Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-25wd4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T16:32:19.545Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - A Theory of Gradual Institutional Change

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

James Mahoney
Affiliation:
Northwestern University, Illinois
Kathleen Thelen
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Get access

Summary

Once created, institutions often change in subtle and gradual ways over time. Although less dramatic than abrupt and wholesale transformations, these slow and piecemeal changes can be equally consequential for patterning human behavior and for shaping substantive political outcomes. Consider, for example, the British House of Lords. This is an institution that began to take shape in the thirteenth century out of informal consultations between the Crown and powerful landowners. By the early nineteenth century, membership was hereditary and the chamber was fully institutionalized at the center of British politics. Who would have thought that this deeply undemocratic assembly of aristocrats would survive the transition to democracy? Not the early Labour Party, which was founded in 1900 and understandably committed to the elimination of a chamber from which its constituents were, more or less by definition, excluded.

Yet Labour did not dismantle the House of Lords – despite recurring opportunities to do so during the twentieth century. Instead, the institution was reformed over time in a series of more measured moves that, successively: circumscribed its powers (especially in 1911 by a Liberal Party government), altered its composition (especially in 1958 under a Conservative government, with the addition of life peerages), and rendered it less unwieldy and – in the eyes of some – more legitimate (in 2000 under a Labour government, by reducing dramatically the number of hereditary peers).

Type
Chapter
Information
Explaining Institutional Change
Ambiguity, Agency, and Power
, pp. 1 - 37
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbott, Andrew. 2001. Time Matters: On Theory and Method. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2005. “Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1A, ed. Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steve, 85–472. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Aminzade, Ronald. 1992. “Historical Sociology and Time.” Sociological Methods and Research 20:456–480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian. 1994. Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Greif, Avner, Levi, Margaret, Jean-Laurent, Rosenthal, and Weingast, Barry R.. 1998. Analytic Narratives. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Beissinger, Mark R. 2002. Nationalist Mobilization and the Collapse of the Soviet State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berger, Peter L., and Luckmann, Thomas. 1967. The Social Construction of Reality. New York: Doubleday.Google Scholar
Taylor, Boas. 2007. “Conceptualizing Continuity and Change: The Composite-Standard Model of Path Dependence.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 19:33–54.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1995. “The Rational Choice Theory of Social Institutions: Cooperation, Coordination, and Communication.” In Modern Political Economy: Old Topics, New Directions, ed. Banks, Jeffrey S. and Hanushek, Eric A., 216–268. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capoccia, Giovanni, and Kelemen, R. Daniel. 2007. “The Study of Critical Junctures: Theory, Narrative, and Counterfactuals in Historical Institutionalism.” World Politics 59 (April): 341–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, Daniel P. 2001. The Forging of Bureaucratic Autonomy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Carpenter, Daniel P., and Moore, Colin D.. 2007. “Robust Action and the Strategic Use of Ambiguity in a Bureaucratic Cohort: FDA Officers and the Evolution of New Drug Regulations, 1950–1970.” In Formative Acts: American Politics in the Making, ed. Skowronek, Stephen and Glassman, Matthew, 340–362. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Clark, Gordon L., and Whiteside, Noel, eds. 2003. Pension Security in the 21st Century: Redrawing the Public-Private Debate. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Clemens, Elisabeth S., and Cook, James M.. 1999. “Politics and Institutionalism: Explaining Durability and Change.” Annual Review of Sociology 25:441–466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collier, Ruth Berins, and Collier, David. 1991. Shaping the Political Arena: Critical Junctures, the Labor Movement, and Regime Dynamics in Latin America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Powell, Walter W.. 1983. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” American Sociological Review 48:147–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbin, Frank. 1994. Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain, and France in the Railway Age. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downing, Brian M. 1992. The Military Revolution and Political Change: Origins of Democracy and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. 1996. “Markets as Politics: A Political-Cultural Approach to Market Institutions.” American Sociological Review 61:656–673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fligstein, Neil D. 2008. Fields, Power, and Social Skill: A Critical Analysis of the New Institutionalisms.” International Public Management Review 9 (1):227–253.Google Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. 1985. “Why Are Unions Faring Poorly in NLRB Representation Elections?” In Challenges and Choices Facing American Labor, ed. Kochan, Thomas A., 45–88. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Laitin, David D.. 2004. “A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change.” American Political Science Review 98 (4) (November): 633–652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S. 2005. “Policy Drift: The Hidden Politics of US Welfare State Retrenchment.” In Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, ed. Streeck, Wolfgang and Thelen, Kathleen, 40–82. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 1986. Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Rosemary, C.Taylor, R.. 1996. “Political Science and the Three ‘New Institutionalisms.’Political Studies 44 (December): 936–957.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannan, Michael T., and Freeman, John H.. 1989. Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Howell, Chris. 1992. “The Contradictions of French Industrial Relations Reform.” Comparative Politics 24 (2) (January): 181–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jepperson, Ronald L. 1991. “Institutions, Institutional Effects, and Institutionalism.” In The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, ed. Powell, Walter W. and DiMaggio, Paul J., 143–163. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Katznelson, Ira. 2003. “Periodization and Preferences: Reflections on Purposive Action in Comparative Historical Social Science.” In Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences, ed. Mahoney, James and Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, 270–301. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, Desmond. 1995. Actively Seeking Work: The Politics of Unemployment and Welfare Policy in the United States and Great Britain. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Klein, Janice A., and Wagner, E. David. 1985. “The Legal Setting for the Emergence of the Union Avoidance Strategy.” In Challenges and Choices Facing American Labor, ed. Kochan, Thomas A., 75–88. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kohli, Atul. 2004. State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global Periphery. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timor. 1991. “Now Out of Never: The Element of Surprise in the East European Revolution of 1989.” World Politics 44 (1) (October): 7–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishney, Robert. 1998. “Law and Finance.” Journal of Political Economy 106 (6) (December): 1113–1155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1997. “A Model, a Method and a Map: Rational Choice in Comparative and Historical Analysis.” In Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure, ed. Lichbach, Mark Irving and Zuckerman, Alan S., 19–41. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 2008. “Reconsiderations of Rational Choice in Comparative and Historical Analysis.” In Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure, ed., Lichbach, Mark Irving and Zuckerman, Alan S., 2nd ed., 117–133. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lieberman, Robert. 2006. “Private Power and American Bureaucracy: The EEOC, Civil Rights Enforcement, and the Rise of Affirmative Action.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, August 31.
Mahoney, James. 2000. “Path Dependence in Historical Sociology.” Theory and Society 29:507–548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2010. Colonialism and Postcolonial Development: Spanish America in Comparative Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1984. “The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life.” American Political Science Review 78:734–749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mettler, Suzanne. 1998. Dividing Citizens: Gender and Federalism in New Deal Public Policy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry. 1987. “Interests, Institutions and Positive Theory: The Politics of the NLRB.” Studies in American Political Development 2:236–299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 2005. “Power and Political Institutions.” Perspectives on Politics 3:215–233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1993. “Toward a Theory of Institutional Change.” In Political Economy: Institutions, Competition, and Representation, eds. Barnett, William A., Schofield, Norman, and Hinich, Melvin, 61–69. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Orren, Karen. 1991. Belated Feudalism. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palier, Bruno. 2005. “Ambiguous Agreement, Cumulative Change: French Social Policy in the 1990s.” In Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, ed. Streeck, Wolfgang and Thelen, Kathleen, 127–144. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 1994. Dismantling the Welfare State? Reagan, Thatcher, and the Politics of Retrenchment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul, and Skocpol, Theda. 2002. “Historical Institutionalism in Contemporary Political Science.” In Political Science: State of the Discipline, ed. Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V., 693–721. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Powell, Walter W. 1991. “Expanding the Scope of Institutional Analysis.” In The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, ed. Powell, Walter W. and DiMaggio, Paul J., 183–203. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Schickler, Eric. 2001. Disjointed Pluralism: Institutional Innovation and the Development of the U.S. Congress. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Scott, W. Richard. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Selznick, Philip. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Sheingate, Adam. 2007. “The Terrain of the Political Entrepreneur.” In Formative Acts: American Politics in the Making, ed. Skowronek, Stephen and Glassman, Matthew, 13–31. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth. 1986. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Political Science: The Science of Politics, ed. Weisberg, Herbert, 51–81. New York: Agathon.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1989. “Studying Institutions: Some Lessons from the Rational Choice Approach.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 1:131–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shonfield, Andrew. 1965. Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1995. “Why I Am an Historical Institutionalist.” Polity 28:103–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skowronek, Stephen, and Glassman, Matthew, eds. 2007. Formative Acts: American Politics in the Making. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Skrentny, John D. 2002. Minority Rights Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1987. Constructing Social Theories. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Streeck, Wolfgang, and Thelen, Kathleen. 2005. “Introduction: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies.” In Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, ed. Streeck, Wolfgang and Thelen, Kathleen, 1–39. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 1999. “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.” Annual Review of Political Science 2:369–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 2003. “How Institutions Evolve: Insights from Comparative Historical Analysis.” In Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences, ed. Mahoney, James and Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, 305–336. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 2004. How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 2009. “Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies.” British Journal of Industrial Relations 47 (September): 471–498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen, and Steinmo, Sven. 1992. “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.” In Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, ed. Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen, and Longstreth, Frank, 1–32. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R.. 2002. “Rational-Choice Institutionalism.” In Political Science: State of the Discipline, ed. Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V., 660–692. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Marshall, William J.. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (February): 132–163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weir, Margaret. 1992. Politics and Jobs: The Boundaries of Employment Policy in the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Yashar, Deborah J. 1997. Demanding Democracy: Reform and Reaction in Costa Rica and Guatemala, 1870s–1950s. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Zald, Mayer N. 1970. Organizational Change: The Political Economy of the YMCA. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Zald, Mayer N., and Denton, Patricia. 1963. “From Evangelism to General Service: The Transformation of the YMCA.” Administrative Science Quarterly 8 (2) (September): 214–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zorn, Dirk, Dobbin, Frank, Dierkes, Julian, and Kwok, Man-Shan. 2006. “The New Firm: Power and Sense-making in the Construction of Shareholder Value.” Nordic Organization Studies 3:41–68.Google Scholar
Zucker, Lynne G. 1983. “Organizations as Institutions.” In Research in the Sociology of Organizations, ed. Bacharach, S. B., 1–42. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×