Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-8zxtt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-12T15:02:24.920Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Discussion

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2010

Get access

Summary

There are two market failure rationales for investor protection regulation: the negative externalities of systemic failure (e.g. bank runs) and the fact that many buyers are much less well informed than sellers about the quality of the services that they are buying. This asymmetric information problem has been recognized in a number of contexts, at least since the classic ‘lemons’ article by Akerlof (1970), and it is the focus adopted by Mayer and Neven in their analysis of European financial markets. They note that the problem for investors can be particularly acute, because it may be impossible to judge ‘quality’ – the honesty and skill of advice, dealing, fund management, etc. – even after purchse. Such services are known as ‘credence’ goods; other examples are professional services.

The asymmetric information perspective taken by Mayer and Neven is in my view very apt and much needed. Their analysis also leads them to conclusions that I support. My comments are in two parts – first, a few questions about the model, and second, some further discussion of the incentives of self-regulatory organizations to detect and expose wrongdoing.

A somewhat curious feature of the model in the text is that dishonest firms are caught with probability 1 (but will nevertheless cheat unless the fine plus their capital foregone outweighs the immediate gain) and that honest firms are deemed to have misbehaved with probability 1 − α (0 < α < 1). Higher capital requirements drive away both types of firms, but improve the trade-off between honest and dishonest firms because capital and quality are associated. A combination of lower fine and higher capital requirement can therefore have merit.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1991

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×