Language-Games, and Information, Oxford, Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey (2003) “The Hidden Persuaders: Institutions and Individuals in Economic Theory,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 27 (2): 159175.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey (2004) “Reclaiming Habit for Non-Mainstream Economics,” Journal of economic psychology 25 (5): 651660.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey (2006) “What are Institutions?Journal of Economic Issues 40 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey (2010) “Choice, Habit and Evolution,” Journal of evolutionary economics 20 (1): 118.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey (2011) “Downward causation: some second thoughts,” www.geoffrey-hodgson.info/downward-causation.htm (accessed 30 October 2020).Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey (2012) “On the Limits of Rational Choice Theory,” Economic Thought 1 (1): 94108.Google Scholar
Hommes, Cars (2013) Behavioral Rationality and Heterogeneous Expectations in Complex Economic Systems, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hoover, Kevin D. (2012) “Microfoundational Programs,” in Duarte, P. G. and Lima, G. T., eds., Microfoundations Reconsidered: The Relationship of Micro and Macroeconomics in Historical Perspective, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar: 1961.Google Scholar
Hoover, Kevin D. and Svorenčík, Andrej (2023) “Who Runs the AEA?Journal of Economic Literature, 61 (3): 1127–71.Google Scholar
Horowitz, Irving (1994) The decomposition of sociology, Oxford University Press Human Development Capabilities Programme (2019) Human Development Report 2019, New York, NY: United Nations.Google Scholar
Hume, David (1739) A Treatise of Human Nature, edited by Selby-Bigge, L. A., 2nd ed. revised by P. H. Nidditch, 1978, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid and Reiter, Stanley (2006) Designing Economic Mechanisms, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1998) “Introduction to the Economics of Religion,” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (3): 14651495.Google Scholar
Ibrahim, Solava (2006) “From Individual to Collective Capabilities: The Capability Approach as a Conceptual Framework for Self-Help,” Journal of Human Development 7 (3): 397416.Google Scholar
Infante, Gerardo, Lecouteux, Guilhem and Sugden, Robert (2016) “Preference Purification and the Inner Rational Agent: A Critique of the Conventional Wisdom of Behavioural Welfare Economics,” Journal of Economic Methodology 23 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Inglehart, R., Haerpfer, C., Moreno, A., Welzel, C., Kizilova, K., Diez-Medrano, J., Lagos, M., Norris, P., Ponarin, E. and Puranen, B. et al., eds. (2014) World Values Survey: All Rounds – Country-Pooled Datafile Version: www.worldvaluessurvery.org/WVSDoctumentationWVL.jsp. Madrid: JD Systems Institute.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald and Welzel, Christian (2005) Modernization, Cultural Change and Democracy: The Human Development Sequence, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Sheldon H, Hall, Shane N. and Swisher, James R. (2006) “Discrete-Event Simulation of Health Care Systems,” International Series in Operations Research & Management Science in Hall, R. W., ed., Patient Flow: Reducing Delay in Healthcare Delivery, New York: Springer: 211252.Google Scholar
Jeffrey, Richard (1974) “Preference Among Preferences,” Journal of Philosophy 71 (13): 377391.Google Scholar
Jo, Tae-Hee, Chester, Lynne and D’Ippoliti, Carlo, eds. (2017) The Routledge Handbook of Heterodox Economics: Theorizing, Analyzing, and Transforming Capitalism, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (1996) “Comment,” in Arrow, K., Colombatto, E., Perlman, M. and Schmidt, C., eds., The Rational Foundations of Economic Behavior, Basingstoke: Macmillan: 251254.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (2003). “Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics,” American Economic Review 93 (5): 14491475.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1979) “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,” Econometrica 47 (2): 263292.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1982) “The Simulation Heuristic,” in Kahneman, D., Slovic, P. and Tversky, A., eds., Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, New York: Cambridge University Press: 201208.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Varey, Carol (1990) “Propensities and Counterfactuals: The Loser that Almost Won,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 59(6), 11011110.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Sugden, Robert (2005) “Experience Utility as a Standard of Policy Evaluation,” Environmental and Resource Economics 32 (1): 161181.Google Scholar
Kaplan, Greg and Violante, Giovanni (2018) “Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 32 (3): 167194.Google Scholar
Kapp, K. William (1950) The Social Costs of Private Enterprise, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kao, Ying-Fang and Velupillai, K. Vela (2015) “Behavioural Economics: Classical and Modern,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22: 223271.Google Scholar
Kierkegaard, Søren (1843) Journalen JJ:167 Søren Kierkegaards Skrifter, vol. 18, Søren Kierkegaard Research Center, Copenhagen, 1997.Google Scholar
Kirzner, Israel (1997) “Entrepreneurial Discovery and the Competitive Market Process: An Austrian Approach,” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (4): 6085.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. (1921) A Treatise on Probability, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kirman, Alan (1992) “Whom or what does the Representative Individual Represent?Journal of Economic Perspectives 6 (2): 117136.Google Scholar
Kirman, Alan (2011) Complex Economics: Individual and Collective Rationality, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank (1921) Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Koppl, Roger and Rosser, J. Barkley, Jr. (2002) “All That I Have to Say Has Already Crossed Your Mind,” Metroeconomica 53: 339360.Google Scholar
Kripke, Saul (1980) Naming and Necessity, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas (1962; 1970) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kuorikoski, Jaakko, Lehtinen, Aki and Marchionni, Caterina (2010) “Economic Modelling as Robustness Analysis,” British Journal for the Philosophy of Science 61 (3): 541567.Google Scholar
Kurz, Heinz and Salvadori, Neri (2008) “Representing the Production and Circulation of Commodities: on Sraffa’s Objectivism,” in Kurz, Heinz Pasinetti, L. and Salvadori, , eds., Piero Sraffa: The Man and the Scholar, London: Routledge: 249–77.Google Scholar
Laibson, David (1997) “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (2): 443478.Google Scholar
Lakatos, Imre (1970) “Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes,” in Lakatos, I. and Musgrave, A., eds., Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 91196.Google Scholar
Landsberger, Henry (1958) Hawthorne Revisited, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University.Google Scholar
Larrouy, and Lecouteux, (2018) “Mindreading and Endogenous Belief in Games,” Journal of Economic Methodology 24 (3): 318343.Google Scholar
Lawlor, Michael (2006) “William James’s Psychological Pragmatism: Habit, Belief and Purposive Human Behaviour,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 30 (3): 321345.Google Scholar
Lawson, Tony (1997) Economics and Reality, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lawson, Tony (2003) Reorienting Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lawson, Tony (2019) The Nature of Social Reality: Issues in Social Ontology, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lawson, Tony (2023) “Categorisation, Criticism and Pluralism in context,” in Negru, I. and Hawkins, P., eds., Economic Methodology, History and Pluralism, London: Routledge: 4860.Google Scholar
Lawson, Tony (2006) “The Nature of Heterodox Economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 30 (4): 483505.Google Scholar
Lee, Fred S. (2009) A History of Heterodox Economics: Challenging the Mainstream in the Twentieth Century, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lee, Kyu Sang (2016) “Mechanism Designers in Alliance: A portrayal of a Scholarly Network in Support of Experimental Economics,” History of Political Economy 48 (2): 191223.Google Scholar
Lehmann-Waffenschmidt, Marco (1990) “Predictability of Economic Processes and the Morgenstern Paradox, Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, Heft 2: 147160.Google Scholar
Lehtinen, Aki and Kuorikoski, Jaakko (2007) “Computing the Perfect Model: Why Do Economists Shun Simulation?Philosophy of Science 74 (July): 304329.Google Scholar
Leßmann, Ortrud (2022) “Collectivity and the Capability Approach: Survey and Discussion,” Review of Social Economy 80 (4): 461490.Google Scholar
Lewis, David (1973) Counterfactuals, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, David (1986) On The Plurality of Worlds, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Livet, Pierre (2006) “Identities, Capabilities, and Revisions,” Journal of Economic Methodology 13 (3): 327348.Google Scholar
Longino, Helen (1990) Science as Social Knowledge: Values and Objectivity in Scientific Inquiry, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. (1976) “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique,” in Brunner, K. and Meltzer, A. H., eds., The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Vol. 1 of Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Amsterdam: North-Holland: 1946.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. (2011) “Ethics, Economic Policy and the Understanding of Economic Development,” in Pontifical Council for Justice and Peace, ed., Social and Ethical Aspects of Economics: A Colloquium in the Vatican, Pontifical Council for Justice and Peace (ed.), Vatican City: Vatican Council: 105139.Google Scholar
Lukes, Steven (2005) Power: A Radical View, 2nd Ed., London: Palgrave.Google Scholar
Lykke, Nina (2010) Feminist Studies: A Guide to Intersectional Theory, Methodology and Writing, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, Donald (2007) “Is Economics Performative? Option Theory and the Construction of Derivatives Markets,” in MacKenzie, D., Muniesa, F. and Siu, L., eds., Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press: 5486.Google Scholar
Mäki, Uskali (2013) “Performativity: Saving Austin from Mackenzie,” in EPSA11 Perspectives and Foundational Problems in Philosophy of Science, Krakostas, V. and Dieks, D., eds., Dordrecht: Springer: 443453).Google Scholar
Małecka, Magdalena (2021) “Values in Economics: A Recent Revival with a Twist,” Journal of Economic Methodology 28 (1): 8897. DOI: 10.1080/1350178X.2020.1868776Google Scholar
Marchionni, Caterina and Ylikoski, Petri (2013) “Generative Explanation and Individualism in Agent-Based Simulation,” Philosophy of the Social Sciences 43 (3): 323340.Google Scholar
Margalit, Avishai (1996) The Decent Society, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Margolis, Howard (1982) Selfishness, Altruism, and Rationality, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Martins, Nuno Ornelas (2022) “Social positioning and the pursuit of power,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 46 (2): 275292.Google Scholar
Mason, Patrick, Stewart, James and Darity, William A., Jr. (2022) “Collective wealth and Group Identity: Insights from Stratification Economics,” Review of Evolutionary Political Economy 3 (3): 463491.Google Scholar
Mayhew, Anne (1998) “On the Difficulty of Evolutionary Analysis,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 22 (4): 449461.Google Scholar
McCulloch, Heather (2017) “Closing the Women’s Wealth Gap: What It Is, Why It Matters, and What Can be Done About It,” Closing the Women’s Wealth Gap Initiative.Google Scholar
McKernan, Signe-Mary, Ratcliffe, Caroline, Steuerle, C. Eugene, Zhang, Sisi (2013) “Less Than Equal: Racial Disparities in Wealth Accumulation,” Washington D.C.: Urban Institute.Google Scholar
McQuillin, Ben and Sugden, Robert (2012) “Reconciling normative and behavioural economics: the problems to be solved,” Social Choice and Welfare 38 (4): 553567.Google Scholar
McTaggart, J. M. Ellis (1908) The Unreality of Time. Mind, New Series, Vol. 17, No. 68, pp. 457–474.Google Scholar
McTaggart, J. M. Ellis (1927) The Nature of Existence, vol. II, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: Bk. V, Ch. 33; also in Gale (1967): 8697.Google Scholar
Mearman, Andrew (2011) “Who do Heterodox Economists think they are?American Journal of Economics and Sociology 70: 480510.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert K. (1936) “The Unanticipated Consequences of Purposive Social Action,” American Sociological Review 1 (6): 894904.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert K. (1949) Social Theory and Social Structure, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Michaelson, Eliot and Reimer, Marga (2022) “Reference,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, Summer Edition, Edward N. Zalta, ed., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/sum2022/entries/reference/Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart (1859) On Liberty, London: John Parker and Son.Google Scholar
Mitrouchev, Ivan and Buonomo, Valerio (2023) “Identity, Ethics and Behavioural Welfare Economics,” Economics and Philosophy, 127.Google Scholar
Mongin, Philippe (2002) “Is There Progress in Normative Economics?” in Boehm, S., Gehrke, C., Kurz, H. and Sturn, R., eds., Is There Progress In Economics? Knowledge, Truth and the History Economic Thought, London, Routledge: 145170.Google Scholar
Mongin, Philippe (2006) “A Concept of Progress for Normative Economics,” Economics and Philosophy 22 (1): 1954.Google Scholar
Mongin, Philippe (2019) “The Allais Paradox: What it became, What it really was, and What it now Suggests to us,” Economics and Philosophy 35 (3): 423459.Google Scholar
Morgan, Mary (2012) The World in the Model: How Economists Work and Think, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Morgenstern, Oskar (1928) Wirtschaftsprognose. Eine Untersuchun ihrer Voraussetzungen und Möglichkeiten, Wien: Springer Verlag.Google Scholar
Moscati, Ivan (2016) “How Economists Came to Accept Expected Utility Theory: The Case of Samuelson and Savage,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 30 (2): 291236.Google Scholar
Moscati, Ivan (2018) Measuring Utility: From the Marginal Revolution to Behavioral Economics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Myers, Samuel L. and Fy Lee, Won (2018) “Racial Disparities, Homeownership, and Mortgage Lending in the Post-Great Recession Period: The Case of the Minneapolis-St. Paul Metropolitan Area,” Journal of Economics, Race, and Policy 1 (2–3): 4759.Google Scholar
Nagatsu, Michiru (2015) “Social Nudges: Their Mechanisms and Justification,” Review of Philosophy and Psychology 6 (3): 481494.Google Scholar
Nagel, Thomas (1986) The View from Nowhere, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
von Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar (1944) Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 2nd ed., 1947; 3rd ed., 1953.Google Scholar
Noël, Reginald (2018) “Race, Economics, and Social Status,” U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington, D.C.; www.bls.gov/spotlight/2018/race-economics-and-social-status/pdf/race-economics-and-social-status.pdf (accessed 19 May 2019).Google Scholar
North, Douglass (1991) “Institutions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97112.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha (2001a) “Adaptive Preferences and Women’s Options,” Economics and Philosophy 17 (1): 6788.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha (2001b) Women and Human Development: The Capabilities Approach, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Obeng-Odoom, Franklin (2020) Property, Institutions, and Social Stratification in Africa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
O’Driscoll, Gerald and Rizzo, Mario (1996) The Economics of Time and Ignorance, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
OECD (2015-10-15) “Making Open Science a Reality,” OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers, No. 25, OECD Publishing, Paris. https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jrs2f963zs1-en; accessed 20 April 2021.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Palmer, R. G., Arthur, W. Brian, Holland, John and LeBaron, Blake (1999) “An Artificial Stock Market,” Artif Life Robotics 3: 2731.Google Scholar
Parfit, Derek (1984) Reasons and Persons, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Peirce, Charles S. (1931–1958). Collected Papers of Charles Sanders Peirce (Vols. 1–8), Charles, H., Weiss, P., & Burks, A., eds., Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pereira, Gustavo (2019) Imposed Rationality and Besieged Imagination: Practical Life and Social Pathologies, Springer.Google Scholar
Peter, Fabienne (2017) “Political Legitimacy,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, ed. Zalta, E. N., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/sum2017/entries/legitimacy/; accessed 15 July 2020.Google Scholar
Peter, Fabienne (2008) Democratic Legitimacy, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Peter, Fabienne (2012) “Sen’s Idea of Justice and the locus of normative reasoning,” Journal of Economic Methodology 19 (2): 165167.Google Scholar
Peterson, Janice and Lewis, Margaret (1999). The Elgar Companion to Feminist Economics. Cheltenham, UK Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Petracca, Enrico (2017) “A Cognition Paradigm Clash: Simon, Situated Cognition and the Interpretation of Bounded Rationality,” Journal of Economic Methodology 24 (1): 2040.Google Scholar
Petracca, Enrico and Grayot, James (2023) “How can embodied cognition naturalize bounded rationality?Synthese 201 (115), https://doi.org/10.1007/s11229-023-04124-3Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas and Saez, Emmanuel (2003) “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (1): pp. 139.Google Scholar
Petracca, Enrico and Gallagher, Shaun (2020) “Economic Cognitive Institutions,” Journal of Institutional Economics 16 (6): 747765.Google Scholar
Plato (1941) The Republic of Plato, trans. with introduction and notes by F. M. Cornford, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Platow, Michael J. and Hunter, John A. (2012) “Intergroup Relations and Conflict: Revisiting Sherif’s Boys’ Camp Studies,” Social Psychology: Revisiting the Classic Studies, Smith, J R. and Alexander Haslam, S., eds, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl (1944) The Great Transformation, Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Michael (1958) Personal Knowledge: Towards a Post-Critical Philosophy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl (1959; 1934) The Logic of Scientific Discovery, translation of Logik der Forschung. London: Hutchinson.Google Scholar
Postmes, Tom and Branscombe, Nyla, eds. (2010) Rediscovering Social Identity: Key Readings, New York: Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Primrose, David (2017) “The Subjectification of Homo Economicus in Behavioural Economics,” Journal of Australian Political Economy 80: 88128.Google Scholar
Primrose, David, Stilwell, Frank and Thornton, Tim, eds. (2022) Elgar Handbook of Alternative Theories of Political Economy, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Putnam, Hilary (2002) The Collapse of the Fact/Value Dichotomy and Other Essays, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, Hilary (2003) “For Ethics and Economics without the Dichotomies,” Review of Political Economy 15 (3): 395412.Google Scholar
Putnam, Hilary and Walsh, Vivian (2012) The End of Value-Free Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Quine, Willard van Orman (1953) “Two Dogmas of Empiricism,” in Quine, W.V.O, ed., From a Logical Point of View, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press: 2046.Google Scholar
Ramsey, Frank (1926) “Truth and Probability,” in Ramsey, F. P. (1931) Foundations of Mathematics and other Logical Essays, ed., Braithwaite, R. B., New York: Harcourt Brace: 156198.Google Scholar
Ranis, Gustav, Stewart, Frances and Ramirez, Alejandro (2000) “Economic Growth and Human Development,” World Development 28 (2): 197219.Google Scholar
Ranis, Gustav, Stewart, Frances and Samman, Emma (2006) “Human development: beyond the Human Development Index,” Journal of Human Development 7 (3):323358.Google Scholar
Rawls, John (1971) A Theory of Justice, Cambridge: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, John (2001) Justice as Fairness: A Restatement, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Reichenbach, Hans (1938) Experience and Prediction. An Analysis of the Foundations and the Structure of Knowledge, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Reiss, Julian (2017) “Fact-Value Entanglement in Positive Economics,” Journal of Economic Methodology 24 (2): 134149.Google Scholar
Reiss, Julian and Sprenger, Jan (2020) “Scientific Objectivity,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Winter Edition), Edward N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/win2020/entries/scientific-objectivity/; accessed 15 April 2021.Google Scholar
Reynolds, Katherine, Turner, John, Haslam, S. Alexander (2003) “Social Identity and Self-Categorization Theories’ Contribution to Understanding Identification, Salience and Diversity in Teams and Organizations,” in Polzer, J., eds., Identity Issues in Groups (Research on Managing Groups and Teams, Volume 5), Bingley, UK: Emerald Publishing: 279304.Google Scholar
Robeyns, Ingrid (2005) “The capability approach: A theoretical survey,” Journal of Human Development 6 (1): 93117.Google Scholar
Robeyns, Ingrid (2017) Wellbeing, Freedom and Social Justice: The Capability Approach Re-Examined, Cambridge, UK: Open Book Publishers, https://dx.doi.org/10.11647/OBP.0130Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani (2015) Economics Rules: The Rights and Wrongs of the Dismal Science, New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Roese, Neal and Morrison, Mike (2009) “The Psychology of Counterfactual Thinking,” Historical Social Research 64 (2): 1626.Google Scholar
Rogers, Carl (1951) Client Centered Therapy, London: Constable.Google Scholar
Rogers, Carl (1959) “A Theory of Therapy, Personality, and Interpersonal Relationships as Developed in The Client-Centered Framework,” in Koch, S., ed., Psychology: A Story of a Science, Vol. 3, New York: McGraw-Hill: 184256.Google Scholar
Ross, Don (2005) Economic Theory and Cognitive Science: Microexplanation, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Ross, Don (2006) “The Economic and Evolutionary Basis of Selves,” Cognitive Systems Research 7: 246258.Google Scholar
Ross, Don (2007) “H. Sapiens as Ecologically Special: What Does Language Contribute?Language Sciences 95 (5): 710731.Google Scholar
Ross, Don (2010) “The Economic Agent: Not Human, But Important,” in Maki, U., ed., Elsevier Handbook of Philosophy of Science, V. 13: Economics, Elsevier: 627667.Google Scholar
Ross, Don (2022) “Economics is converging with sociology but not with psychology,” Journal of Economic MethodologyGoogle Scholar
Rosser, J. Barkley Jr. (2021) Foundations and Applications of Complexity Economics, London: Springer Nature.Google Scholar
Roth, Alvin E., Sönmez, Tayfun Ünver, M. Utku (2004) “Kidney Exchange,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119 (2): 457488.Google Scholar
Ryle, Gilbert (1945) “Knowing How and Knowing That,” Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society New Series 46 (1945–1946): 116.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm (2010) Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel (2021) “Public Economics and Inequality: Uncovering our Social Nature,” American Economic Review 111: 126.Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel and Zucman, Gabriel (2014) “Wealth Inequality in the United States Since 1913: Evidence from Capitalized Income Tax Data,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (2): 519578.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. (1997) “The Case for Methodological Pluralism,” in Salanti, A. and Screpanti, E., eds., Pluralism in Economics: Theory, History and Methodology, Cheltenham: Elgar: Edward Elgar: 6779.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. (1998) “Methodological Pluralism,” in Davis, J. B., Hands, D.W. and Mäki, U., eds., The Handbook of Economic Methodology, Cheltenham: Elgar:Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul (1937) “A Note on Measurement of Utility,” The Review of Economic Studies 21: 19.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul (1938) “A note on the pure theory of consumers’ behaviour,” Economica, new series 5 (17): 6171.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. and Nordhaus, W. D. (2001) Economics, 17th Edition, McGraw-Hill, New York.Google Scholar
Santos, Ana C. (2009) “Behavioral experiments: how and what can we learn about human behavior,” Journal of Economic Methodology 16 (1): 7188, DOI: 10.1080/13501780802684278Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard (1954) The Foundations of Statistics, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Schechtman, Marya (1996). The constitution of selves. Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Schickore, Jutta (2018) “Scientific Discovery,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer Edition), Edward N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/sum2018/entries/scientific-discovery/; accessed 20 April 2021.Google Scholar
Schickore, Jutta (2020) “Mess in Science and Wicked Problems,” Perspectives on Science 28 (4): 482504.Google Scholar
Schmid, Hans Bernhard (2020) “Groups Speaking for Themselves: Articulating First-Person Plural Authority,” Language and Communication 70: 3845.Google Scholar
Schofield, Janet Ward (2010) “Realistic Group Conflict Theory,” in Levine, J. and Hogg, M., eds., Encyclopedia of Group Processes and Intergroup Relations, Los Angeles: Sage: 681683.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (1985) “Goals, Commitment, and Identity,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 1 (2): 341355.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (1987) On Ethics and Economics, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (1992) Inequality Reexamined, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (1995) “Gender Inequality and Theories of Justice,” in Nussbaum, M. and Glover, J., eds., Women, Culture, and Development, Oxford: Clarendon Press: 259273.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (1999) Development as Freedom, New York: Anchor.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (2002) Rationality and Freedom, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (2009) The Idea of Justice, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (2012a) “A Reply to Robeyns, Peter and Davis,” Journal of Economic Methodology 19 (2): 173176.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (2012b) “Values and Justice,” Journal of Economic Methodology 19 (2): 101108.Google Scholar
Sent, Esther-Mirjam (2004) “Behavioral Economics: How Psychology Made its (limited) way back into Economics,” History of Political Economy 36 (4): 735760.Google Scholar
Shaikh, Anwar (2016) Capitalism: Competition, Conflict, Crises, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Lawrence and Spaulding, Shannon (2021) “Embodied Cognition,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Winter 2021 Edition), Edward N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/win2021/entries/embodied-cognition/ (accessed 13 February 2022).Google Scholar
Sherif, Muzafer (1956) “Experiments in Group Conflict,” Scientific American 195: 5458.Google Scholar
Sherif, Muzafer, Harvey, O. J., Jack White, B., Hood, William R. and Sherif, Carolyn W. (1954/1961) Intergroup Conflict and Cooperation: The Robbers Cave Experiment, Norman: University of Oklahoma Book Exchange.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1954) “Bandwagon and Underdog Effects and the Possibility of Election Predictions,” Public Opinion Quarterly 18: 245253.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1955) “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 99118.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1956) “Rational Choice and the Structure of the Environment,” Psychological Review 63 (2): 129138.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1962) “The Architecture of Complexity,” Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 106 (6): 467482.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1983) Reason in Human Affairs, Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1990) “Invariants of Human Behavior,” Annual Review of Psychology, 41: 119.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1992) “What is an ‘Explanation’ of Behavior?” Psychological Science 3 (3): 150161.Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon (2005) “Behavioral Economics Research and the Foundations of Economics,” Journal of Socio-Economics 34 (2): 135150.Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon (2008) Rationality in Economics: Constructivist and Ecological Forms, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Soros, George (2013) “Fallibility, Reflexivity, and the Human Uncertainty Principle,” Journal of Economic Methodology 20 (4): 309329.Google Scholar
Speaks, Jeff (2021) “Theories of Meaning,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring Edition), Edward N. Zalta, ed., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2021/entries/meaning/Google Scholar
Spong, Heath (2019) “Individuality and Habits in Institutional Economics,” Journal of Institutional Economics 15 (5): 791809.Google Scholar
Sraffa, Piero (1931) “Surplus Product,” D3/12/7, August, Wren Library, Trinity College, Cambridge UK.Google Scholar
Sraffa, Piero (1960) Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stalnaker, Robert (1968) “A Theory of Conditionals,” in Rescher, N., ed., Studies in Logical Theory (American Philosophical Quarterly Monograph Series: Volume 2), Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 98112.Google Scholar
Stalnaker, Robert (1976) “Possible Worlds,” Noûs 10 (1): 6575.Google Scholar
Stalnaker, Robert (1987) Inquiry, Boston: Bradford Books, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Starr, Martha (2014) “Qualitative and Mixed-Methods Research in Economics: Surprising Growth, Promising Future,” Journal of Economic Surveys 28 (2): 238264.Google Scholar
Starr, William (2019) “Counterfactuals,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring), E. N. Zalta, ed., https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2019/counterfactuals/Google Scholar
Steele, Claude, Spencer, Steven and Aronson, Joshua (2002) “Contending with Group Image: The Psychology of Stereotype and Social Identity Threat,” Advances in Experimental Psychology 34: 379440.Google Scholar
Stewart, Frances (2005) “Groups and capabilities,” Journal of Human Development 6 (2): 185204.Google Scholar
Stewart, Frances (2009) “Horizontal Inequality: Two Types of Trap,” Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 10 (3): 315340.Google Scholar
Stewart, Frances and Deneulin, Severine (2002) “Amartya Sen’s Contribution to Development Thinking,” Studies in Comparative International Development 37 (2): 6170.Google Scholar
Stewart, James (1995) “Toward Broader Involvement of Black Economists in Discussions of Race and Public Policy: A Plea for a Reconceptualization of Race and Power in Economic Theory, NEA Presidential Address, 1994,” The Review of Black Political Economy 23 (3), 1336.Google Scholar
Stewart, James (2008) “Stratification Economics,” International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, Farmington Hills: Cengage.Google Scholar
Stewart, James (2010) “Racial Identity Production Dynamics and Persisting Wealth Differentials: Integrating Neo-Institutionalist Perspectives into Stratification Economics,” The Review of Black Political Economy 37 (3): 217222.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., Sen, Amartya and Fitoussi, Jean-Paul (2010) Mismeasuring Our Lives: Why GDP Doesn’t Add up, New York: The New Press.Google Scholar
Stowe, Harriet Beecher (1852) Uncle Tom’s Cabin, 2 vols., John P. Jewett and Company.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (1991) “Rational Choice: A Survey of Contributions from Economics and Philosophy,” Economic Journal 101 (4): 751785.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (2000) “Team Preferences,” Economics and Philosophy 16 (2): 175204.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (2003) “The Logic of Team Reasoning,” Philosophical Explorations 6 (3): 165181Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (2015) “Looking for a psychology for the Inner Rational Agent,” Social Theory and Practice 41 (4): 579598.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (2018) The Community of Advantage: A Behavioural Economist’s Defence of the Market. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass (2015) Choosing Not to Choose: Understanding the Value of Choice, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Szymborska, Hanna (2022) “The Evolution of Gender Wealth Inequality in the United States in a Changing Institutional Context,” Feminist Economics 28 (2): 3263.Google Scholar
Tajfel, Henri and Turner, John (1979) “An Integrative Theory of Intergroup Conflict,” in Austin, W. and Worchel, S., eds., The Social Psychology of Intergroup Relations, Monterey, CA: Brooks-Cole: 3340.Google Scholar
Tajfel, Henri and Turner, John (1986) “The Social Identity Theory of Intergroup Behaviour,” in Worchel, S. & Austin, W. G., eds., Psychology of Intergroup Relations, Chicago, IL: Nelson-Hall: 724.Google Scholar
Taleb, Nassim Nicholas (2007), The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable, New York, Random House.Google Scholar
Teschl, Miriam and Comin, Flavio (2005) “Adaptive Preferences and Capabilities: Some Preliminary Conceptual Explorations,” Review of Social Economy 63 (2): 229247.Google Scholar
Tesfatsion, Leigh (2002) “Agent-Based Computational Economics: Growing Economies from the Bottom Up,” Artificial Life 8: 5582.Google Scholar
Tesfatsion, Leigh (2006) “Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory,” in Tesfatsion, L. & Judd, K. L., eds., Handbook of Computational Economics, Volume 2: Agent-Based Computational Economics, Elsevier: 831–880.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard (2000) “From Homo Economicus to Homo Sapiens,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (1): 133141.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard (2016) “Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, and Future,” American Economic Review 106 (7): 15771600.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard and Sunstein, Cass (2003) “Libertarian Paternalism,” American Economic Review 93 (2): 175179.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard and Sunstein, Cass (2008) Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Thoits, Peggy and Virshup, Lauren (1997) “Me’s and We’s: Forms and Functions of Social Identities,” in Ashmore, R. and Jussim, L., eds., Self and Identity: Fundamental Issues, Oxford: Oxford University Press: 106133.Google Scholar
Tohmé, Fernando and Crespo, Ricardo (2013) “Abduction in Economics: A Conceptual Framework and Model,” Synthese 190 (18): 42154237.Google Scholar
Truc, Alexandre (2022) “Interdisciplinary Influences in Behavioral Economics: A Bibliometric Analysis of Cross-Disciplinary Citations,” Journal of Economic Methodology 29 (3): 217251.Google Scholar
Truc, Alexandre and Jullien, Dorian (2023) “A controversy about modeling practices: the case of inequity aversion,” Journal of Economic Methodology, DOI: 10.1080/1350178X.2023.2180153Google Scholar
Tuomela, Raimo (1995) The Importance of Us: A Philosophical Study of Basic Social Norms, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Turner, J. C. (1999). “Current Issues in Research on Social Identity and Self-Categorization Theories,” in Ellemers, N., Spears, R., & Doosje, B., eds., Social Identity: Context, Commitment, Content (pp. 634) Oxford, UK: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Turner, Jonathan (1998) The Structure of Sociological Theory, Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishing.Google Scholar
UNDP (1990) “Human Development Report 1990: Concept and Measurement of Human Development,” United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), https://hdr.undp.org/en/reports/global/hdr1990, (accessed 22 November 2020).Google Scholar
UNDP (2019) “Human Development Report 2019: Beyond income, beyond averages today: Inequalities in human development in the 21st century,” United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), https://hdr.undp.org/content/human-development-report-2019.Google Scholar
UNESCO [61719] (2021) “UNESCO Recommendation on Open Science,” SC-PCB-SPP/2021/OS/UROS; https://unesdoc.unesco.org/ark:/48223/pf0000379949.locale=en; accessed 21 January 2021.Google Scholar
United Nations (1948) “Universal Declaration of Human Rights,” United Nations, 217 (III) A, Paris: UN General Assembly; www.un.org/en/universal-declaration-human-rights/ (accessed 15 July 2020).Google Scholar
Vellupillai, K. Vela (2010) Computable Foundations for Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Vera, Alonso and Simon, Herbert (1993) “Situated Actions: A Symbolic Interpretation,” Cognitive Science 17 (1): 748.Google Scholar
Vulkan, Nir, Roth, Alvin E. and Neeman, Zvika, eds. (2013) The Handbook of Market Design, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Vygotsky, Lev (1986).Thought and Language, A. Kozulin, trans., Cambridge: MIT Press; originally published 1934.Google Scholar
Walsh, Vivian (1987) “Philosophy and Economics,” in Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, vol. 3, London: Macmillan: 861869.Google Scholar
Wasserman, Stanley and Faust, Katherine (1994) Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1964) The Theory of Social and Economic Organization, Parsons, T. (ed.), New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Weeden, Kim A., Cha, Youngjoo and Bucca, Mauricio (2016) “Long Work Hours, Part-Time Work, and Trends in the Gender Gap in Pay, the Motherhood Wage Penalty, and the Fatherhood Wage Premium,” RSF: The Russell Sage Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences 2 (4): 71102.Google Scholar
Weintraub, Roy (2002) How Economics Became a Mathematical Science, Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Welzel, Christian (2013) Freedom Rising: Human Empowerment and the Quest for Emancipation, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
White, Mark (2011). Kantian Ethics and Economics: Autonomy, Dignity, and Character. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
White, Mark (2018) “On the Relationship Between Economics and Ethics,” Annals of the Fondazione Luigi Einaudi 52 (2): 4556.Google Scholar
White, Mark, ed. (2019) Oxford Handbook on Ethics and Economics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wilcox, Nathaniel (2008) “Against Simplicity and Cognitive Individualism,” Economics and Philosophy 24 (3): 523532.Google Scholar
Williams, Bernard (1985) Ethics and the Limits of Philosophy, London: Collins.Google Scholar
Wilson, Robert A. and Foglia, Lucia (2017) “Embodied Cognition,” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring 2017 Edition), Edward N. Zalta (ed.), https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2017/entries/embodied-cognition/; accessed 1 October 2020.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, Ludwig (1953) Philosophical Investigations, translated by G. E. M. Anscombe, Oxford: Blackwell, 3rd edition, 1967.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, Ludwig (1974) On Certainty, edited by Anscombe, G. E. M. and von Wright, G. H., translated by Denis Paul and G.E.M. Anscombe, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Woodward, James (2003) Making Things Happen: A Theory of Causal Explanation, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ylikoski, Petri (2014) “Agent-Based Simulation and Sociological Understanding,” Perspectives on Science 22 (3): 318335.Google Scholar
Zappia, Carlo (2018) “Rationality Under Uncertainty: Classic and Current Criticisms of the Bayesian Viewpoint,” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 25 (6): 13871419.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • John B. Davis, Marquette University, Wisconsin and Universiteit van Amsterdam
  • Book: Identity, Capabilities, and Changing Economics
  • Online publication: 11 January 2024
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • John B. Davis, Marquette University, Wisconsin and Universiteit van Amsterdam
  • Book: Identity, Capabilities, and Changing Economics
  • Online publication: 11 January 2024
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • John B. Davis, Marquette University, Wisconsin and Universiteit van Amsterdam
  • Book: Identity, Capabilities, and Changing Economics
  • Online publication: 11 January 2024
Available formats
×