Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-5nwft Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-10T15:53:53.684Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part III - Interpreting Customary International Rules

Current Challenges

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2024

Panos Merkouris
Affiliation:
Rijksuniversiteit Groningen, The Netherlands
Andreas Kulick
Affiliation:
Eberhard-Karls-Universität Tübingen, Germany
José Manuel Álvarez-Zarate
Affiliation:
Universidad Externado de Colombia
Maciej Żenkiewicz
Affiliation:
Nicholas Copernicus University of Toruń, Poland
Konrad Turnbull
Affiliation:
Rijksuniversiteit Groningen, The Netherlands

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2024
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

10 Police Powers in a Pandemic Investment Treaty Interpretation and the Customary Presumption of Reasonable Regulation

Oliver Hailes Footnote *
1 Introduction

In 1634, amid waves of bubonic plague, the governor of Ancona suspected that the Venetian consul had spread information detrimental to local commerce. The governor seized the consul’s possessions and banished him ‘under pretence that, contrary to public prohibition, he had caused goods to be unloaded in a time of contagion’.Footnote 1 An imbroglio of infectious disease and economic insecurity thus occasioned the arbitrary treatment of a foreign national and his property. In the realm of diplomatic protection, Emer de Vattel advised that the ‘surest way’ to settle such matters was by ‘commercial treaty’; otherwise, ‘custom is to be the rule’.Footnote 2 Four centuries later, thousands of treaties provide substantive standards and consent to arbitration in the cognate realm of investment protection. But these treaties have not supplanted the customary rule that there is no State responsibility for reasonable regulation of foreign investment. Effectively a presumption derived from territorial sovereignty, this rule has manifested in investment jurisprudence through the police powers doctrine, the right to regulate, and a margin of appreciation. Foregrounding the presumption of reasonable regulation helps to situate these arbitral trends from a generalist perspective and provides the baseline for interpretation of investment treaties in another time of contagion: the COVID-19 pandemic and its economic aftermath.Footnote 3

Section 2 reviews the demand for governments to impose a moratorium on investment treaty arbitration amid the COVID-19 pandemic. Modern treaty practice, however, already recognises the right to regulate as an affirmation of the customary position that each State may reasonably regulate foreign investment without violating international obligations. Section 3 recalls how this regulatory dimension of territorial sovereignty endured throughout the mid-century debate over the standard of compensation for nationalisation and the rise of investment treaty arbitration. The police powers doctrine is singled out as a formulation through which tribunals impose the burden on claimants to prove that a regulatory measure was unreasonable before it may be addressed as an alleged expropriation. By recognising the link between police powers and territorial sovereignty, we may realise the potential scope of the customary presumption of reasonable regulation. Section 4 identifies how this presumption may be integrated in the interpretation of investment treaties, addressing whether modern treaties may operate as leges specialis. Reasonable regulation is nevertheless presumed under the standard of fair and equitable treatment (FET) by determining legitimate expectations in light of the State’s right to regulate or by applying a margin of appreciation. Section 5 reviews classical practice on the treatment of alien property in times of infectious disease and its contemporary lessons for investment treaty arbitration alongside the international health regulations of the World Health Organization (WHO), concluding that it should be very difficult to establish that an investment obligation has been violated by regulatory measures designed to mitigate the chronic character of today’s entwined crises.

2 Treaty and Custom in the COVID-19 Pandemic

From the outset of the COVID-19 pandemic, public health measures threatened to undermine the ordinary conditions for private enterprise; the Spanish government, for example, empowered the Minister of Health to requisition industrial property.Footnote 4 Rapidly, it became apparent that markets could not ‘self-regulate in relation to all conceivable social and economic shocks’, leading to ‘interventions on a scale last seen in World War II’.Footnote 5 Scholars and practitioners published bulletins on whether such measures might trigger obligations to compensate foreign investors.Footnote 6 In light of the mounting crises, however, NGOs called on States to address proactively their exposure to costly claims. The Columbia Center on Sustainable Investment (CCSI), for instance, recommended an immediate moratorium on investment treaty arbitration and a permanent restriction on claims related to ‘measures targeting health, economic, and social dimensions of the pandemic and its effects’.Footnote 7 The proposed moratorium would last until governments had agreed on principles to safeguard ‘good faith recovery efforts’.Footnote 8

CCSI’s proposal was consistent with past demands for States to protect their right to regulate in the public interest.Footnote 9 Yet, the concerns of civil society, like much of the scholarly literature, have concentrated on perceived pitfalls of investment treaties and arbitral institutions rather than the customary foundations for investment regulation.Footnote 10 The intergovernmental reform agenda, moreover, has focused on procedural and institutional aspects of investment treaty arbitration.Footnote 11 In other words, efforts to suspend or recalibrate the practice of investment treaty arbitration have oddly illustrated the normative resilience of substantive investment law,Footnote 12 while overlooking sources of applicable law that reinforce the international lawfulness of health, social, and economic measures. A more constructive intervention than CCSI’s proposed moratorium, therefore, would be to equip vulnerable polities with defence arguments derived from customary international law that might accommodate the dynamic character of regulatory measures amid chronic crises.Footnote 13

While acknowledging that regulatory powers originate in custom, Catharine Titi argues that the right to regulate should be understood narrowly as an express treaty provision permitting a State to regulate in derogation of its commitments.Footnote 14 But one should resist the reflex to rely on treaty exceptions, which reproduces the popular perception that investment obligations normally forbid ambitious regulation.Footnote 15 In reality, the basic aim of CCSI’s moratorium has long formed part of customary international law; by virtue of the police powers doctrine, governments may indeed adopt regulatory measures in good faith without compensating investors.Footnote 16 In modern treaties, moreover, parties have secured the presumptive lawfulness of their regulatory measures not by fashioning an exceptional right under treaty law, but by ‘reaffirm[ing] their right to regulate within their territories to achieve legitimate policy objectives’.Footnote 17 As governments struggle to confront the pandemic and its aftermath, it is timely to review the enduring relevance of custom as the wellspring of investment regulation.

3 Investment Regulation under Customary International Law

To unearth the customary roots of regulatory power, it helps to survey some historical foundations of investment treaty arbitration. Modern standards of treatment, enforceable originally through diplomatic protection, emerged out of transitions from formal empire towards post-colonial independence and from coercive intervention towards peaceful means of dispute settlement.Footnote 18 Digging through juridical strata, three layers underpin the importance of custom in the regulation of foreign investment. First, the mid-century debate over the standard of compensation for nationalisation situates investment treaty arbitration as a relatively recent exception to the customary principle of permanent sovereignty over natural resources (PSNR). Secondly, before and during that debate, the regulatory dimension of territorial sovereignty was reaffirmed through instruments acknowledging the State’s right to regulate and judicial dicta that investors bear the risk of regulatory change. Finally, the police powers doctrine is identified as an expression of territorial sovereignty by which investment tribunals may distinguish non-compensable regulation from compensable expropriation. By recognising the imbrication of police powers and territorial sovereignty, we may appreciate the general application of the customary presumption that reasonable regulation does not engage State responsibility to compensate foreign investors.

3.1 Exceptional Character of Investment Treaty Arbitration

A debate over compensation for nationalisation flared up in the era of decolonisation, framed by newly independent States as a manifestation of their PSNR.Footnote 19 Now a recognised principle of customary international law,Footnote 20 PSNR was a ‘linchpin’ of the movement for a New International Economic Order.Footnote 21 Through the 1974 Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States (CERDS), the movement sought to fortify the economic content of self-determination by embedding a standard of ‘appropriate compensation’ in domestic jurisdiction.Footnote 22 But an earlier formulation of PSNR in the widely supported General Assembly resolution 1803 included the requirement of compensation ‘in accordance with international law’,Footnote 23 often decoded as ‘prompt, adequate and effective payment’.Footnote 24 Capital-exporting States defended this standard during the drafting of CERDS, opposing its ultimate adoption.Footnote 25 Subsequent awards reaffirmed that nationalisation remained subject to an international standard of compensation and the fundamental principle of pacta sunt servanda.Footnote 26 Indeed, resolution 1803 provided that ‘[f]oreign investment agreements freely entered into by or between sovereign States shall be observed in good faith’;Footnote 27 and that disputes over compensation should be settled ‘through arbitration or international adjudication’.Footnote 28 Consistent with their right of entering into international agreements,Footnote 29 States consented to prospective arbitration of investment disputes under contract, statute, or treaty.Footnote 30 By the 1990s, investment treaty arbitration had emerged as an overgrown exception to the principle of PSNR.Footnote 31 Yet, it must not be overlooked that the nationalisation debate generated a variegated grammar of sovereign rights.Footnote 32 While the right to expropriate is one dimension of sovereignty, its bounds often blur with the State’s right to regulate.Footnote 33

3.2 Regulatory Dimension of Territorial Sovereignty

Regulatory authority over foreign investment is an extension of the State’s plenary competence under customary international law to determine its internal priorities, often formulated as an expression of PSNR or the sovereign right freely to choose and develop an economic system.Footnote 34 Manifestations of regulation, as activities performed à titre de souverain, are often decisive in territorial disputes.Footnote 35 Indeed, the exclusive right to regulate, opined Max Huber in the Island of Palmas case, entails a corollary duty to regulate ‘in a manner corresponding to circumstances’.Footnote 36 This notion of correspondence implies that measures must be reasonable, reflected in contextual gradations of deference.Footnote 37 In Spanish Zone of Morocco Claims, given the State’s duty to maintain social order, responsibility for injury to foreign nationals was engaged only if local authorities acted in manifest abuse of their discretion; that is, beyond a margin of appreciation.Footnote 38 In the North Atlantic Coast Fisheries Case, moreover, Great Britain had a ‘duty of preserving and protecting the fisheries’ in its territorial waters, even though the United States had secured liberties for its nationals to exploit that resource.Footnote 39 British authorities enjoyed ‘the right to make reasonable regulations’ and the burden fell on the United States to prove that its liberties were violated by such measures.Footnote 40 These days, a State’s duty to regulate may be triggered by treaties and customary principles requiring the protection of human rights and the prevention of environmental harm, even beyond its territory.Footnote 41 The basic right and manifold duties to adopt reasonable regulations in the circumstances, however, derive fundamentally from territorial sovereignty over internal affairs, which vastly predates the articulation of PSNR.Footnote 42

In the Oscar Chinn Case, the Permanent Court of Justice held that ‘[f]avourable business conditions and goodwill are transient circumstances, subject to inevitable changes,’ including ‘the general trade depression and the measures taken to combat it’.Footnote 43 Throughout the nationalisation debate, moreover, Third World initiatives to establish an international regulatory regime for multinational corporations were resisted by capital-exporting States, which insisted that regulation was strictly for domestic jurisdiction.Footnote 44 The range of compensable expropriations, therefore, never encompassed any deprivation of property or economic disadvantage resulting merely from taxation, monetary reform, or regulatory measures.Footnote 45 Commentary to the 1967 Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) Draft Convention on the Protection of Foreign Property, for instance, acknowledged ‘the sovereign right of a State, under international law, to deprive owners, including aliens, of property which is within its territory in the pursuit of its political, social or economic ends’ and that to ‘deny such a right would be to … interfere with its powers to regulate’.Footnote 46 The power to regulate may include placing limits on activities, including their wholesale prohibition for legitimate purposes such as environmental protection.Footnote 47 The financial risk of such measures is accordingly borne by foreign nationals.Footnote 48 The customary position that any loss arising from reasonable regulation does not violate international law remains salient in contemporary investment jurisprudence, including through the police powers doctrine.

3.3 Development of the Police Powers Doctrine

While some depict the police powers doctrine as a recent innovation,Footnote 49 others have traced its deeper genealogy.Footnote 50 Derived from the Greek politeia, the notion of police as prudent regulation originated in administrative manuals of France and Germany, later adopted by William Blackstone and Adam Smith.Footnote 51 By the influence of Vattel,Footnote 52 police power as the conceptual basis for public regulation of private property evolved through the United States constitutional law and migrated to Argentina.Footnote 53 On the international stage, the concept featured in significant developments towards property protection: the jurisprudence of mixed claims commissions;Footnote 54 the 1930 Hague Conference;Footnote 55 the 1961 Harvard Draft;Footnote 56 scholarly debates;Footnote 57 the Restatements of Foreign Relations Law;Footnote 58 and the jurisprudence of the Iran-United States Claims Tribunal.Footnote 59 The police powers doctrine then entered investment treaty arbitration to shield measures from claims of indirect expropriation,Footnote 60 including health,Footnote 61 licensing,Footnote 62 environmental,Footnote 63 bankruptcy,Footnote 64 and financial regulation.Footnote 65

For two decades, investment tribunals have recognised the police powers doctrine as custom.Footnote 66 States reiterate that customary status in their submissions as respondents and non-disputing parties.Footnote 67 The resulting decisions, as ‘subsidiary means for the determination of rules of law’,Footnote 68 have further developed the ‘scope, content and conditions’ of police powers.Footnote 69 The doctrine effectively is a screening mechanism between the right to expropriate with compensation and the right to regulate without compensation.Footnote 70 While few treaties refer explicitly to police powers,Footnote 71 many now reflect the content of custom in interpretative annexes.Footnote 72 The Tribunal in Philip Morris v Uruguay rendered a typical formulation in its finding that branding restrictions and health warnings on cigarette packaging did not constitute indirect expropriation of intellectual property: ‘the State’s reasonable bona fide exercise of police powers in such matters as the maintenance of public order, health or morality, excludes compensation even when it causes economic damage to an investor’.Footnote 73

As Jorge Viñuales explained, ‘the lack of public purpose, discrimination, arbitrariness, due process, effects and/or prior specific assurances’ should be understood as ‘considerations of good faith’, which serve not as ‘cumulative requirements’ of the police powers doctrine but rather as ‘indicia guiding a broader assessment of regulatory reasonableness’ by reference to circumstances of the case and the applicable treaty standard.Footnote 74 While the standard of reasonableness gives leeway to arbitral discretion,Footnote 75 tribunals have applied that standard in a broadly deferential manner by requiring the absence of arbitrariness through some link between a rational policy and the adopted measure.Footnote 76

Not to be conflated with its domestic expression,Footnote 77 the police powers doctrine under customary international law is an operative formulation of the regulatory dimension of territorial sovereignty.Footnote 78 This nexus is evident in the Iron Rhine Arbitration, wherein the Netherlands ‘forfeited no more sovereignty than that which is necessary’ for Belgium to exercise it treaty rights and, thus, ‘retain[ed] the police power throughout that area,’ including the power to establish health, safety and environmental standards.Footnote 79 The Tribunal effectively presumed no derogation from territorial sovereignty, albeit conditioned by good faith and reasonableness.Footnote 80 While such presumptions have eroded in some contexts,Footnote 81 reaffirmation of regulatory powers in recent treaties has reinforced a general presumption that ‘investment treaties were never intended to do away with their signatories’ right to regulate’.Footnote 82

3.4 Customary Presumption of Reasonable Regulation

The principled starting point under customary international law, reflected in the police powers doctrine, is to presume that regulation is a reasonable manifestation of territorial sovereignty. ‘Presumptively’, recalled James Crawford, ‘the ordering of persons and assets is an aspect of the domestic jurisdiction of a state and an incident of its territorial sovereignty’.Footnote 83 In the Brewer, Moller and Co Case, moreover, the German-Venezuelan Commission endorsed the ‘uniform presumption of the regularity and validity of all acts of public officials’.Footnote 84 Rosalyn Higgins further referred to a ‘weighty presumption’ when measures are introduced by ‘normal legislative processes of a democratic parliament’.Footnote 85 This presumption’s contemporary relevance was reaffirmed by the partially dissenting arbitrator in Philip Morris v Uruguay, Gary Born, who endorsed: ‘the presumptive lawfulness of governmental authority under customary international law, as well as respect for a state’s sovereignty, particularly with regard to legislative and regulatory judgments regarding its domestic matters’.Footnote 86

Plainly, this presumption would be rebutted if a claimant proved that an impugned regulation was adopted in bad faith.Footnote 87 Several tribunals have also found that a State’s failure to comply with requirements of domestic law prevented its reliance on the police powers doctrine.Footnote 88 But the presumptive character of the police powers doctrine has significant implications for the burden of proof, given the party who asserts must prove.Footnote 89 If the doctrine was pleaded as an exception, tribunals might wrongly require the State to justify its regulatory measures.Footnote 90 In Servier v Poland, however, the Tribunal dismissed the claimant’s submission that the police powers doctrine was an ‘affirmative defence’ for which the respondent had to ‘prove the negative’ by demonstrating ‘an absence of bad faith and discrimination, or the lack of disproportionateness in the measures taken’.Footnote 91 The respondent had shown the domestic legal basis for its decisions not to renew marketing authorisations for pharmaceutical products.Footnote 92 The claimant thus had to prove that those decisions were inconsistent with a legitimate exercise of police powers.Footnote 93 While this burden allocation is surely correct, its basis is not merely evidential but rather reflects the customary presumption that each State is entitled to regulate in the reasonable pursuit of its priorities and may indeed be required to regulate in the circumstances, such as a duty to adopt legislation for the ‘protection of health and life of humans’.Footnote 94

Beyond the context of expropriation, the presumption of reasonable regulation is apparent in other customary rules, foremost the minimum standard of treatment.Footnote 95 The well-known Neer standard provides that ‘an unsatisfactory use of power included in national sovereignty’ amounts to ‘an international delinquency’ when conduct amounts ‘to an outrage, to bad faith, to wilful neglect of duty’ or ‘to an insufficiency so far short of international standards that every reasonable and impartial man would readily recognise its insufficiency’.Footnote 96 This formulation is often adopted to determine the content of the customary minimum standard or the related treaty standard of FET.Footnote 97 In Al Tamimi v Oman, moreover, the Tribunal observed that the ‘high threshold’ for breach of the minimum standard requires a claimant to ‘confront’ the State’s ‘margin of discretion in exercising its police powers to enforce its existing laws’.Footnote 98 Weaving together these strands, we may say there is a general presumption that a State is not responsible for loss suffered by a foreign investor as a result of reasonable regulation.

4 Integrating Custom through Investment Treaty Interpretation

This chapter has thus far bracketed the matter of how custom forms a part of applicable law in investment treaty arbitration. Most investment treaties require disputes to be determined in accordance with the treaty simpliciter or alongside rules of international law.Footnote 99 No treaty is a ‘self-contained closed legal system’; however, each must be ‘envisaged within a wider juridical context’ through the integration of ‘rules from other sources’.Footnote 100 This section explores how the police powers doctrine has been incorporated in arbitral reasoning through the principle of systemic integration, which permits the customary presumption of reasonable regulation to be taken into account generally in treaty interpretation. Modern treaties include bespoke protection of the State’s regulatory powers, which could operate as leges specialis. Arbitral recognition of the State’s right to regulate and a margin of appreciation, however, hints at the tacit integration of the customary presumption within the FET standard.

4.1 Systemic Integration of the Customary Presumption

One way of bringing custom into the interpretative process is by referencing a customary concept as the ‘ordinary meaning’ under Art 31(1) or as a ‘special meaning … the parties so intended’ under Art 31(4) of the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (VCLT).Footnote 101 But, consider the obligation not to ‘take any measures depriving, directly or indirectly, investors … of their investments’.Footnote 102 The ordinary meaning of ‘measures’ is ‘wide enough to cover any act’ and ‘imposes no particular limit on their material content or on the aim pursued thereby’.Footnote 103 In Saluka v Czech Republic, however, the Tribunal considered that ‘the concept of deprivation’ allowed for integration of the ‘customary international law notion that a deprivation can be justified if it results from the exercise of regulatory actions aimed at the maintenance of public order’.Footnote 104 The Tribunal in El Paso v Argentina similarly interpreted an expropriation standard in light of custom, requiring the claimant to show that ‘general regulations are unreasonable, that is, arbitrary, discriminatory, disproportionate or otherwise unfair’ before determining whether they neutralised property rights to constitute indirect expropriation.Footnote 105 Rather than direct reference to custom, these tribunals interpreted the obligation in light of the distinction between compensable expropriation and non-compensable regulation embodied in the police powers doctrine, which served as an organising principle around which to structure the applicable standard and burden of proof.

The principle of systemic integration applied in Saluka and El Paso is the chief means by which the customary presumption of reasonable regulation may be incorporated in arbitral practice.Footnote 106 Under Art 31(3)(c) of the VCLT, an interpreter must take into account, together with context, ‘any relevant rules of international law applicable in the relations between the parties’, including customary rules.Footnote 107 But tribunals seldom formulate precisely the rule, its relevance, or its applicability between the parties.Footnote 108 For clarity, therefore, the presumption of reasonable regulation may be formulated as the rule that there is no State responsibility to compensate for reasonable regulation of foreign investment. The elastic element of reasonableness might provoke the complaint that norms of investment law are too nebulous to qualify as custom.Footnote 109 But the ‘inchoate character’ of a rule is ‘by no means fatal to its legal character’ so long as it generates ‘an adequate apparatus of precise principles’.Footnote 110 Investment treaty arbitration may well serve as that apparatus, transforming the customary criterion of reasonableness into determinate standards of review.Footnote 111 Tribunals need not address the elements of opinio juris and concordant practice, in any event, when investment disputes tend to concern the evolving content of custom rather than its formation.Footnote 112 Moreover, the presumption of reasonable regulation is a well-established expression of territorial sovereignty, for which general practice accepted as law is axiomatic. As a customary rule, therefore, it is applicable in relations among all States and would doubtless be relevant to any investment treaty standard.Footnote 113

4.2 Investment Treaties as Leges Specialis

The chapeau of Art 31(3) of the VCLT provides that an interpreter must take into account any relevant rules ‘together with the context’. Some argue that the sparse context of investment obligations supports the operation of investment treaties as leges specialis in respect of the police powers doctrine.Footnote 114 This view might support the ‘sole effect’ approach to indirect expropriation, which focuses on the deprivation caused by a measure regardless of regulatory intent.Footnote 115 But ‘the persistence of the regulatory powers of the host State is not the accidental result of the failure of investment treaties to eliminate them’, observed Vaughan Lowe; such powers remain ‘an essential element of the permanent sovereignty of each State over its economy’.Footnote 116

Given the reaffirmation of the right to regulate in modern treaties, the context of investment treaty standards should generally permit systemic integration of the customary rule that there is no State responsibility for reasonable regulation.Footnote 117 In Bear Creek v Peru, however, the Tribunal held that an express provision for general exceptions – modelled on Art XX of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) – was ‘an exclusive list’ precluding the application of ‘other exceptions from general international law’, including ‘the police powers exception [sic]’.Footnote 118 The provision stated that ‘nothing in this Agreement shall be construed to prevent a Party from adopting or enforcing measures necessary … to protect human, animal or plant life or health’.Footnote 119 While these terms arguably imply a presumption in favour of such measures, the Tribunal imposed the burden of proving their necessity on the respondent.Footnote 120 That treaty exception, therefore, should not have precluded the presumptive operation of the police powers doctrine, given a lex generalis and a lex specialis should have the same character as either a device limiting the scope of a treaty obligation (by distinguishing a regulatory measure from an alleged expropriation) or an affirmative defence (for which a State bears the burden).Footnote 121

Another ground on which the Bear Creek Tribunal excluded the police powers doctrine was the ‘very detailed provisions’ on expropriation.Footnote 122 An interpretative annex materially provided:

Except in rare circumstances, such as when a measure or series of measures is so severe in the light of its purpose that it cannot be reasonably viewed as having been adopted and applied in good faith, non-discriminatory measures of a Party that are designed and applied to protect legitimate public welfare objectives, such as health, safety and the environment, do not constitute indirect expropriation.Footnote 123

Yet, these terms reflect custom, incorporating typical indicia of police powers and imposing upon claimants the burden of proving such measures are disproportionate.Footnote 124 Indeed, in Eco Oro v Colombia, the Tribunal held that an identical annex did not exclude but rather ‘reflect[ed] the more general doctrine of police powers in customary international law’, such that ‘awards on the police powers doctrine … may provide some guidance (by analogy)’ in ‘interpreting and applying the provisions’.Footnote 125 By entering investment treaties, States may well agree to transform the customary presumption into a more determinate test by specifying factors that arbitrators must address in their assessment of a measure’s proportionality in light of its purpose.Footnote 126 While an interpretative annex could thus operate as lex specialis in regard to indirect expropriation, the customary presumption would remain relevant in the interpretation of other standards, including full protection and securityFootnote 127 and protection against unreasonable and discriminatory measures.Footnote 128 Let us now consider the most frequently violated of all investment obligations.Footnote 129

4.3 Tacit Integration Through Fair and Equitable Treatment

The FET standard has long been criticised for arbitral expansion beyond textual warrant.Footnote 130 Tribunals adopted the framework of legitimate expectations, for instance, to determine whether a State acted unfairly.Footnote 131 Modern treaties have since narrowed the notion of FET to the customary minimum standard and thus the circumstances in which interference with expectations may violate investment obligations.Footnote 132 It is through the framework of legitimate expectations, however, that we witness further expression of the customary presumption of reasonable regulation as alpha and omega of the FET standard in the respective guises of the right to regulate and a margin of appreciation.

To establish that an expectation has been defeated, tribunals typically require a claimant to prove three interlocking elements: an unfulfilled commitment; reliance when the investment was made; and reasonableness of that reliance, allied to the first element where the commitment was implicit.Footnote 133 In El Paso, the Tribunal held that there can be ‘no legitimate expectation for anyone that the legal framework will remain unchanged in the face of an extremely severe economic crisis’.Footnote 134 Seldom do tribunals spell out the customary roots of such reasoning, treating the State’s regulatory authority as a matter of fact rather than a legal presumption. In Suez v Argentina, however, the Tribunal recognised that the police powers doctrine and the State’s right to regulate under the FET standard were in fact ‘duplicative’ inquiries.Footnote 135 In other words, each inquiry is a reformulation of the customary presumption tailored to a different standard.Footnote 136 Acknowledging the common source of the police powers doctrine and the right to regulate helps us better to understand the customary drivers of arbitral convergence on contextual inquiries into the reasonableness of government conduct, regardless of the applicable treaty standard.Footnote 137

An emerging consensus that the FET standard preserves the State’s right to regulate was complicated by disputes regarding fiscally prudent adjustments to renewable energy incentives.Footnote 138 The jurisprudence divided into ‘two schools of thought’ as to whether legislative regimes constituted specific commitments that guaranteed tariffs would not change.Footnote 139 Arguments based on the State’s right to regulate ‘miss the point’, quipped the majority in Greentech v Italy, when there were ‘repeated and precise assurances to specific investors’ that tariffs would remain fixed for two years.Footnote 140 In RREEF v Spain, however, the majority recalled that the absence of an express reference to the State’s right to regulate under the Energy Charter Treaty did not mean it was excluded from applicable law.Footnote 141 As a matter of principle, ‘an international obligation imposing on the State to waive or decline to exercise its regulatory power cannot be presumed’ absent an ‘unequivocal’ commitment; ‘more so when it faces a serious crisis’.Footnote 142 In the majority’s view, ‘there can be no doubt that States enjoy a margin of appreciation in public international law’.Footnote 143

The margin of appreciation is an established principle of the European Court of Human Rights (ECtHR) that has been adopted by several tribunals applying the FET standard.Footnote 144 The majority in Philip Morris v Uruguay held that such a margin required ‘great deference to governmental judgments of national needs in matters such as the protection of public health’.Footnote 145 Due to the complexity of scientific and policy assessments, the ‘sole inquiry’ was whether the measures were adopted with ‘manifest lack of reasons’ or ‘in bad faith’.Footnote 146 Partially dissenting arbitrator Born believed such a margin was ‘neither mandated nor permitted’ under international law, finding instead that treaty and custom required a ‘minimum level of rationality and proportionality’.Footnote 147 Yet, the concept may be viewed as another iteration of the customary presumption that Born himself endorsed.Footnote 148 A margin of appreciation serves as the final layer of deference in determining the reasonableness or proportionality of regulatory measures,Footnote 149 reflecting the epistemic advantage of local authorities and their relative proximity to mechanisms of accountability.Footnote 150 These practical and normative factors assumed real significance in the COVID-19 pandemic, which transpired as ‘a collection of national epidemics’ shaped by interwoven social and biological factors.Footnote 151

5 Reasonable Regulation in a Pandemic

Since the outbreak of COVID-19, the Bischoff Case has become a salient authority.Footnote 152 In 1898, Caracas police detained the carriage of a foreign national, which they supposed to have transported persons infected with smallpox. The police had acted on false information and eventually offered to return the carriage. Reflecting the customary presumption of reasonable regulation, the German-Venezuelan Commission held: ‘Certainly during an epidemic of an infectious disease there can be no liability for the reasonable exercise of police power, even though a mistake is made.’Footnote 153 This final section fleshes out that prescient dictum by reviewing the classical practice on diplomatic protection in times of contagion and its contemporary lessons for investment treaty arbitration, highlighting how tribunals may interpret treaty standards in light of another codification of reasonable regulation – the proportionality inquiry under Art 43 of the International Health Regulations (IHR).Footnote 154 The inherent limits of the IHR, however, mean that many claims arising from the COVID-19 pandemic and its economic aftermath should be resolved by integrating the customary presumption of reasonable regulation through the police powers doctrine, the right to regulate, or a margin of appreciation.

5.1 Classical Practice

The eminent digests contain a cluster of cases in which the British Foreign Office and the United States Department of State held that injury to property during an epidemic did not entitle a foreign national to compensation. In 1875, the destruction of property by Turkish authorities to combat plague entitled British nationals to compensation only if local subjects were compensated.Footnote 155 Similarly, in 1894, Brazilian authorities destroyed the watermelon crop of the US nationals to prevent the spread of cholera.Footnote 156 The State Department found such measures were ‘justified under the circumstances’ and accepted the Brazilian view that any claims must go before local courts.Footnote 157 The apparent standard of national treatment reflected the ubiquity of epidemics and the reciprocal need to maintain discretion without hypocrisy.Footnote 158 There was nevertheless a reasonableness requirement. In the 1893 case of Lavarello, Italy was awarded partial indemnity of a trader’s travelling expenses and spoilage of his merchandise because Cape Verdean sanitary authorities had exceeded their powers and arbitrarily withdrew an initial order permitting him to unload.Footnote 159 In Bischoff, moreover, the State was ‘liable for damages for the detention of the property for an unreasonable length of time and injuries to the same during that period’.Footnote 160 The unlawful conduct of injured foreigners was also a relevant factor in the reasonableness inquiry.Footnote 161

The limits of reasonable regulation in the time of cholera were well articulated in the 1861 case of the Azorian, a British vessel that was ordered by local authorities in Tenerife to perform quarantine despite its clean bill of health upon departure. The Queen’s Advocate complained:

The fact of the ‘Azorian’ (alone) being treated in this unjust manner without any bonâ fide reason, and whilst free communication was taking place between London and all Parts of Spain, by land and sea, is so unreasonable, and primâ facie indefensible, that the mere assertion of the technical legal power of the Board of Health to do as it did will not satisfy the British Government.Footnote 162

There had been no ‘symptom of disease on board during the voyage’; Spain did not even pretend that the ‘arbitrary and unjustifiable’ quarantine measure was ‘necessary to prevent infection, or that it was done in every (or any) other case’.Footnote 163 In a neglected passage of his leading monograph, Martins Paparinskis addressed the Azorian as an exemplary case of the distinction between compensable and non-compensable measures in State practice of the nineteenth century.Footnote 164 He accordingly adopted the Azorian case as a yardstick of classical customary law in his assessment of the modern jurisprudence on property rights in the ECtHRFootnote 165 and the Inter-American Court of Human Rights,Footnote 166 which he further linked to the formulation of arbitrariness by the International Court of Justice in the ELSI caseFootnote 167 and arbitral interpretation of the FET standard in Saluka.Footnote 168 Following the grain of the Azorian case, Paparinskis believed these authorities point towards a consistent method of examining regulatory measures that are alleged to have breached international law: deference to ‘the legitimacy of the purpose and means chosen to pursue it as such (unless they are entirely indefensible)’ coupled with ‘formal and procedural safeguards against abuse in their implementation (the absence of which permits a more critical engagement with the ends and means)’.Footnote 169

Tracing the classical practice concerning past pandemics through to modern customary law, therefore, strengthens the presumption of reasonable regulation; rebutted when a claimant proves that government conduct was unreasonable because, for instance, requirements of domestic law were arbitrarily applied, discriminatory, or knowingly violated.Footnote 170 A mid-century study observed that State responsibility would be engaged only ‘if health or quarantine regulations are imposed not bona fide to protect public health, but with the real, though unavowed, purpose of ruining a foreign trader’.Footnote 171 As Born would later put it, each State ‘possesses broad and unquestioned sovereign powers to protect the health of its population’.Footnote 172 As a further corollary of territorial sovereignty, however, Hersch Lauterpacht (in his work for the United Nations Secretariat) underscored each State’s ‘obligation to take measures both of a preventive nature and of active co-operation with other States against the spread of disease and epidemics’.Footnote 173 The pioneering instance of such cooperation was the 1851 International Sanitary Conference of a dozen European States on the ‘standardization of quarantine regulations’,Footnote 174 followed by six conferences before the first binding convention on infectious disease.Footnote 175 The World Health Assembly, composed of WHO Members, is the contemporary forum for intergovernmental cooperation, authorised to adopt regulations ‘designed to prevent the international spread of disease’.Footnote 176 Given that there are 196 parties to the IHR, it is highly likely that a tribunal would take into account any relevant rules in investment treaty claims arising from the COVID-19 pandemic, notably the restriction on additional health measures.

5.2 Current Prognosis

Two broad categories of regulatory response to the COVID-19 pandemic might give rise to an investment treaty claim: overreach and underreach.Footnote 177 Given the fear of regulatory chill animating CCSI’s proposed moratorium,Footnote 178 responsibility for alleged overreach has been our focus in this chapter.Footnote 179 It is nevertheless worth observing how the IHR sets both a floor and a ceiling for internationally lawful health measures. Parties are required to share information with WHO so the Director-General may determine whether an extraordinary event constitutes a ‘public health emergency of international concern’ (PHEIC),Footnote 180 posing ‘a public health risk to other States through the international spread of disease’ and ‘potentially requir[ing] a coordinated international response’.Footnote 181 Subject to procedural requirements,Footnote 182 the Director-General issues ‘temporary recommendations’, which may include ‘health measures’ to be implemented by a party experiencing the PHEIC or by other parties ‘without delay’ and ‘in a transparent and non-discriminatory manner’.Footnote 183 The obligation to implement recommended health measures thus serves as the regulatory floor.Footnote 184 Reflecting ‘the principles of international law’, however, the IHR reaffirms ‘the sovereign right to legislate and to implement legislation in pursuance of their health policies’ while ‘uphold[ing] the purpose’ of the IHR.Footnote 185 That purpose is, in a word, proportionality: the IHR were designed not merely ‘to prevent, protect against, control and provide a public health response to the international spread of disease’ but to do so in ways that are ‘commensurate with and restricted to public health risks’ and ‘avoid unnecessary interference with international traffic and trade’.Footnote 186

Elaborating upon the ceiling of proportionality, Art 43(1) provides that the IHR ‘shall not preclude’ parties from implementing ‘additional health measures’ in accordance with their domestic law and international obligations in order to achieve a ‘greater level of health protection than WHO recommendations’. Additional health measures, however, ‘shall not be more restrictive of international traffic and not more invasive or intrusive to persons than reasonably available alternatives that would achieve the appropriate level of health protection’. In determining whether to implement additional health measures, parties are required by Art 43(2) to base their determinations upon scientific principles; available scientific evidence of a risk to human health, or where such evidence is insufficient, the available information including from WHO and other relevant inter-governmental organisations and international bodies; and any available specific guidance or advice from the WHO. The IHR also must be implemented ‘with full respect for the dignity, human rights and fundamental freedoms of persons’.Footnote 187

Article 43 of the IHR bears a striking resemblance to Art 5.6 of the SPS Agreement,Footnote 188 under which a complaining member of the World Trade Organization (WTO) must establish that there is a reasonably available measure that achieves the responding member’s appropriate level of sanitary or phytosanitary protection and is significantly less restrictive to trade.Footnote 189 Without digressing into how WTO law should inform its interpretation,Footnote 190 it suffices to note that Art 43 of the IHR could be considered more relevant than custom in the interpretation of investment treaty standards.Footnote 191 Like the interpretative annex on indirect expropriation in Bear Creek and Eco Oro, the proportionality inquiry under Art 43 of the IHR is the applicable lex specialis for the regulation of infectious disease, setting a floor of recommendations and a ceiling of proportionality.Footnote 192 If WHO were to advance this position in an amicus brief,Footnote 193 a tribunal may be persuaded that the IHR determine the parameters of reasonable regulation during a PHEIC.Footnote 194

Yet there are limits to the relevance of the IHR. As defined under Art 1.1, ‘health measure’ means ‘procedures applied to prevent the spread of disease or contamination’, but excludes ‘law enforcement or security measures’. Restrictions on additional health measures are determined by reference to temporary recommendations during a PHEIC, which expire automatically after three months unless extended.Footnote 195 The proportionality inquiry under Art 43, moreover, balances additional health measures against restrictions on ‘international traffic’, defined under Art 1.1 as ‘the movement of persons, baggage, cargo, containers, conveyances, goods or postal parcels across an international border, including international trade’. This definition notably excludes cross-border flows of capital and financial instruments, let alone assets owned by foreign investors within a State’s territory; the IHR does even not cover the same subject matter as investment treaty arbitration.Footnote 196 Given these temporal and material limitations, the proportionality inquiry under Art 43 has minimal relevance for claims arising from the full gamut of regulatory responses to the social and economic disruptions caused by the COVID-19 pandemic.

In addition to the inbuilt limits of the IHR, it is important to recall that the principle of systemic integration is directed to the interpretation of investment treaties, not to the application of conflicting rules.Footnote 197 While the IHR may take general priority over custom in the regulation of infectious disease, an investment treaty is the product of (usually) bilateral negotiation in respect of investment promotion and protection, which may be considered a lex specialis in respect of the multilateral IHR.Footnote 198 Modern investment treaties increasingly make express provision for health measures and future treaties could actively seek to harness private capital towards public health goals through specialised mechanisms for settling health-related investment disputes.Footnote 199 In general, however, the proportionality inquiry under Art 43 of the IHR may be considered in certain claims arising from health measures during a PHEIC, but it does not supplant the customary presumption of reasonable regulation defended throughout this chapter and its manifestations in investment jurisprudence: the police powers doctrine, the right to regulate, and a margin of appreciation.

From its microscopic origin, the COVID-19 pandemic has spawned planetary crises of a social, economic, and fiscal character. Yet the State remains the locus of regulatory power in an international legal system founded on the rights and duties of territorial sovereignty. While all States are equal in their sovereignty, the asymmetric impact of the pandemic has exposed unequal institutional capacities. Past tribunals have accommodated local circumstances in determining the reasonableness of government conduct; ‘the heritage of the past as well as the overwhelming necessities of the present and future’.Footnote 200 In Philip Morris v Uruguay, the majority was satisfied that the FET standard did not ‘preclude governments from enacting novel rules’, even if these were ‘in advance of international practice’, provided they had ‘some rational basis’ and were ‘not discriminatory’.Footnote 201 Conversely, the Tribunal in Genin v Estonia found that procedures adopted by a central bank that fell short of ‘generally accepted banking and regulatory practice’ did not violate the FET standard in light of Estonia’s transition status and ‘the emergence of state institutions responsible for overseeing and regulating areas of activity perhaps previously unknown’.Footnote 202 Such factors must likewise inform how a diligent investor would reasonably expect governments to address the economic recession and social dislocation caused by the COVID-19 pandemic.Footnote 203 It should be very difficult for claimants to rebut the customary presumption of reasonable regulation without clear evidence of bad faith or discriminatory treatment, more so when threats to human rights convert the State’s right to regulate into a duty to regulate.Footnote 204

6 Conclusion

At the time of writing, the annulment committee in Tethyan Copper Company v Pakistan found that enforcement of an award of USD 5.9 billion would not compromise the ‘capacity to respond promptly and effectively to a pandemic’ despite Pakistan’s reliance on loans from the International Monetary Fund ‘to address the economic impact of the COVID-19 shock’.Footnote 205 If the committee’s insouciance were reflected in an award on the merits, that would surely provoke more calls for a moratorium or broader exceptions to investment treaty arbitration. The police powers doctrine, the right to regulate, and a margin of appreciation, however, are all examples of an ostensibly ‘new jurisprudence’ focused on finding ‘space for flexibility within the primary rules themselves’.Footnote 206 The customary presumption of reasonable regulation, as a longstanding expression of territorial sovereignty, is the underlying driver of these doctrines. While Art 43 of the IHR may have some relevance in determining the proportionality of health measures during a PHEIC, the economic aftermath of the pandemic presents a broader opportunity for governments, counsel and arbitrators to revive the general rule that there is no State responsibility for reasonable regulation of foreign investment. Investment treaty arbitration, rather than acting as an unmitigated constraint on regulatory powers, may both guard against arbitrary treatment by governments and transform the ambitious measures of successful respondents into lasting legal principle in the face of overbearing investors.

11 Bilateral Investment Treaties, Investor Obligations and Customary International Environmental Law

Madhav Mallya
1 Introduction

In 2016, Nigeria and Morocco signed a Bilateral Investment Treaty (BIT), which mandated that the foreign investor conduct an Environmental Impact Assessment (EIA) in accordance with domestic law and that both the foreign investor and the host State apply the precautionary principle to the investment.Footnote 1 The BIT also required that foreign investors comply with the international environmental obligations of the host State while operating the investment.Footnote 2 This treaty follows upon the heels of several other regional model international investment frameworks which require similar obligations.Footnote 3 BITs rarely impose obligations of conduct on foreign investors, given that they are not considered a means of economic regulation,Footnote 4 and their primary objective is the promotion and protection of investments. However, these treaties represent a new paradigm in investment treaty drafting. They try to hold foreign investors accountable for potential violations of domestic and international environmental norms. Further, both the precautionary principle and EIA are rules of customary international law.Footnote 5 Their inclusion in BITs gives rise to two pertinent issues.

First, though the precautionary principle and EIA are recognised as rules of Customary International Law (CIL), their status as CIL has been highly debated because they are, in essence, rules of procedure, and their form and content vary from jurisdiction to jurisdiction.Footnote 6 Therefore, for these rules to create binding obligations upon foreign investors, the host State must have first recognised these rules as CIL. This recognition may happen through domestic law or the ratification of an international treaty or even any other action of the host State which demonstrates acceptance of the rule.

Second, are foreign investors, most of whom are private multinational corporations, directly bound by these rules because of their inclusion in a BIT? Multinational Corporations as non-state actors are not considered to be subjects of international lawFootnote 7 and, while Investor-State Dispute Settlement (ISDS) tribunals have recognised that they need to operate the investment and act in accordance with the domestic and international environmental obligations of the host State, they have been reluctant to recognise that foreign investors may have any direct environmental obligations with the host State.Footnote 8

To discuss these issues, this chapter will be divided into three parts. The first part will briefly document how the international investment law regime has evolved from an isolated regime, focusing only on investment promotion and protection, to a regime which is trying to take investor responsibility into account. The second part of this chapter will discuss the incorporation of the precautionary principle and EIA as investor obligations into BITs, with reference to their status as CIL. It will correspondingly examine how these rules may bind the foreign investor if the host State has recognised them as CIL.

While the BITs analysed in this chapter seek to impose obligations on foreign investors, they also require the host State to apply some of these rules in conjunction with the foreign investors. Therefore, the third part of this chapter will be divided into two sections. It will first discuss how the inclusion of these rules of customary international environmental law in investment treaties will affect host States and whether host States can be held accountable by foreign investors for not implementing the precautionary principle or following EIA procedures.

The second part will discuss the decisions of investor-State arbitral tribunals towards the international environmental obligations of foreign investors as non-State actors. It will argue that while the inclusion of environmental rules in investment treaties is a welcome step towards ensuring investor responsibility, tribunals are not yet ready to acknowledge that foreign investors have responsibility towards the host State unless such obligations are a part of general international law or incorporated in domestic law.Footnote 9 It will also situate these decisions within the systemic reluctance of public international law frameworks to impose international environmental obligations on non-State actors such as multinational corporations. Most international efforts to regulate the environmental obligations of multinational corporations place the onus on State parties to create obligations of compliance, rather than create any direct obligation.Footnote 10

2 A Brief History of Environmental Regulation in Investment Treaties

The first BITs focused solely on investment promotion and protection, following a capital exporting model, which sought to protect investments in new nations and former colonies from nationalisation.Footnote 11 Initially, only a handful of BITs were signed between developed and developing nations, in part because of resistance from the New International Economic Order (NIEO) movement and the Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources (PSNR) resolution.Footnote 12 It was only in the early 1990s that certain States began signing investment treaties, following the collapse of the Soviet Union and the realisation that foreign capital was needed for economic development.Footnote 13

By the early 2000s, States had begun challenging the legitimacy of BITs, arguing that they were a restraint on the sovereign regulatory power of the host State, especially since the threat of investment arbitration could prove costly to developing host States – the concept of ‘regulatory chill’.Footnote 14 The signing of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) in 1994, led to developed economies like the US and Canada finding themselves as respondents in investment treaty arbitration, because domestic environmental regulation was often challenged by foreign investors.Footnote 15 Many erstwhile capital importing States became exporters of capital and several BITs were signed between developing countries.Footnote 16 These reasons contributed to States’ rethinking of the regulatory scope of BITs, beginning with the model US and Canada BITs of 2004 and 2006 respectively.Footnote 17 These BITs contained Exception Clauses and Non-Precluded Measures to regulate the investment, a common component of most BITs today.Footnote 18

Since then, BITs have continued the trend of allowing the host State to regulate the investment. However, it is rare to see BITs impose obligations of environmental conduct on investors and host States. Countries use IIAs to attract foreign investment and as observed recently, it does not appear likely that express investor obligations of conduct will be included in investment treaties in the immediate future, since they may serve as deterrent to the signing of investment treaties and investors may shy away from making investments.Footnote 19

Admittedly, the BIT models being discussed in this chapter are a unique exception to BIT drafting practices, envisaging that both investors and host States will play a role in the environmental management of the investment. While the treaty drafting language does not have precedent, the objective of this chapter is to give an overview of the investor obligations enshrined in these treaties so that their implications from both the perspective of investors and host States can be understood.

3 Integrating Customary International Environmental Law in Investment Treaties
3.1 Treaty Drafting Practices

Over the past decade or so, several regional model investment treaties have tried to integrate the EIA and the precautionary principles as investor obligations. The clauses in the Nigeria–Morocco BIT are based on similar clauses from other model treaties as well the International Institute for Sustainable Development Model BIT.Footnote 20 In addition, the African Union in 2016 produced the Draft Pan African Investment Code, a comprehensive document which seeks to protect the environment through investor obligations and promote investment protection in the African continent.Footnote 21 However, are these obligations couched in terms which make them directly binding on foreign investors or is their enforceability dependent on domestic law or the host State’s international environmental obligations?

Article 14(1) of the Nigeria–Morocco BIT mandates ‘that investors or the investment shall comply with environmental assessment screening and assessment processes applicable to their proposed investments prior to their establishment as required by the laws of the host state or home state, whichever is more rigorous’.Footnote 22 Article 14(3) states that

investors, their investments, and host state authorities shall apply the precautionary principle to their environmental impact assessment and to decisions taken in relation to a proposed investment, including any necessary mitigation [sic] or alternative approaches of the precautionary principle by investors and investments shall be described in the environmental impact assessment they undertake.Footnote 23

Article 18(3) states that ‘[i]nvestors and investments shall not manage or operate the investments in a manner that circumvents international environmental, labour and human rights obligations to which the host state and/or home state are parties’.Footnote 24

These clauses are almost identical to the corresponding clauses of the International Institute of Sustainable Development (IISD) Model Investment Agreement. Article 12(a) of the IISD Model Agreement provides for investors to comply with the EIA processes of the home State or the host State, whichever is more rigorous.Footnote 25 The only addition is that Article 12(a) calls for the parties to adopt a minimum standard of EIA at their first meeting and comply with these standards on all occasions. Likewise, Article 12(d) requires investors to apply the precautionary principle to their investments.Footnote 26 Article 14(d) is identical to Article 18(3) of the Nigeria–Morocco BIT.Footnote 27

While the South African Development Community (SADC) Model BIT also adopts identical language to the Nigeria–Morocco BIT and SADC Model BIT, it goes a step ahead and prescribes the International Finance Corporation’s (IFC) performance standards on environmental and social impact assessments as an alternative to home State and host State laws.Footnote 28 Likewise, the Economic Committee of West African States (ECOWAS) Common Investment Code also adopts the precautionary principle and EIA as investor obligations but only mandates the investor to undertake an EIA and social impact assessment of proposed business activities and investments with respect to natural environment and the local population in the relevant jurisdiction. It also only mandates the investor to apply the precautionary principle to the EIA or social impact assessment, including any mitigating approaches.Footnote 29

Finally, the Pan African Investment Code (PAIC) does not mention the precautionary principle but simply mandates the investor to conduct an EIA.Footnote 30 However, the Nigeria–Morocco BIT, IISD Model Investment Agreement, ECOWAS Common Investment Code and the PAIC incorporate these obligations to try and hold the investor accountable for the violation of environmental norms; they do not, however, prescribe any standard to be followed for the implementation of the precautionary principle and EIA. In the absence of a domestic law incorporating EIA or the precautionary principle, these investor obligations may be rendered nugatory. Moreover, even if the investor must act in accordance with the host State’s international obligations, which may include the host State’s recognised rules of CIL, it will be difficult for the investor to implement these rules in the absence of domestic law. It is only the SADC Model BIT which expressly prescribes the IFC standards in absence of rigorous domestic standards.Footnote 31 However, the adoption of these standards is subject to an agreement between the investor and host State. Therefore, does the inclusion of these CIL obligations in BITs have any real significance for investor obligations, or are they just window dressing without any real effect? The next subsection, which discusses the customary nature of the precautionary principle and EIA, will try to answer this question.

3.2 Customary International Law Status of the Precautionary Principle and Environmental Impact Assessment and Their Relevance as Investor Obligations
3.2.1 The Precautionary Principle

The Precautionary Principle was first incorporated into international environmental agreements in the 1980s, though precautionary thinking had been present in domestic environmental policy.Footnote 32 The basic underlying idea behind this concept is that the lack of scientific certainty about the actual or potential effects of an activity must not prevent States from taking appropriate measures.Footnote 33 The most accepted formulation of the precautionary principle is in the Rio Declaration. Principle 15 states that:

In order to protect the environment, the precautionary approach shall be widely applied by states according to their capabilities. Where there are threats of serious or irreversible damage, lack of full scientific certainty shall not be used as a reason for postponing cost-effective measures to prevent environmental degradation.Footnote 34

The precautionary principle is not so much a principle, as it is a rule or a standard.Footnote 35 This dichotomy marks a controversy regarding its actual status as a rule of customary international law. Though it has been included in several transboundary environmental treaties, all of which reflect the approach echoed in the Rio Declaration, its status as a CIL rule has been debated.Footnote 36 The debate surrounding its normative content also has a spillover effect in its application, as is it a rule that obligates a State to act irrespective of scientific uncertainty. Does such a spillover, therefore, shift the burden of proof to the proponent of a project (ie, the investor), or is it simply a standard which States may include in its domestic laws and policies, with varying environmental standards and thresholds?Footnote 37

There is one school of thought which argues that it is CIL, simply, based on the frequency of its inclusion in multilateral treaties and declarations, while another school of thought argues that it is not customary international law since actual State practice is difficult to prove empirically.Footnote 38 This is the classic rule vs standard dialectic.Footnote 39 CIL is often difficult to prove and depends upon whether widespread State practice (and corresponding opinio juris) can be established.Footnote 40 This grey area has not been resolved by the decisions of several international courts and tribunals, which have adopted what may be called a precautionary approach, where they have been reluctant to recognise the principle as CIL. This reluctance stems from the fact that while international treaties may enshrine the rule, its application, form and content differs across jurisdictions, which poses a challenge in establishing definitive State practice.

In the Southern Bluefin Tuna case, New Zealand and Australia filed for provisional measures restraining Japan from unilaterally designing and undertaking an experimental fishing programme.Footnote 41 Both New Zealand and Australia requested that the parties act consistently in accordance with the precautionary principle.Footnote 42 In their decision, the Tribunal did not expressly mention the precautionary principle, but stated that even though they could not conclusively assess the scientific evidence presented by the parties, further measures must be taken to preserve the rights of the parties and to avert further deterioration of Bluefin Tuna and that the parties must act with prudence and caution to ensure that effective conservation measures are taken.Footnote 43

Though the Tribunal did not expressly mention the precautionary principle, several separate opinions clarified the approach of the Tribunal, lending clarity to the application of the precautionary principle. Judge Laing stated that adopting an approach (sic), rather than a principle, appropriately imports a certain degree of flexibility and tends, though not dispositively, to underscore reticence about making pronouncements about desirable normative structures.Footnote 44 Judge Treves, while regretting that the precautionary principle was not expressly stated in the order of the Tribunal, underscored the importance of the Tribunal adopting a precautionary approach even though it was reluctant in taking a position whether it was a binding position of international law. Observing that the measures prescribed by the Tribunal aimed at stopping the deterioration of the Southern Bluefin tuna stock, it was essential that the Tribunal adopt a precautionary approach since there was scientific uncertainty whether the situation of the stock had improved.Footnote 45 In fact, he equated the notion of precaution with ‘caution’, an aspect inherent in the very notion of precautionary measures.Footnote 46

Reinforcing this approach, in the EC Asbestos dispute, the WTO Appellate body adopted a precautionary approach, stating that member States have the undisputed right to determine the level of health protection they deem appropriate and that Canada, the proponent of the exports, would have to prove that their ‘controlled use’ alternative would achieve the same level of protection.Footnote 47 In the Nuclear Tests case, the separate dissenting opinions of Judges Weeramantry and Palmer supported the idea of the Precautionary Principle being a rule of customary international law relating to the environment.Footnote 48 In the EC-Hormones dispute, the WTO Appellate Body, while noting that the Precautionary Principle did not override the treaty obligation of Article 5.7 of the WTO Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Standards to base measures on a risk assessment, noted that it would be unnecessary to take a position on whether the precautionary principle had been authoritatively formulated as a general principle of customary international law, since ‘responsible, representative governments commonly act from perspectives of prudence and caution where risks are irreversible…’.Footnote 49

3.2.2 Environmental Impact Assessment

Like the Precautionary Principle, the status of EIA as customary international law is not established. While it may be argued that it is custom in a transboundary context, given the number of treaties and tribunal decisions which stress its importance,Footnote 50 it is not referred to in a transnational context to the treaties discussed in this chapter. Rather, the reference to EIA will be within the domestic context. Still, it has been observed that human rights law has greatly expanded through the adoption of wide-ranging international conventions, even with the typical difficulty in establishing a practice based customary law.Footnote 51 Since many of these conventions have been ratified by almost all States, it is argued that the norms embodied in those conventions are binding on non-parties, leading to a customary law of human rights.Footnote 52 It might be argued that even though an EIA has been recognised as customary in a transboundary context, it has developed as a customary norm of international environmental law, where the rule of conducting an impact assessment is customary rather than the context in which it is undertaken.

It is evident that while the customary status of the precautionary principle as rule per se is debated, courts and tribunals appear to treat the precautionary approach as customary. What is the significance of this approach for BITs? It could be argued that by placing the onus of applying the precautionary principle in the context of an EIA on the investor and the host State, a BIT is trying to adopt a precautionary approach, giving credence to what may be termed a customary approach instead of customary rule. The significance of this inclusion cannot be underestimated. BITs, which have traditionally only obligated host States to protect the investment, could now require environmental cooperation between the investor and host State. The inclusion of these CIL rules in BITs also promotes the host State’s right to regulate the investment, though of course, domestic frameworks or standards would have to be adopted to give effect to these rules creating investor obligations.Footnote 53

While these treaties try to ensure that the host State regulates the investment in accordance with its international legal obligations and places affirmative obligations of conduct on the investor, it remains to be seen whether and how investor-State dispute settlement tribunals may interpret these clauses and agree with the objectives of such inclusion. This question is discussed in the following section.

4 The Interpretation of Environmental Obligations by Investor-State Arbitration Tribunals

While the precautionary principle and EIA clauses in the treaties discussed above have not yet been interpreted by any investor-State arbitration tribunal, they have implications for investors and host States alike. This section examines the jurisprudence of investor-State arbitration tribunals, which discuss the host State’s environmental obligations towards foreign investors – both substantive and procedural. Subsequently, it will discuss the approach of tribunals towards the environmental obligations of foreign investors.

4.1 Procedural Implications for Host States

Foreign investors have often challenged the procedures used by the host State to apply the precautionary principle to the investment or to challenge the EIA methodology employed by the host State to assess the investment.Footnote 54 Consequently, tribunals have adjudicated on the legitimacy of application of these procedural rules. Investors have also argued that host State’s neglect of the environment has led to a diminishment of value of the investment. These decisions are discussed below.

The BilconFootnote 55 decision concerned the denial of a permit to conduct mining activities in Nova Scotia following the recommendation of an environmental joint review panel (JRP). On the grounds of procedural fairness, the majority of the tribunal concluded that the review panel had acted in breach of Canadian environmental law, which amounted to a breach of the international minimum standard of treatment. The Tribunal held that it was a serious breach of the law on procedural fairness that Bilcon was denied reasonable notice of the ‘community core values’ standard of the environmental JRP as well as a chance to seek clarification and respond to it.Footnote 56 The Tribunal emphasised that while legislatures could adopt rigorous and comprehensive environmental regulations, including assessments, those regulations had to be actually implemented and carried out.Footnote 57

The Bilcon award highlights the importance of an effective and transparent impact assessment procedure prior to the establishment of the investment and could work as a call to host States to incorporate such clauses into BITs, in order to ensure stability and transparency of investment projects.Footnote 58 Such impact assessment mechanisms, along with adopting a precautionary approach, could include public participation in the form of information sharing and consultation which would increase the likelihood of potential impacts, the disclosure of all alternatives and the reasons for rejection of certain alternatives based on a measure of accountability.Footnote 59

In Allard v Barbados, the claimant claimed that the host State failed to take the necessary environmental protection measures and contributed to the contamination of the claimant’s eco-tourism site.Footnote 60 These actions violated the FET and expropriation standards of the investment.Footnote 61 While the Tribunal noted that the host State was not responsible for the contamination of the eco-tourism site, and therefore, the terms of the BIT were not violated,Footnote 62 it did note that the claimant bought the land for economic development even before submitting an environmental management plan or conducting an EIA, against the warnings of State officials.Footnote 63

The decisions in these awards may be relevant to scenarios where both the investor and the host State have the responsibility of ensuring the environmental viability of a project. The Nigeria–Morocco BIT and the African model treaties, which create such a scenario, do not explain what they mean by these clauses. Nonetheless, some educated guesses can be made as to potential interpretative implications that may arise with respect to these clauses.

First, procedurally speaking, the host State will be bound to be transparent with the investor about environmental screening procedures. Moreover, if a host State alleges that an investor is responsible for environmental degradation, the host State cannot evade responsibility if proper procedures have not been followed or if a project has been approved even without environmental sanction. Therefore, the host State may share liability with a foreign investor for environmental degradation.

Second, an investor cannot argue that environmental procedures were not informed or that the host State did not follow due procedures and that action of the host State led to a diminishment in the economic value of the investment. A joint reading of the obligations in the Nigeria–Morocco BIT, the ECOWAS treaty, and the SADC Model and to some extent, the PAIC, emphasise that the obligation to conduct an EIA employing the precautionary approach is on the investor, in conjunction with the host State and that there is a certain duty of responsibility.Footnote 64

4.2 Investor-State Arbitration and Investor Obligations

BITs do not expressly impose environmental obligations of conduct on foreign investors, whether in accordance with domestic law or international law. Consequently, tribunals have rarely had a chance to expound upon investor obligations from a general international law perspective. The limited jurisprudence on investor obligations usually involves counterclaims. However, even these instances have been marked by a reluctance on the part of tribunals to expressly recognise investor obligations unless they are treaty obligations or a general principle of international law.Footnote 65 In general, tribunals have also been reluctant to recognise human rights defences raised by host states.Footnote 66

Both the Nigeria–Morocco BIT and the SADC Model Treaty recognise the domestic and international environmental obligations of foreign investors. However, international environmental treaties do not impose any obligations on non-State actors and, while domestic law may place a precautionary burden of proof on a private actor, the onus to apply the principle and decide is on a State party.Footnote 67 Therefore, to what extent would clauses that mandate that foreign investor conduct an EIA and apply the precautionary principle, in accordance with the international legal obligations of the host State, have credence before an investor-State arbitration tribunal? Further, would such tribunals be willing to hold foreign investors liable in accordance with international law? The following analysis discusses the jurisprudence on investor obligations to answer this question.

In Aven v Costa Rica, the respondent claimed that the suspension of the claimant’s real estate project was in pursuit of legitimate environmental interests protected under the Central America-Dominican Republic Free Trade Agreement (DR-CAFTA)Footnote 68 and in accordance with Costa Rica’s domestic and international environmental obligations.Footnote 69 The respondent also argued that sound and efficient measures to protect the environment is key to the implementation of the treaty.Footnote 70 Chapter 17 of the DR-CAFTA expressly reserved space for environmental issues.Footnote 71 While making these arguments, the respondent maintained that neither the treaty nor the customary international law exonerates the claimants from complying with Costa Rica’s framework for the protection of the environment.Footnote 72 However, the respondent did not emphasise which rule of customary international law applied to the claimants.Footnote 73

One of the respondent’s key contentions was that the burden of proof was reversed on the party allegedly causing the risk of harm, that is, the claimant had the burden of disclosing to the host State, the existence of protected wetlands and forests on the construction site.Footnote 74 The respondent tied this obligation to the precautionary principle, recognised in its domestic biodiversity law which provided that ‘the burden of proof … shall correspond to whom requests the approval, the permit, or the access to biodiversity, or who is accused of having caused environmental harm’.Footnote 75 The respondent linked these obligations in its domestic law to its international obligations under the Ramsar and Biodiversity Conventions.Footnote 76

The Tribunal sided with the respondent and found that the claimant had a duty to advise the environmental authorities in matters that affect any impact to the environment, and to evidence that no adverse impact was to occur as a result of the development, and that this duty arose under domestic law.Footnote 77 Therefore, the burden of proof was with the claimant when applying for a permit to demonstrate the absence of non-permitted pollution, degradation or affectation.Footnote 78 A pertinent question arises from this ruling, relevant to our central analysis.

First, the Tribunal did not hold the claimant responsible in accordance with international law or the precautionary principle, per se, but rather in accordance with domestic law which incorporated the precautionary approach. The claimant had a duty under the domestic biodiversity law to advise the competent authority in matters that affect any impact to the environment and to evidence that no adverse impact was to occur as a result of the development.Footnote 79

Therefore, even if a BIT does say that a foreign investor must apply the precautionary principle and conduct an EIA, the tribunal will be bound to decide in accordance with the domestic law of that State, rather than an absolute rule, even if that rule is embodied in the treaty. This approach again gives rise to the rule vs standard dialectic. Even if the BIT states that the investor must operate the investment in accordance with the host State’s international obligations and apply the precautionary principle, the application of such rule will happen in accordance with domestic law, even if the host state has ratified environmental treaties which imbibe the precautionary approach.Footnote 80 It is, therefore, difficult to gauge the efficacy of the investor obligations in the Nigeria–Morocco BIT and draft PAIC from a purely international law perspective, even more so since these BITs are not in force.

Tribunals have also been reluctant to import investor obligations into investment treaties unless the treaty expressly mentions obligations.Footnote 81 In the Aven dispute, the host State also filed a counterclaim alleging that the claimant was responsible for environmental damage. Though the Tribunal recognised that the claimant was bound by the environmental measures taken by the host State under the DR-CAFTA, it observed that the treaty did not place any direct affirmative obligation on foreign investors.Footnote 82 Of course, an arbitral tribunal’s ruling may differ regarding a treaty which expressly places obligations on the investor. In such cases, as the model treaties discussed in this chapter suggest, in the absence of a domestic legal framework the question of being held liable in accordance with international law would arise.Footnote 83

The Urbaser v Argentina dispute is more relevant in the context of discussing the relationship between human rights treaties and the international investment law regime. However, the reasoning employed by the Tribunal is of some significance to understanding how the rules of international environmental law within investment treaties may apply to foreign investors.

In their counterclaim, Argentina argued that they suffered damage since the claimant failed to make the necessary level of investment, which would have guaranteed the human right to water and sanitation.Footnote 84 Their position was that under the concession contract and applicable regulatory framework, the claimants assumed investment obligations, which gave rise to bonafide expectations that the investment would be made and guarantee the human rights to water and sanitation. By failing to make these investments, the claimants violated the principles of good faith and pacta sunt servanda recognised by both Argentina and international law.Footnote 85 The claimant, on the other hand, argued that it was Argentina’s regulatory actions which prevented them from making the investment and that the Argentine Republic should be the true guarantor of human rights, and not a private party.Footnote 86 The investor also argued that the treaty did not place any express obligations on the investor and, therefore, the counterclaim of the host State faced the insurmountable challenge of being presented in the context of a BIT which did not create obligations for the investor or subject the investor to the rules of Argentine or international law.Footnote 87 While Argentina agreed that the responsibility of the investor originated under international law per se, through the concession framework, it argued that the Universal Declaration on Human Rights placed obligations on private parties and had achieved the status of customary international law.Footnote 88

In making its decision whether the investor had any positive obligation to guarantee human rights, the Tribunal referred to the dispute resolution clause of the Spain–Argentina BIT, which stated that disputes had to be decided in accordance with the general principles of international law. Using this clause as a steppingstone to further its arguments, the Tribunal ruled that a BIT cannot be an isolated, asymmetric set of rules, which only focuses on investment protection.Footnote 89 However, this is where the Tribunal showed a reluctance to read and express human rights obligation upon the investor within the treaty. The guarantee of human rights should be borne solely by the State, and the investor had a duty to ensure that its operations did not obstruct the host State from fulfilling its human rights obligations.Footnote 90 For such an obligation to exist, it should be part of another treaty or represent a principle of general international law.Footnote 91

The precautionary principle and EIA are not substantive rights. Rather within the international and transnational context, they are procedurally binding on State parties in terms of application and implementation. If the reasoning of the Urbaser Tribunal were to be followed, there is no international treaty obligation, or any general principal of international law independent of the investment treaty, which obligates private investors to implement these obligations. Therefore, it seems unlikely that tribunals would budge from their narrow stance on the international law-based obligations of investors. This reluctance stems not only from the ambiguity surrounding the international environmental obligations of non-State actors but also whether arbitrators will accept the validity of a treaty which directly imposes international obligations on investors. Irrespective of their status in general international law, most treaties only mandate that investors act in accordance with domestic law and even these obligations rarely extent to obligations of conduct.Footnote 92

The question of whether international obligations can be imposed on non-State actors or not remains unanswered. The next section explores this question from the wider perspective of those frameworks which try to impose environmental and human rights obligations on multinational corporations. It situates this discussion within the unique conception of international investment law, a regime which gives international rights to foreign investors but does not impose liabilities upon them.

5 The Environmental Liability of Foreign Investors as Non-State Actors – An International Law Perspective

The tribunals in the Urbaser and Aven counterclaims made similar observations that ‘it can no longer be admitted that companies operating internationally are immune from becoming subjects of international law’.Footnote 93 This observation was because several international instruments encouraged non-State actors to observe human rights and environmental obligations and investment treaties themselves expected investors to abide by host State measures to protect the environment. However, this is where the buck stopped, and the tribunals were unable to express themselves any further on the issue of the environmental liability of foreign investors. This limitation arose because general principles of international law do not recognise the international environmental liabilities of non-State actors. Indeed, while there are several soft law efforts to draft human rights codes for transnational multinational corporations like the ‘UN Draft Norms on the Responsibilities of Transnational Corporations and Other Business Enterprises with Regard to Human Rights’, the ‘Guiding Principles on Business and Human Rights’ and the ‘Third Draft of the Open Ended Intergovernmental Working Group (OEIGWG)’, these instruments place the onus of regulation and enforcement on State parties and do not consider, in-depth, environmental obligations.Footnote 94

There are historic and economic factors which have given investors, as private non-State actors, certain rights in international law to have their investments protected and file claims against States for a decrease in the value of the investment,Footnote 95 but they have not been imposed with reciprocal obligations. While a discussion on this dichotomy remains beyond the scope of this chapter, it is important to try and understand what the nature of environmental obligations imposed on foreign investors by the Nigeria–Morocco BIT and the PAIC are.

To that extent, do these BITs try to equate foreign investors and State parties with the same obligations? Or is there a greater burden on State parties to ensure the compliance of these norms along with cooperation and participation of the investor? The answer is, perhaps, the latter. The obligation to conduct an EIA applying the precautionary principle, and to follow the international environmental obligations of the host State, would be in conjunction with the independent obligation of the host State to ensure that its investment is in accordance with its domestic and international legal obligations. It is difficult to imagine a scenario where these obligations could be construed as being imposed solely on investors.

It will be useful to take inspiration from Alvarez’ idea that international lawyers should spend their time addressing which rules may apply to corporations, rather than thinking about whether corporations are subjects of international law or not.Footnote 96 While acknowledging that corporations do have international responsibilities, he cautions that these responsibilities cannot be the same as those of State parties simply because corporations are not the equivalent of States or natural persons.Footnote 97 Therefore, a tribunal will not agree that an investor has the responsibility of ensuring the human right to water, but can agree that the investor has the responsibility of ensuring that the precautionary approach is followed while conducting an EIA, provided there are binding legal frameworks which provide for such obligations. International law does not directly hold multinational corporations responsible for human rights violations and, therefore, the drafters of investment treaties must align the obligations of conduct they place on foreign investors with their domestic legal frameworks, ensuring that their international legal obligations have been assimilated into those domestic legislations applicable to foreign investors.

6 Conclusion

Many of the treaties discussed in this chapter have not yet come into force and, in fact, the PAIC has been relegated to the status of a policy document.Footnote 98 However, the unique aspect of these treaties is that they adopt a precautionary approach and mandate both investor and host State to assess the environmental impact of an investment with caution. In fact, the customary status of the precautionary approach is further legitimised with its integration in investment treaties. Though these environment CIL rules may bind only State parties, their inclusion in non-environmental treaties could be a step towards ensuring that State parties clearly delineate procedures for their implementation.

The reader may possibly think that this chapter started on an optimistic note, with its highlighting of the integration of customary international environmental law in investment treaties and its exploration of the possibilities of crafting investor obligations. However, it ends on a slightly pessimistic note, concluding that the efficacy of these obligations would primarily depend on domestic law mechanisms and by simply including these obligations in a treaty, even if they are CIL, is not enough. However, it is hoped that these treaties, and this chapter, mark the beginning of trying to find a solution to a problem that has plagued the study of international investment law for the past few years.

12 The Role of Customary International Law in International Investment Law Remedies The Curious Case of Natural Resources

Filip Balcerzak Footnote *
1 Introduction

The growing number of investor-State arbitrations shed a light on the role of customary international law in the context of remedies. In virtually every arbitral award based on international investment treaties, when tribunals find that respondent States have violated their obligations, stemming from the underlying treaties, they make explicit reference to the Chorzów Factory judgment. They find that the principle that an award should ‘wipe out all the consequences of the illegal act and re-establish the situation which would, in all probability, have existed if that act had not been committed’ reflects customary international law. Sometimes, additional reference is made to the Draft Articles on Responsibility of States for Internationally Wrongful Acts (ILC Articles) to confirm that the calculations which follow are rooted in customary international law. This is commonly repeated, but often no detailed analysis follows. Instead, tribunals simply proceed to calculate compensation guided by the principle that a methodology should be applied which does not result in a ‘speculative’ outcome.

This chapter analyses some of the issues which arise in this context. First, what is the real meaning of references to the Chorzów Factory judgment in virtually every investment arbitral award? Is customary international law helpful in determining remedies, or is it merely a shortcut which allows the tribunals to proceed to compensation calculations? Second, why are references to remedies other than compensation, which are available under customary international law, so rare in investor-State arbitrations?Footnote 1 Is there a place for restitution or declaratory awards in international investment law? Third, what are the differences between the consequences of lawful expropriation and the consequences of treaty breaches in the light of customary international law?

The issues discussed in this chapter are particularly visible in disputes concerning renewable energy and early-stage mining projects, both of which fall within a broad definition of the natural resources sector. Therefore, the final part of this chapter concerns the methodologies available for calculations of compensation for treaty breaches, explained by way of examples of disputes concerning the flagged industries.

2 The Chorzów Factory Judgment as the Textualisation of Customary International Law

In its judgment, issued on 13 September 1928, the Permanent Court of International Justice (PCIJ) observed as follows:

The essential principle contained in the actual notion of an illegal act – a principle which seems to be established by international practice and in particular by the decisions of arbitral tribunals – is that reparation must, as far as possible, wipe out all the consequences of the illegal act and reestablish the situation which would, in all probability, have existed if that act had not been committed. Restitution in kind, or, if this is not possible, payment of a sum corresponding to the value which a restitution in kind would bear; the award, if need be, of damages for loss sustained which would not be covered by restitution in kind or payment in place of it – such are the principles which should serve to determine the amount of compensation due for an act contrary to international law.Footnote 2

Even back in 1928, this principle was ‘established by international practice’.Footnote 3 Thus, the first pre-requisite (usus) for considering it as customary international law has been met. In 1987, the US–Iran Claims Tribunal noted that ‘in spite of the fact that it is nearly sixty years old, this judgment is widely regarded as the most authoritative exposition of the principles applicable in this field, and is still valid today’.Footnote 4 It has been confirmed on uncountable occasions since then.Footnote 5 Thus, the second condition, opinio juris sive necessitatis, has also been met.Footnote 6 In the context of investor-State disputes, States not only commonly adopt this position but also enforce and recognise arbitral awards rendered on this basis as final and binding.

The Chorzów Factory principle is reflected in the ILC Articles.Footnote 7 Even though the ILC Articles ‘seek to formulate, by way of codification and progressive development, the basic rules of international law concerning the responsibility of States for their internationally wrongful acts’, their respective provisions codify, not progressively develop, the principle reflected in the Chorzów Factory judgment.Footnote 8

The ILC Articles precisely define that Part Two thereof (which includes remedies) ‘does not apply to obligations of reparation to the extent that these arise towards or are invoked by a person or entity other than a State’.Footnote 9 This ‘is without prejudice to any right, arising from the international responsibility of a State, which may accrue directly to any person or entity other than a State’.Footnote 10 Despite that, they have been continuously referred to in investor-State arbitrations.Footnote 11 Depending on how one assesses the nature of investors’ rights under investment treaties, they are applicable either directly or mutatis mutandis. One possible theoretical approach is that investment treaties create investors’ own substantive and procedural rights (being States’ obligations towards investors, which would allow for Part Two of the ILC Articles being applied only mutatis mutandis).Footnote 12 Another possible approach is that investment treaties create procedural rights which can be applied to trigger arbitral proceedings related to alleged breaches of obligations owed to the State of the investor’s nationality (being obligations owed to the other contracting State, and not to the investors themselves, which would allow for Part Two of the ILC Articles being applied directly).Footnote 13

The Chorzów Factory judgment is frequently referred to by arbitral tribunals in cases based on investment treaties.Footnote 14 The tribunals consider the Chorzów Factory judgment as reflecting customary international law and, therefore, playing a pivotal role in determining remedies available in investor-State arbitrations. Even though the starting point for determining the remedies available in each case is always the text of the applicable investment treaty,Footnote 15 most treaties remain silent on the issue of remedies for their breach, although a few exceptions exist.Footnote 16 Thus, customary international law becomes relevant, as it governs issues that are not regulated in an applicable international treaty.Footnote 17

The Chorzów Factory principle ‘is precise, strict, and unchangeable as a principle, but flexible and useful in a myriad of different scenarios’.Footnote 18 Its biggest advantage sometimes turns out to be its disadvantage – tribunals have frequently failed to sufficiently analyse the application of this customary international law rule. Instead, they often tend to take a ‘shortcut’ and proceed to calculation of compensation, simply observing that this is ‘consistent with the principles set forth’ in the Chorzów Factory judgment.Footnote 19

3 Restitution as the Primary Remedy

Under the Chorzów Factory principle, restitution is the default remedy for violations of a State’s international obligations.Footnote 20 Only when restitution ‘is not possible’ should the ‘payment of a sum corresponding to the value which a restitution in kind would bear’ be awarded.Footnote 21 This is re-affirmed in Article 36(1) of the ILC Articles, according to which a State responsible for an internationally wrongful act ‘is under an obligation to compensate for the damage caused thereby, insofar as such damage is not made good by restitution’.

Therefore, under customary international law, the broad concept of ‘reparation’ is divided into three subcategories: restitution, compensation and satisfaction, each being a different type of remedy. Restitution is a default remedy and a primary obligation of a State which violates an investment treaty.Footnote 22 However, sometimes full reparation may only be achieved by combining different forms of reparation.Footnote 23

From a theoretical perspective, the possibility of arbitral tribunals awarding restitution in investor-State disputes has been recognised for many years.Footnote 24 This theoretical possibility has been confirmed as available in investor-State arbitrations.Footnote 25 In light of the above, it may be surprising that investor-State arbitral awards almost always comprise a compensation payment.Footnote 26 Only sometimes does this result from a particular substantive law being applicable to the dispute.Footnote 27 Typically, investment treaties do not address remedies at all, so they also do not preclude the possibility of restitution.

Most probably, the main reason for tribunals paying insufficient attention to restitution is the way in which claims are framed. Claimants have the right to choose which form of remedies they seek.Footnote 28 The way in which claims are framed binds the tribunals, which cannot go beyond the remedies sought by the claimants.Footnote 29 It is rare in practice for investors to seek remedies other than compensation.Footnote 30 It was rightly commented that ‘the ultimate goal of the claimant in an investment treaty arbitration is almost always the payment of compensation for the harm it believes it has suffered at a host State’s hands’.Footnote 31

Recent awards rendered against Spain suggest that this approach may be revisited in practice. In Eiser v Spain, Masdar v Spain, Antin v Spain, RREEF v Spain, RWE v Spain, PV Investors v Spain and Watkins v Spain, the claimants primarily sought restitution and only asked for compensation if restitution was not awarded.Footnote 32 None of the tribunals in these cases declined the theoretical possibility of awarding restitution.Footnote 33 However, each tribunal arrived at the conclusion that restitution was inappropriate on the facts of the particular case.

Such an approach seems to be justified in the Spanish saga cases, which concern alleged violations of investment treaties arising due to changes in the general regulatory framework. Restitution can be replaced by compensation not only where restitution is ‘not possible’ (as expressly stated in the Chorzów Factory judgment and recognised in Art 35 of the ILC Articles), but also if restitution is ‘unavailable’ or ‘inadequate’.Footnote 34

It would be either impossible, or at least extremely difficult, to comply with an award which ordered the restitution of previously applicable laws and regulations.Footnote 35 Moreover, the Tribunals in Eiser v Spain, Antin v Spain and Watkins v Spain observed that ordering restitution could give rise to doubts as to the permissibility of limiting State sovereignty.Footnote 36 The Tribunal in Masdar v Spain concluded that it could ‘unduly burden’ the respondent’s ‘legislative and regulatory autonomy’.Footnote 37 The Tribunal in RWE v Spain observed that the case was ‘plainly not an appropriate case for restitution’, as it involved regulations ‘generally applicable across a very important sector in Spain’ and restitution ‘would obviously involve a burden to the Respondent out of all proportion’.Footnote 38

The ‘sovereignty concern’ is well founded in the context of treaty violations caused by changes to generally applicable regulatory frameworks, as happened in the Spanish saga cases. It is less justified in cases concerning treaty breaches targeting a specific, individual investor. In such cases, the approach adopted by Energy Charter Treaty (ECT), North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the United States Mexico Canada Agreement (USMCA) provide useful guidance on how to mitigate the sovereignty concern related to restitution by ordering that the respondent ‘may pay monetary damages and any applicable interest in lieu of restitution’.Footnote 39 This solution is not a deviation from the Chorzów Factory principle.Footnote 40 Arbitral tribunals have the possibility to adopt a similar approach in investment disputes based on investment treaties other than ECT, NAFTA or USMCA. This is certainly so if the claimant presents an explicit request for such relief. However, even if a claimant’s request is framed in a traditional manner – ie, it requests restitution and, only if restitution is impossible, compensation as an alternative – this opens the door for the tribunal to order restitution with the possibility to pay compensation in lieu of restitution.

Alternatively, tribunals can award restitution, stipulate a time limit within which it must materialise and proceed to ordering compensation only if the respondent fails to perform the specific obligation imposed upon it. Although no publicly available arbitral award reveals that this theoretical possibility has already been applied in practice, an analogy can be made from some tribunals’ approach of deferring a decision on compensation to await both parties’ initiative to provide a joint experts’ report, whilst at the same time securing an alternative scenario if the parties cannot or do not wish to reach an agreement.Footnote 41

Restitution may occur alongside compensation, not merely as an alternative.Footnote 42 With respect to an income-generating business, a return of the asset alone would not fully compensate the investor, as it would not compensate the income lost by that business in the intervening period.Footnote 43 In such a case, restitution should take place ‘in combination’ with compensation, as explicitly stated in Article 34 of the ILC Articles.Footnote 44 Only then is the principle of full reparation met.Footnote 45 Similarly, restitution should take place ‘in combination’ with compensation if an expropriated asset has lost its value since it was taken away. Otherwise, the claimant would be in a worse position if the asset were returned to him than if he received compensation.Footnote 46

4 No Place for Declaratory-Only Awards

Satisfaction is a third type of remedy available for the violation of treaty obligations. This remedy comes into play insofar as the injury ‘cannot be made good by restitution or compensation’.Footnote 47 In this sense, an award itself, which declares the wrongfulness of State actions, can constitute satisfaction – a form of reparation.Footnote 48

This remedy has little, if any, relevance in investor-State disputes. First, no investor would ever decide to commence costly arbitral proceedings solely to achieve this purpose. Therefore, a declaratory-only award by itself would be considered a ‘paper victory’ and a de facto loss, rather than one which results in meaningful reparation being granted.

Second, the award must be made public if the claimant is to receive satisfaction within the above meaning. Many arbitral awards remain unpublished, notwithstanding a certain tendency towards transparency.Footnote 49 The fact that an award will remain confidential would require an arbitral tribunal to order the State to issue ‘an acknowledgement of the breach, an expression of regret, a formal apology or another appropriate modality’, rather than simply issuing an award which declares that certain treaty provisions were infringed.Footnote 50

Although theoretically possible, there is nothing in the public domain to suggest that a claim has ever been framed in that manner, ie requesting exclusively declaratory relief.Footnote 51 Claimants invariably request declaratory relief in conjunction with compensation (and sometimes restitution).Footnote 52

5 Compensation for Lawful Expropriation

When looking at compensation, it is important to differentiate between lawful expropriation and violations of investment treaties, including unlawful expropriation.Footnote 53

Expropriation as such is not prohibited under general international law.Footnote 54 On the contrary, States have a right to expropriate alien property.Footnote 55 Investment treaties do not alter this situation. In fact, most explicitly reaffirm States’ right to expropriate. They do, however, define the conditions which must be met by expropriatory action before it will comply with States’ international obligations. The standard conditions of lawful expropriation include the existence of a public purpose, non-discrimination, due process and ‘prompt, adequate and effective compensation’Footnote 56 (or similar wording having the same meaning).Footnote 57 The last condition is typically accompanied by a determination of the valuation date and applicable interest rate.Footnote 58

The most essential element in defining compensation – adequate – is linked with the objective value of the expropriated investment, which is equated with its ‘fair market value’.Footnote 59 The fair market value is understood as reflecting ‘the price at which a willing buyer would buy, and a willing seller would sell, no party being under any type of duress and both parties having good information about all relevant circumstances involved in the purchase’.Footnote 60 ‘Effective’ means that compensation must be ‘fully realizable’, whilst ‘prompt’ means ‘paid without delay’.Footnote 61

The above is not, however, a remedy for an internationally wrongful act.Footnote 62 The applicable legal principles differ between compensation, as one of the conditions of lawful expropriation, and compensation, as a remedy for unlawful expropriation.Footnote 63

In this context, a question arises whether a failure to fulfil this condition of lawful expropriation (ie the condition of paying ‘prompt, adequate and effective compensation’) by itself means that the expropriation becomes unlawful. Many tribunals have ruled in favour of this approach.Footnote 64 Others have decided that non-fulfilment of the compensation prerequisite does not, by itself, render the expropriation unlawful.Footnote 65 However, the latter cases concerned situations where the respondent States accepted their obligation to pay compensation, but the parties were unable to agree on the amounts due. The Tribunal in Tidewater v Venezuela found that this was ‘not a case where the State took assets without any offer of compensation. The record does not demonstrate a refusal on the part of the State to pay compensation. Rather, it discloses that the Parties were unable to agree on the basis or the process by which such compensation would be calculated and paid’.Footnote 66 Similarly, in Venezuela Holdings v Venezuela the negotiations on compensation took place and the respondent State ‘made proposals during those negotiations’.Footnote 67 This allows the conclusion that expropriation should be considered as legal if all other conditions have been met (aside from the payment of compensation) and the respondent State has made ‘a good faith effort to comply with the compensation requirement’ (even if unsuccessfully).Footnote 68 If, on the other hand, the respondent State declines to pay any compensation at all, the failure to fulfil this condition suffices to consider the expropriation unlawful. In line with the above, any indirect expropriation would always amount to unlawful expropriation, as it is not compensated and involves no attempt to negotiate the amount of compensation payable.

6 Remedies Available for Treaty Breaches

As noted above, compensation for lawful expropriation is linked with the ‘fair market value’ of the expropriated object, typically with the valuation date set immediately prior to expropriation and increased by the applicable interest rate. If an expropriation does not meet the conditions of being lawful, it should not have taken place at all. In such a situation, reparation should ‘wipe out’ all of its consequences. The principle of full reparation rooted in customary international law does not provide any guidelines on how to determine the financial situation of the victim of a treaty breach.Footnote 69

The aim is to put the claimant in the same situation as it would have been ‘but for’ the breach. In the first place, this may justify restitution in kind, as noted above. In the context of compensation, there are two vital differences between the compensation calculated as a condition for lawful expropriation and the compensation calculated as a remedy for unlawful expropriation. These relate to: (i) the date of valuation and (ii) the possibility to use ex post information during the calculation.Footnote 70

As noted earlier, compensation for lawful expropriation is typically calculated on the basis of the fair market value shortly prior to the time at which the asset was taken. Calculating compensation for unlawful expropriation offers more flexibility. It allows the same date to be chosen as would apply in the case of lawful expropriation (ie immediately prior to the taking), but it offers an alternative – ie the date of the award.Footnote 71 This is in line with the principle of putting the claimants in the situation they would have been in ‘but for’ the breach. The PCIJ itself noted in the Chorzów Factory judgment that compensation

is not necessarily limited to the value of the undertaking at the moment of dispossession, plus interest to the day of payment. This limitation would only be admissible if the Polish Government had had the right to expropriate, and if its wrongful act consisted merely in not having paid to the two Companies the just price of what was expropriated.Footnote 72

In the words of the US–Iran Claims Tribunal in Phillips Petroleum v Iran, the difference is – apart from restitution – ‘whether compensation can be awarded for any increase in the value of the property between the date of the taking and the date of the judicial or arbitral decision awarding compensation’.Footnote 73

Another difference is the possibility to make use of ex post information – ie information which became available only after the expropriation took place. In the case of lawful expropriations, calculations are based on data available at the moment just prior to the taking, which reflects ‘the price at which a willing buyer would buy, and a willing seller would sell’ with the knowledge they would have actually had on the valuation date.Footnote 74 Customary international law allows a different approach – ie relying on any available information, including ex post knowledge.Footnote 75 The ‘only subsequent known factors relevant to value which are not to be relied on are those attributable to the illegality itself’.Footnote 76

These differences can result in higher amounts of compensation when compared to compensation for lawful expropriation. As was summarised by the Tribunal in Quiborax v Bolivia: ‘This is easily explained by a reference to restitution: damages stand in lieu of restitution which would take place just following the award or judgment. It is also easy to understand if one keeps in mind that what must be repaired is the actual harm done, as opposed to the value of the asset when taken.’Footnote 77 This may become relevant in practice. For example, with respect to unlawfully taking a mining concession, it would not be surprising if, at the moment of taking, the deposit estimations suggest that a specific amount of mineral resource exists, but subsequently the deposit turns out to be larger, thereby increasing the amount of due compensation.

At the same time, these differences should not result in a lower compensation for unlawful expropriation than for lawful expropriation. It is possible for an expropriated investment to lose its value between the expropriation date and the date of the award. If this occurs, compensation for lawful and unlawful expropriation should be calculated on the same basis, ie based on the value of the asset at the time of expropriation, plus interest.Footnote 78 This is in line with customary international law, which provides that restitution – if possible – should be awarded together with compensation for any loss which is not covered by restitution. If compensation is the only remedy available, the claimant is entitled to compensation ‘in the amount of the asset’s higher value’ between the expropriation date and the date of the award. This is because the State which violated international law bears ‘the risk of unanticipated events decreasing the value of an expropriated asset over that time period’, not the individual who suffered the loss.Footnote 79

An important differentiation in this context arises with respect to a division between unlawful expropriation and other treaty breaches. It goes without saying that the Chorzów Factory principle finds application to all violations of investment treaties’ provisions, not solely unlawful expropriation.Footnote 80

In this context, restitution could play a more important role in the future.Footnote 81 In terms of compensation, if violations of multiple standards are found, typically, tribunals consider it sufficient to calculate compensation for unlawful expropriation as covering the whole loss suffered.Footnote 82 This is in line with the Chorzów Factory principle, which requires that no overcompensation takes place.Footnote 83 It results from a pragmatic approach: typically, other breaches would result in a compensation award of equal or less value than the compensation due in the case of unlawful expropriation.Footnote 84

7 Methodologies of Calculating Compensation in the Light of the Chorzów Factory Principle

Within the legal framework discussed above, when calculating compensation tribunals must decide which methodology to apply. In each case, the choice of methodology is fact dependent. In the words of the Tribunal in Antin v Spain: ‘there are no right or wrong valuation methods, but different methods that are appropriate depending on the specific circumstances of the case’.Footnote 85 Whichever methodology is applied, typically, compensation ‘cannot be determined with mechanical precision’.Footnote 86 What matters is that the arbitrators are comfortable that the methodology applied is not ‘speculative’.Footnote 87 Reluctance towards a speculative outcome is one of the key factors which influences arbitrators when choosing the methodology for calculating compensation.

Keeping in mind the above, it is possible to make a few general comments on the methodologies typically available in investor-State arbitrations. From a theoretical perspective, they can be divided into two classifications: (i) backward-looking and (ii) forward-looking.Footnote 88

Probably the most common backward-looking methodology considers the amounts actually invested (‘sunk costs’) and seeks to return this amount to the investor. The advantage of this methodology is that the outcome is based on actual figures, which avoids any speculation.Footnote 89 The disadvantage is that it does not compensate for lost profits.Footnote 90 As such, it does not place the claimant in a situation in which it would have been ‘but for’ the treaty breach, as required by customary international law. No reasonable investor decides to undertake an investment with the sole purpose of receiving back the amount it originally invested after a period of time.

This shortcoming is partially cured by ordering pre-award interest.Footnote 91 This is envisaged by Art. 38 of the ILC Articles, which states that interest may be ‘necessary in order to ensure full reparation’.Footnote 92 Pre-award interest ‘should compensate a claimant for the deprivation of money owed to it between the date of the harm suffered and the award’.Footnote 93 The economic rationale behind interest is to reflect the ‘cost of money that a lender is willing to be paid to part with his money for a given period of time’.Footnote 94 Pre-award interest, therefore, brings ‘past losses […] to present value’ and compensates for loss stemming from the fact that the investors were not ‘in possession of the funds’ to which they were entitled and they had ‘either to borrow funds at a cost or were deprived of the opportunity of investing these funds at a profit’.Footnote 95 As such, it reflects the time value of money and the decreasing purchasing power of money over time. It does not compensate investors for the fact that they did not obtain a profit from the investment.Footnote 96

For the above reason, ‘sunk costs’ can be used as a ‘reality check’ of the outcome reached by applying other methodologies.Footnote 97 They can serve as the primary methodology only if forward-looking ones are unavailable in a particular case. The two most common forward-looking methodologies are: (i) income based and (ii) market based.Footnote 98

Income-based methodology, also known as the Discounted Cash Flow (DCF) method, calculates the present value of an investment’s anticipated future cash-flows during its useful life.Footnote 99 As such, it provides for a fair market value of a ‘going concern’.Footnote 100 It aims at compensating lost profits which the investment was supposed to generate, but was unable to because of the treaty breach.Footnote 101 Application of this method requires the ability to forecast future earnings.

Market-based methodology determines the value of an investment by comparing it to similar investments traded on the open market. Whilst DCF ‘computes the present value of the business’s future earnings’ directly, the market-based approach does so indirectly ‘because it incorporates market values of comparable businesses’.Footnote 102 Application of this method requires the existence of comparable transactions (concerning similar projects or companies, if an investment is implemented through a special purpose vehicle having one asset).Footnote 103

Forward-looking methods are commonly applied in business reality, outside the context of litigation.Footnote 104 For example, they are recognised in industry standards for valuating mineral properties.Footnote 105 They are based on market indicators. Thus, even though they represent a degree of subjectivity and uncertainty, this in itself should not preclude their application.Footnote 106

8 The Curious Case of the Natural Resources Sector

Investor-State arbitration case law reveals the reluctance of arbitral tribunals to apply forward-looking valuation methods to early-stage projects, particularly those which have not yet started to generate any income. With respect to such projects tribunals tend to consider the DCF method as ‘too speculative and uncertain’,Footnote 107 ‘unattractive and speculative’,Footnote 108 requiring ‘too many unsubstantiated assumptions’ and being ‘overly speculative’,Footnote 109 requiring an investment to be ‘a going concern with a proven record of profitability’.Footnote 110 The tendency with respect to comparable transactions is to consider them as ‘not sufficiently comparable’Footnote 111 or to find that they do not ‘support a clear conclusion’ regarding comparability.Footnote 112 Instead, tribunals prefer to look at the amounts actually invested (‘sunk costs’)Footnote 113 or other backward-looking methods, such as offers actually received in the past to acquire the relevant investment.Footnote 114

In cases where tribunals have decided not to apply the DCF method to early-stage mining projects, they did not preclude the use of the method per se, but merely decided that it was not applicable to the facts of the given case.Footnote 115 Rightly so, as the methodology itself is in line with the Chorzów Factory principle.

There are examples to show that the DCF method can also be applied in disputes concerning early-stage mining projects. In Tethyan v Pakistan case, the Tribunal awarded compensation based on a ‘modern DCF’. It observed that, among other matters,

the question whether a DCF method (or a similar income-based valuation methodology) can be applied to value a project which has not yet become operational depends strongly on the circumstances of the individual case. The first key question is whether, based on the evidence before it, the Tribunal is convinced that in the absence of Respondent’s breaches, the project would have become operational and would also have become profitable. The second key question is whether the Tribunal is convinced that it can, with reasonable confidence, determine the amount of these profits based on the inputs provided by the Parties’ experts for this calculation […].Footnote 116

Both prerequisites were met in the case. The Tribunal in Crystallex v Venezuela observed, in the context of a gold mine project which had not commenced production, that:

the Claimant has established the fact of future profitability, as it had completed the exploration phase, the size of the deposits had been established, the value can be determined based on market prices, and the costs are well known in the industry and can be estimated with a sufficient degree of certainty. […] In this case only forward-looking methodologies aimed at calculating lost profits are appropriate in order to determine the fair market value of Crystallex’s investment.Footnote 117

This is in line with standard industry practices such as CIMVal Standards and Guidelines 2003. Also, the Tribunal in Gold Reserve v Venezuela, where the experts for both parties used the DCF method, applied it to non-production property.Footnote 118

This case law reveals that the DCF method can indeed be applied to early-stage mining projects.Footnote 119 Relevant factors in the fact-assessment include whether a sufficient degree of certainty has been achieved regarding projections of future profitability (such as knowledge of the size of the mineral deposit,Footnote 120 predictability of price fluctuations strengthened by resource typeFootnote 121 and reliable mining cashflow analysis prepared prior to the dispute having arisen),Footnote 122 combined with the claimant’s standing (such as a historical record of financial performance,Footnote 123 whether it has a demonstrated commitment and capacity – both financial and organisational – to progress to the production stage).Footnote 124

These observations find support in the Spanish saga case law, concerning investments in the renewable energy sector (which is considered to fall within the field of natural resources).Footnote 125 In most of these cases, when tribunals found that the underlying investment treaty had been infringed, they decided to apply the DCF method.Footnote 126 The tribunals did not consider it too speculative. The lifetime of the investments (power plants) was foreseeable. This can be compared to the expected lifetime of a mine and the production period of a particular deposit. The commodity price (electricity) was foreseeable. This can be compared to the commodity price of natural resources such as gold, copper or gas.Footnote 127 Developing projects in both fields requires large, upfront investments.Footnote 128

In the renewable energy sector, an important element allowing for DCF calculations was the highly regulated nature of the industry, minimising the expected fluctuations of future cash flows. In the words of the Tribunal in Novenergia v Spain, the DCF method ‘is considered particularly suitable for valuating income-streams that are regulated (as opposed to unregulated business that is more exposed to market fluctuations)’.Footnote 129 Thus, the DCF method was applied not only to ‘going concerns’, but also to investments which began generating income shortly prior to the respondent’s regulatory changes, which violated the investment treaty.Footnote 130 This is a major difference between mining and renewable energy disputes. Whereas mining disputes also concern a highly-regulated industry, this factor is not related to State subsidies and, therefore, has limited impact on future cash flows.

9 Conclusions

The Chorzów Factory principle reflects customary international law governing remedies for treaty breaches. As such, it applies to violations of international investment treaties. It entitles claimants in investor-State arbitrations to seek restitution prior to compensation or satisfaction.

Claimants have a right to choose the remedy they wish to seek. If claimants seek restitution, tribunals have the power to award it, unless this is explicitly precluded by the underlying treaty or is impossible (or at least inadequate) due to the facts of a particular case. Restitution was considered as inadequate in the Spanish saga cases, which concerned treaty violations resulting from the adoption of new laws and regulations. Ordering restitution in this context was considered as potentially limiting State sovereignty. Tribunals can award restitution with the possibility to pay compensation in lieu of restitution, to overcome similar concerns in cases concerning individually applied measures.

A declaratory-only award is considered as a ‘paper victory’ and the de facto loss of the case, rather than as having obtained satisfaction, a meaningful form of reparation. Such an award is disproportionate when compared to the costs of arbitral proceedings and its significance is undermined by the confidentiality of the bulk of investor-State arbitral awards.

In practice, claimants rarely consider any remedy other than compensation. The Chorzów Factory principle seems to be used by claimants as a shortcut to proceed to calculating compensation. There is nothing reproachable in this, and the precise manner in which claims are framed is binding on tribunals, which cannot go beyond the remedies sought by the claimants. This explains, however, the reasons why remedies other than compensation – restitution and satisfaction, available under customary international law – are only occasionally considered in investor-State arbitrations.

With respect to compensation, differences exist between compensation for lawful expropriation (compensation is a prerequisite of any lawful expropriation) and compensation as a remedy for unlawful expropriation. The latter can be higher, as it can be calculated as of the date of the award and it can make use of ex post information. This understanding of the customary international law governing compensation appears to be already settled in investor-State arbitral case law.

There is no infallible approach to choosing the methodology for calculating compensation for treaty breaches. However, the choice of forward-looking (income-based) methods is generally available in cases concerning all sectors of the economy, including in disputes concerning early-stage mining projects and renewable energy power plants. There are identifiable patterns in the case law, showing that (i) in principle, arbitral tribunals are reluctant to apply forward-looking valuation methods to early-stage projects, particularly those which have not begun to generate any income, but (ii) if a number of factual elements exist, this initial reluctance can be overturned. This U-turn is easier in renewable energy disputes than in mining disputes, because the highly-regulated nature of the renewable energy industry is closely related to State subsidies, which allow the expected fluctuations of future cash flows to be minimised.

13 A TWAIL Engagement with Customary International Investment Law Some Strategies for Interpretation

Nina Mileva Footnote *
1 Introduction

The intellectual movement of Third World Approaches to International Law (TWAIL) is now a well-established strand of critical thought within the international legal discourse. At its core, TWAIL unveils the hierarchical nature of the international legal system and undertakes critical investigations which unearth power relationships within the international community.Footnote 1 While nowadays some may argue that the term TWAIL or the reference to third world States is anachronistic, it is important to understand that TWAIL is not a reference to a particular geographical constellation in international law. This is all the more so if we consider that States traditionally grouped under the ‘third world’ heading have since changed the political, economic or social traits that originally earned them this categorisation.Footnote 2 Rather, TWAIL represents a perspective which is ‘critical of the universalizing mission and occidental authority of Eurocentric international legal scholarship and practice’,Footnote 3 and is not necessarily tied to a geographical Statist space. This reflects first the non-homogeneous ideological make-up of States traditionally considered as belonging to the third world, as well as the fact that nowadays one may often find the wretched and the dispossessed among societies traditionally considered to be part of the Global North. Thus, members of the TWAIL intellectual movement may not always share a geographical space and yet be united in ‘a sensibility and a political orientation’.Footnote 4

Historically, there have been different ways that TWAIL scholars have chosen to engage with international law, varying from complete denunciations of the system to more constructive attempts to deploy existing legal structures with a view to enacting change.Footnote 5 In this chapter, I will sketch out a discussion of customary international law (CIL) interpretation as an example of constructive engagement with international investment law (IIL) from a TWAIL perspective. I will build on the existing TWAIL scholarship, which has engaged in criticism of IIL as a regime and of the theory of CIL as a source of international law (Section 2). Having outlined the existing critique, I will turn to a discussion of CIL interpretation as a potential tool for reconciling some of the harsh, but merited, criticism coming from the TWAIL perspective with a continued engagement with and reliance on international (investment) law.

First, relying on the example of the minimum standard of treatment of aliens (MST) – one of the oldest customary rules of the international investment regime – I will argue that interpretation plays a crucial role in the construction of customary rules and is central to their evolution and continued existence (Section 3). Having established this, I will move to my final argument as to how this awareness of the function of interpretation in CIL can help us constructively engage with IIL from a TWAIL perspective (Section 4). Here, I will outline strategies for interpretation which may be deployed from the TWAIL perspective in order to address the perceived problems in the regime of IIL. Put differently, I will argue that the awareness of what interpretation is and how it functions in CIL opens up new avenues for addressing problems within both particular customary rules and, more generally, international (investment) law. It is at the stage of interpretation of customary rules that particular criticism can be raised and potentially resolved. In this sense, interpretation is a tool that may be utilised to address and potentially improve upon problematic rationales underlying the rule or the larger system in which it operates. While this presents great emancipatory potential with regard to argumentative strategies that may be developed, it also has its limitations. An evaluation of the limitations of the argument as well as some summary observations are thus addressed in the conclusion (Section 5).

2 The Criticism of Customary International Investment Law from the TWAIL Perspective

It is not surprising to observe that TWAIL scholarship is very critical of the regime of IIL. The TWAIL intellectual tradition in international law originates from decolonisation. It is a school of thought which perceives the international legal system as one built on power disparity, exploitation, and unequal relations. On this understanding, international law as a system reflects the interests of powerful States, and these interests are deployed through various legal doctrines including the doctrine of CIL. Here CIL is considered problematic both generally as a category in the sources doctrine,Footnote 6 and more specifically on the level of individual customary rules.Footnote 7 These problems of CIL are set in the wider historical context which links the development of international law to the colonial encounter between European States and the violently colonised non-European world.Footnote 8 It is thus not surprising to find particularly strong criticism among TWAIL scholars aimed at the system of IIL, and the (customary) rules contained therein.Footnote 9

Historically, one of the strongest concerted TWAIL efforts at both criticising and reforming the international economic legal order was the New International Economic Order (NIEO).Footnote 10 This was an initiative of Third World States aided by TWAIL scholars aimed at reforming regimes such as the IIL via a concentrated legislative effort at the United Nations General Assembly. The initiative concerned a reformation of key areas such as foreign direct investment, the rules of nationalisation and expropriation, the criteria applied to compensation, and the fora for dispute settlement in this area.Footnote 11 While highly ambitious, this initiative was met with little success. Pushback from Western States as well as various complex forms of financial domination deployed in the international system undermined the reformative effort, and the battle for a NIEO was largely lost.Footnote 12 The limited success of the NIEO has spurred what some have called a second generationFootnote 13 of TWAIL scholars, more disenchanted with international law, and focused on uncovering its continuously hegemonic traits. It is among this scholarship that much of the criticism of the contemporary IIL system can be found.

A central trait of this criticism revolves around the underlying rationale of IIL. The assumption upon which IIL is constructed is that foreign investment is so essential to economic development that its operation must be facilitated by near absolute protection of the foreign investment/investor.Footnote 14 This assumption, however, remains contested among critical scholars, as case studies demonstrate that foreign investment can be hugely exploitative and damaging to host economies.Footnote 15 This has led Sornarajah to observe that while the potential of foreign investment to aid development must be recognised, the absolute protection of investment in international law enables ‘the instrumentalism of free market fundamentalism’ to fragment international law ‘without paying heed to prescriptions of law relating to the environment, human rights or labour standards’.Footnote 16 Similarly, Odumosu has demonstrated that in the context of investment dispute settlement, this overwhelming focus on investment protection has all but erased legitimate grievances of local populations affected by investments, and also significantly restricted the extent to which host States might balance the protection of foreign investment with the protection of other local interests.Footnote 17

The criticism of the underlying rationale of IIL often goes hand in hand with a critique of its historical origin, as well that of specific customary rules operating in the system. For instance, Kelly traces the customary MST to early natural law doctrines on the freedom of commerce and the rights to hospitality and sociability of Vittoria and Grotius, developed to legitimise the extension of the European colonial empires and the exploitation of peoples and resources encountered in the process.Footnote 18 Similarly, Anghie unpacks the relationship between State responsibility and the customary MST to demonstrate that Western States re-established colonial relationships of power with former colonies through what was ostensibly neutral international law.Footnote 19 Thus, while the formal process of decolonisation got rid of colonial empires, legal doctrines formed in the colonial period survive today and perpetuate problematic logics in the contemporary context of international law. On this point, Pahuja persuasively demonstrates that in moments when the Third World attempted to dispute existing structures in international law (such as with the NIEO), this was met with a response by the First World, which claimed the universality of values so as to discredit attempted alternatives.Footnote 20

A related criticism here is the structure of dispute settlement inIIL. Scholars have pointed out the asymmetry inherent in the fact that while foreign investors may bring suit against host States, the opposite is not true.Footnote 21 Moreover, the rationale inherent in many BITs, trade agreements, and customary rules automatically puts host States on the defensive should there be an attempt to limit foreign investment in favour of the protection of local environment or peoples.Footnote 22 The obvious counter-argument here is that States willingly admit foreign investment by signing BITs or trade agreements, thereby subjecting themselves also to potential dispute settlement and the application of (customary) investment law. However, this argument potentially neglects the larger socio-economic context in which this ‘willingness’ takes place. Moreover, often political elites in States which conclude foreign investment agreements do not, in fact, represent or purport to protect the rights of some local populations, and thus, the asymmetry grows. Investment dispute settlement treats the State as a unitary entity, and as such, the interests of different local communities which might be differently affected by a particular foreign investment project are all subsumed under it.Footnote 23

Having briefly outlined the lines of criticism levelled at customary IIL from the TWAIL perspective, I now turn to a discussion of CIL interpretation as the next step in the argument.

3 The Interpretation of Customary International Investment Law

This section first outlines more generally the nature and role of interpretation in the context of customary international law, before turning to the more concrete example of the customary MST as an illustration of these more general observations.

3.1 What Constitutes Interpretation of Customary International Law

Legal interpretation is the process of determining the scope and content of legal rules. It can be distinguished from rule-identification, which is the act of establishing whether a legal rule exists. Thus, interpretation is the process of discerning or clarifying the meaning of an existing legal rule, and takes place when a general rule is applied to particular facts.

CIL interpretation is the process that takes place after a customary rule has been identified. Once a rule of CIL is identified for the first time through an assessment of State practice and opinio juris, its existence is not restricted to the moment where it was identified for the first time; rather it is a continuous one. When the same rule is invoked in subsequent cases before the same or a different judicial body, the judicial body does not usually go into the exercise of re-establishing that the rule in question is a customary one by reassessing State practice and opinio juris.Footnote 24 Instead, the rule is interpreted within the given legal and factual context of the new case at hand. Moreover, outside of the dispute-settlement context, a customary rule does not only exist in the isolated moments when it is identified for the purposes of a particular case. Rather, its existence in the complex of international legal relations is also a continuous one. In this sense, interpretation allows us to account for the continued existence and operation of a customary rule. Within the timeline of existence of a CIL rule, interpretation takes place after the periods of formation and identification of the rule.Footnote 25 Identification yields a general rule of CIL, based on an inductive analysis of State practice and opinio juris.Footnote 26 It is important to note that a form of interpretive reasoning may also take place at this stage, in the sense of assessment of the relevant practice and opinio juris. The identification exercise includes choices in the selection of certain custom-formative practices over others in order to infer the general rule, as well as the choices in how we describe these practices which lead to the identification of the rule.Footnote 27 The reasoning employed in these choices and descriptions is by necessity interpretative. However, this is not an interpretation of a customary rule because this rule has not been confirmed to exist yet. Rather, what happens at the stage of identification is an evaluation of the evidence of State practice and opinio juris in order to assess whether they qualify for the purposes of establishing a customary rule and whether they in fact point to the existence of a customary rule.Footnote 28 Some scholars do employ the term ‘interpretation’ to also refer to the reasoning that takes place at the stage of identification.Footnote 29 However, a distinction must be maintained between what might be labeled as interpretation at the stage of identification and what is interpretation in the strict sense of an existing CIL rule. This is because these two operations are substantively different with respect to both their content and their outcome. The reasoning employed at identification is concerned with questions about the relevance and weight to be given to evidence of State practice and opinio juris, and the outcome of this reasoning is a binary one – a CIL rule is either determined to exist or it is not. The reasoning employed in interpretation is concerned with the determination of the content of the CIL rule and how this rule applies to the case at hand, and this reasoning may have a variety of outcomes depending on the rule being interpreted and the legal and factual circumstances it is being interpreted in. It is only by distinguishing these two operations that we may adequately capture the fact that the interpretation manifests differently in the context of CIL, that it is subject to a different methodology than that of identification, and it performs specific functions.

A related consideration in this context is who interprets. Formally, international law does not allocate interpretive authority with a single entity. Depending on the circumstances, interpretive authority may lie with a court, a State, or even a non-governmental entity.Footnote 30 All these actors together form the epistemic community of international law, and as such contribute broadly to the way legal rules are interpreted.Footnote 31 Nevertheless, judicial interpretation holds a prominent role in international law.Footnote 32 In the subsequent discussion I focus on judicial interpretation for two reasons. First, because in the practice of international law, questions of interpretation tend to arise in the context of disputes and be formulated with a judge or arbitrator in mind.Footnote 33 Put differently, the bulk of the judicial role in international law consists of interpretation.Footnote 34 In this regard, and without prejudice to the interpretation of CIL by other actors, examples of CIL interpretation are most likely to be found in the jurisprudence of courts and tribunals. Second, because in international law judicial decisions possess what has aptly been described as a ‘centrifugal normative force’ – other international legal actors tend to follow judicial reasoning, and judicial decisions can be ‘substantively constitutive’ of international law.Footnote 35 ‘That normative effect is exacerbated when dealing with unwritten sources of law, in particular customary international law […]: there is no balancing between the text, its authors, and the interpreter in such situations, and the certainty of judicial reasoning holds and intrinsic appeal’.Footnote 36

An examination of jurisprudence dealing with the interpretation of CIL indicates that interpretation performs two important functions in the continued existence of customary rules – a constructive/concretising function and an evolutive function.Footnote 37 The constructive/concretising function refers to the fact that interpretation is the process through which the content of general customary rules is fleshed out and specified. Customary rules are often formulated in broad terms, and require precisely the act of interpretation to arrive at more concrete findings of their content.Footnote 38 In this sense, it is through interpretation that we arrive at more specific sub-elements of a general customary rule, or more specific sub-obligations that flow from it. Merkouris also refers to this as the collapsing function of interpretation.Footnote 39 The evolutive function of interpretation refers to the fact that interpretation is crucial in the continued existence of CIL rules, and their adaptation to new developments of fact or law. Contrary to some views, customary rules are not static legal rules which have no place in modern legal systems.Footnote 40 Rather, customary rules are by their nature dynamic because they move together with the community from whose conduct they emerge. As such, they require interpretation in order to be able to respond to emerging new circumstances.Footnote 41 For an illustration of these two functions relevant to our present discussion, let us briefly consider the example of the customary MST.

3.2 The Interpretation of the Customary MST and the Functions of CIL Interpretation

The customary status of MST is uncontested, and support for this may be found widely among States, tribunals, and scholarly writings. What is, however, in question is its precise content.Footnote 42 As argued above, customary rules necessarily come in a general format, and the MST is one among many examples which confirms this. This is certainly both a virtue and a vice of custom. The generality of customary rules makes them particularly fit to answer to a variety of circumstances, and thus regulate a variety of situations that may arise in international law. In a scenario where multiple legal regimes might interact or bind different actors differently, general customary rules present a least common denominator of legal obligation. In the context of the MST, its customary status means that obligations flowing from it apply to all States, including those that may not have entered into any bilateral investment treaties (BITs), and may also be invoked by any foreign investor irrespective of whether or not their State of origin has entered into a BIT with the State where they’ve made an investment.Footnote 43 Moreover, in new legal situations not covered by conventional rules, customary law may prove a source of regulation that can be extended by analogy.Footnote 44 This is arguably what indeed happened with the customary MST, which had originally broadly applied to the treatment of aliens and was later also extended to the property of aliens as well as their investments. At the same time, the generality of customary rules also leads to vagueness, and this is a challenge to the legal certainty and predictability that actors might desire in particular legal scenarios or in international law more generally. The customary MST has indeed been criticised for its vagueness, its inability to provide clear standards for behaviour, and even its ‘normative weakness’.Footnote 45

Historically, the formulation of the MST is traced back to a 1910 address by the American Secretary of State, Elihu Root, who expressed the view that an international standard is necessary in order to guarantee appropriate treatment by host countries to the nationals of another country.Footnote 46 Root’s formulation, however, was quite vague, and did not in fact provide for a more concrete content of the standard beyond a claim that such a standard existed and was recognised by civilised countries.Footnote 47 A more concrete expression of the content of the MST is ascribed to the US–Mexico Claims Commission in its Neer award.Footnote 48 Much like the formulation expressed by Secretary Root, however, the Neer award did not express the MST with the protection of foreign investments or property in view. Rather, it was concerned with the more specific scenario of alleged failure to investigate the murder of an alien, and the more general standard of denial of justice in the context of treatment of aliens.Footnote 49 Thus, while Neer is considered the classical starting point of MST, both States and tribunals have recognised that MST is not frozen in time to this formulation.Footnote 50 The shift from a more general standard of denial of justice to the more specific rationale of protection of foreign investment and property is not insignificant. As Paparinskis aptly demonstrates in his genealogy of the standard, in post-World War 2 discussions of the MST there is a marked ‘shift of the paradigm that the standard was meant to regulate’, including now a focus on property and the personality of the foreign investor.Footnote 51 This focus on the protection of property rights and protection of foreign investment is the primary area of application of the MST today.Footnote 52

TWAIL scholarship has offered its own take on why this shift occurred.Footnote 53 What we are more concerned with for the purposes of this section is how these changes in perspective were operationalised in the standard by means of interpretation. As the upcoming discussion will demonstrate, while the customary MST was initially expressed in general terms, its content in the context of investment law has been made more concrete and specific through interpretation by various investment tribunals. Moreover, it is also through interpretation that the MST has evolved over time.

Early mentions of the MST as a customary rule relevant in the context of investment protection can be found in the reasoning of the ICJ in the ELSI case. Here, the court acknowledged that the relevant treaty standard of treatment ‘must conform to the minimum international standard’,Footnote 54 and found that this minimum standard includes the element of ‘denial of procedural justice’.Footnote 55 The reasoning of the ICJ with regard to the denial of procedural justice as an element of the customary MST has been referenced by various investment tribunals similarly faced with the need to specify the content of the general customary standard. For instance, in its award in respect of damages, the Pope and Talbot Tribunal relied on the reasoning in ELSI when seeking to define the arbitrariness requisite for a finding of denial of justice as part of the MST.Footnote 56 In Mondev International Ltd, this reference was part of a broader interpretation of the customary MST. Here, the Tribunal began by decoupling the customary MST in the context of investment protection from the minimum standard broadly outlined in Neer.Footnote 57 It then proceeded to interpret the customary MST evolutively so as to account for changes of law that have taken place in the broader legal environment in which the rule operates.Footnote 58 While this may, at first glance, seem expansive, it is interesting to note that the Tribunal also acknowledged the limitations of its interpretive power, and professed to remain within the limits posed by the customary MST.Footnote 59 After examining the relevant legal developments in the period since Neer, the Mondev Tribunal came to the conclusion that under the customary MST investments are entitled to fair and equitable treatment and full protection and security.Footnote 60 Having outlined the content of the customary MST in this way, the Tribunal went on to examine the applicable standard of denial of justice which would render treatment unfair or inequitable. Here it relied, among other, on the reasoning of the ICJ with respect to the nature of arbitrariness as a denial of justice, and accepted the ICJ definition of arbitrary conduct ‘as that which displays a willful disregard of due process of law, … which shocks, or at least surprises, a sense of judicial propriety’.Footnote 61 In addition to the ICJ’s reasoning in ELSI, the Mondev Tribunal also relied on the Azinian Tribunal for an even more detailed interpretation of denial of justice, thus also accepting into its definition elements such as refusal to entertain a suit, undue delay, inadequate administration of justice and malicious misapplication of the law.Footnote 62

I flag this cross-reference to the reasoning of other tribunals because it is illustrative of the role of judicial interpretation in the construction of both customary rules more generally and the customary MST more specifically. In light of the general nature of CIL, it is not at all surprising that courts will borrow from each other when interpreting rules in pari materia. What is noteworthy in this cross-referencing is that the interpretive reasoning does not remain limited to the particular case, but carries over to subsequent cases as well. It is attached to the rule beyond the context of the specific case in that it has specified the content which is now considered to be an expression of the rule. In this sense, interpretation affects the content of the customary rule more generally as it exists continuously in international law. We may similarly observe this in the reasoning of the Loewen Group Inc Tribunal, which relied on the reasoning in Pope & Talbot, ELSI and Mondev to elucidate what would constitute arbitrariness amounting to a denial of justice in breach of the customary MST.Footnote 63 The constructive role of interpretation is illustrated perhaps most strongly by the reasoning of the Tribunal in Waste Management. Here, having surveyed the previous jurisprudence of a number of investment tribunals, the Waste Management Tribunal arrived at the following finding:

Taken together, the S.D. Myers, Mondev, ADF and Loewen cases suggest that the minimum standard of treatment of fair and equitable treatment is infringed by conduct attributable to the State and harmful to the claimant if the conduct is arbitrary, grossly unfair, unjust or idiosyncratic, is discriminatory and exposes the claimant to sectional or racial prejudice, or involves a lack of due process leading to an outcome which offends judicial propriety—as might be the case with a manifest failure of natural justice in judicial proceedings or a complete lack of transparency and candour in an administrative process. In applying this standard it is relevant that the treatment is in breach of representations made by the host State which were reasonably relied on by the claimant.Footnote 64

The Tribunal here comes up with a very specific definition of the customary MST as a set of concrete elements and obligations. I would argue that this kind of construction of the customary MST, as a general rule made up of various specific legal sub-obligations, is a product of interpretation. This is certainly not an entirely novel observation, as several authors have made similar claims as to the ‘umbrella-like’ character of MST.Footnote 65 Building on their observations, I would merely argue more specifically that it is through interpretation particularly that the content of the general customary MST was developed and concretised. Why this is important is because this act of concretisation through interpretation does not remain restricted to the case at hand, but carries over to reasoning in subsequent cases both before the same tribunal and others that might follow it. Thus, we may envisage a general customary rule in case A whose content gets concretised through interpretation to contain element A1, where that element is carried over to the subsequent case B. Should further concretisation through interpretation take place in case B, whereby the customary rule is found to also contain element B1, elements A1 and B1 would now carry over to subsequent case C, and so on. In this way, interpretation affects the content of general customary rules not only for purposes of one specific case but also throughout the continuous existence of that customary rule overall and generally in international law. That this transcends adjudication becomes evident when we consider that often States rely on earlier judicial reasoning to argue the content of customary rules in subsequent cases. Thus, this constructive function of interpretation finds its way into State practice as well, thereby penetrating the very process of custom-creation by States.Footnote 66

While this brief analysis of case law demonstrates how the customary MST has evolved and been constructed through judicial interpretation, this trend has not gone without criticism. For one, scholars have noted that this form of development of the standard through a case-by-case application is not coherent and may lead to discrepancies in the way the standard is applied and enforced.Footnote 67 Furthermore, scholars have criticised this expansion through interpretation for developing investment protection obligations which arguably do not flow from the customary standard or the conduct of States.Footnote 68 For instance, several awards have read into the standard a requirement for a stable and predictable regulatory environment owed to investors,Footnote 69 which does not necessarily flow from the customary MST.Footnote 70 Similarly, and relying on the conviction that the customary MST should be interpreted evolutively,Footnote 71 the Bilcon Tribunal also found that the standard requires a ‘fair opportunity for review’ to be extended to the investor,Footnote 72 which once again is not obvious from the customary MST. On this critical note, it has also been observed that in the context of NAFTA proceedings there is a conflation of the customary MST with the treaty standard enshrined in Article 1105 NAFTA.Footnote 73 Thus, tribunals often make interpretive findings concerning the customary MST by relying on the treaty standard and relevant rules for treaty interpretation, which is problematic.Footnote 74 Nevertheless, it has been observed that the content of the standard is likely to continue being ‘created through the dispute-settlement process’,Footnote 75 and no universal international codification or clarification effort seems imminent.Footnote 76 Bearing these observations in mind, let us now turn to a discussion of how these traits of interpretation in the context of CIL rules may be conducive to a TWAIL engagement with customary IIL.

4 A TWAIL Approach to the Interpretation of Customary International Investment Law

In outlining a potential TWAIL approach to the interpretation of customary international investment law, I join the chorus of critical scholars who have taken the proverbial good with the bad in attempting to devise critique without dismissing international law as a whole. This, I believe, reflects what Sundhya Pahuja has aptly named a ‘critical faith’ – maintaining faith in international law despite firmly comprehending its problematic complicity with power.Footnote 77 At the centre of such an engagement with international law lies the need to deconstruct international law’s claim to universality in order to trace problematic elements and potentially resolve them. This entails recognising ‘both the contingency of any value put forth as universal and the frame of reference supporting the universal claim’.Footnote 78 This I would argue is a task that can be achieved at the stage of interpretation. With this in mind, this section outlines three potential strategies which rely on the constructive and evolutive functions of interpretation in the context of CIL. These strategies represent modes of engagement with customary international investment law from the TWAIL perspective which rely on interpretation in order to draw out and address the problems inherent in the law, without dismissing the system as a whole. They represent what Georges Abi Saab has humorously dubbed ‘operating behind enemy lines’ – a mode of engagement with problematic aspects of international law premised on the understanding that it is better to attempt change from within than from outside.Footnote 79

One might question the value of engaging with international investment law from a TWAIL perspective in this ‘internal’ way. The benefit of this kind of engagement lies in the opportunity to engage familiar professional language that is intelligible to the broader ‘target audience’ (courts, lawyers, States, scholars). Moreover, it also lies in the power to speak and be heard that comes from remaining within an arena of discussion rather than abandoning it.Footnote 80 This type of TWAIL engagement with international law capitalises on the existing structures in order to deploy what might be considered a subversive argument aimed at the amelioration of perceived biases. At the same time, it is important to acknowledge that professionals participating in international legal argumentation have a responsibility of maintaining what has been dubbed a ‘methodological honesty’ in their development of arguments concerning the content and purpose of international legal rules. The persuasiveness of any legal argument depends upon maintaining the idea of international law as a formal system according to which answers to legal questions can be derived from sources and principles whose validity depends on the internal logic of the system.Footnote 81 In this sense, the interpretive strategies suggested below are not attempts to argue in bad faith or misrepresent existing legal rules. Rather, the objective is to explore avenues of argumentation that promote the interpretation of customary rules in a way that accounts for their historically problematic origin and promotes their re-construction in a manner consistent with contemporary developments and values in the broader system.

The interpretive strategies suggested below are informed, amongst others, by the regime bias approach (alternatively also called the regime bias critique) developed by TWAIL scholars engaged with the various legal regimes of international economic governance.Footnote 82 The regime bias approach is aimed at uncovering how rules of the legal regimes making up the international economic order are constructed in a way that disempowers particular members of the system, inconsistently with the ‘liberal promise of even-handedness’.Footnote 83 This approach looks particularly at the way rules of international trade, commerce, and investment are construed, and identifies a differential manner in which the rules are interpreted and applied when the interests of the Third World are at stake.Footnote 84 Some of the main insights of the regime bias approach include the observation that international law is not a neutral and objective set of rules but rather an instrument employed in the context of power relations, and the finding that international institutions may interpret and apply international law in ways that are systemically biased against Third World interests.Footnote 85 For instance, using the example of the Dabhol investment arbitration before the International Chamber of Commerce (ICC), Van Harten argues that the ICC construed its role broadly to include not only arbitration on the basis of the pertinent investment contract but also what was in effect a review of domestic regulatory choices and a disciplining of constituencies in the Third World.Footnote 86 While the main contribution of the regime bias approach is critical, scholars have also used its rationale to propose reform within the international investment regime. For example, Hippolyte advocates for Third World countries to develop their own BIT models, which would focus on modes of investment attuned to their particular concerns, or to establish alternative regional investment arbitration centres.Footnote 87 Similarly, Odumosu flags mechanisms within investment arbitration proceedings such as the amicus curiae brief or public interest arguments, which may be a way for subaltern voices to be heard and considered in the otherwise insular investment proceedings.Footnote 88

The regime bias approach is instructive because it demonstrates the inherent plasticity of legal rules, which becomes apparent at the stage of interpretation. It counters the image of a stable and neutral international investment law regime and reveals some of the biases which are woven into rules during the act of interpretation. Thus, the regime bias approach does not only shed light on certain problematic rationales operating in the investment law regime but also flags interpretation as a viable ‘entry point’ for TWAIL counter-arguments and resistance. Bearing in mind that throughout the analysis in this chapter I have focused on judicial interpretation and the function of interpretation in the dispute settlement context, the strategies sketched below are focused primarily on interpretation in dispute settlement and operate differently depending on one’s positionality in the process.Footnote 89 In this sense, they are also differentially suitable for different actors who might want to engage with international law from the TWAIL perspective.

The first possible strategy in the context of CIL interpretation is advancing evolutive interpretative claims which push for a reconsideration of the rule’s content in light of factual or legal changes in the broader normative environment in which the rule operates. Depending on the rule in question, this would entail different argumentative strategies. For instance, when advancing an evolutive interpretative claim for the customary MST, this type of engagement consists of answering two connected questions: (i) can an argument be made that there is a need to interpret the rule dynamically in order to capture a change in the legal environment in which the rule operates? and (ii) are there competing rationales that may be taken in consideration and affect the interpretation of the rule accordingly? In relation to the first question, in the context of the customary MST, it has been argued persuasively that given the generality of the rule the elements which form part of its content are inherently dynamic and as such require evolutive interpretation.Footnote 90 Claims for evolutive interpretation may thus persuasively be made any time it can be shown that there is a need to interpret the rule dynamically in order to capture a change in the relevant standards or normative environment in which the rule operates. Answering question two entails, as a first step, recognising and stating plainly the rationale that the customary MST is driven by. This rule is largely focused on the protection of foreign investment, premised in turn on the ideology of economic development. Recognising this enables us to situate the historical development of the rule and understand how it has come to be what it is today. Having done that, we are able to evaluate how the rule plays out in the modern context, and which claims regarding its evolution are likely to work. Are there competing rationales – such as, for instance, the protection of the environment or human rights – that may be taken into consideration and that affect the interpretation of the rule accordingly? These may be found in other regimes as relevant treaty rules applicable between the parties, or in competing customary rules which have developed later than the customary MST and afford protection to, for instance, the environment or indigenous peoples. Interpretation entails, amongst other things, a balancing exercise,Footnote 91 and as such, it is capable of striking a balance between the rationale of economic development and these competing interests and competing rationales.

In the context of this strategy of engagement, interpretation functions as a sort of controlled ‘arguing space’ wherein competing argumentative strategies are deployed. This strategy is suited to TWAIL advocates and practitioners participating in relevant litigation. The limits here are of course the forum in which one attempts to advance evolutive interpretative claims, as well as the instructions of the party one is representing. For example, with respect to the limitation posed by the forum, it has been observed that certain formats of investment arbitration, such as ICSID arbitration, are inherently tilted in favour of the protection of foreign investors.Footnote 92 Thus, attempting to argue for evolutive interpretation, which balances the protection of investors with the protection of say the environment or indigenous groups, may not always be successful. With respect to the limitation posed by the party one is representing, it has been observed that the arguments deployed by, for instance, counsel representing States are limited in scope and content by the previous consultations and instructions of their client.Footnote 93 In this regard, any TWAIL arguments advanced by counsel on behalf of a State would be limited accordingly. Another relevant consideration here is that sometimes strategic engagement with litigation in this way may lead to adverse effects if the proposed interpretation is not accepted by courts.Footnote 94 Thus, for instance, an unsuccessful argument for evolutive interpretation may lead to a consolidation of the undesirable content of the rule.

An alternative to this strategy would be the strategy of arguing for a restrictive interpretation of a CIL rule. In the context of the customary MST, this would entail arguing for a stringent customary standard of treatment which has a high threshold of breach. This may involve similar argumentative strategies to the ones described above, only deployed in the ‘opposite direction’. More specifically, it may involve argumentative strategies which hark back to the older Neer standard and early investment arbitration which maintained it, arguing for a limitation of the customary standard to the high threshold described therein. These argumentative strategies may rely on exo-legal findings which show that expanding investment protection in the past has been to the detriment of local communities, and has potentially violated standards of environmental protection, or human and labour rights.Footnote 95 In this context, they may argue that a stringent customary standard, coupled with a balancing exercise, which considers rationales such as public policy or the protection of the local environment or communities, yields a narrow interpretation of the customary MST and the rights and protections extended to the investor. Alternatively, they may rely on a doctrinal positivist argument arguing that the expansion of the customary MST through interpretation is illegitimate and inconsistent with State practice. In this regard, it has been argued, for instance, that arguments which attempt to draw a uniform standard from widespread investment treaties as a form of State practice are unsubstantiated because while these treaties are many in number, their content as to the treatment of investors is varied and fails the uniformity requirement for CIL.Footnote 96 This strategy may be particularly fit for TWAIL advocates or governmental advisors who are representing or advising States.

A final strategy in the context of CIL interpretation is what I would call ‘interpreting against the grain’. This strategy consists of devising innovative arguments as to the (re)interpretation of general customary rules, with a view to forwarding a new rationality previously unexplored in the rule.Footnote 97 In this context, one can rely on existing CIL doctrine more generally and the customary MST more specifically and utilise some of its inherent plasticityFootnote 98 to argue for a possible remoulding of the content. Interpretation here opens a sort of ‘reasoning space’ in which the problematic origin of a rule can be scrutinised and interpretive arguments deployed to resolve it. Can certain past practices and rationalities withstand modern scrutiny when placed against contemporary values espoused in the system? This is one of the central questions that may be asked when an older general customary rule such as the MST is being interpreted in the modern context. The resulting answer is a normative argument which might claim that the protection of investment to the detriment of the environment or human wellbeing is incompatible with contemporary values. A similarly plausible argument in this vein would be that the unitary notion of Statehood inherent in the construction of the investor-State relationship is incompatible with the heterogeneous make-up of States, which often comprise of different communities with varying interests.Footnote 99 This strategy would best fit a TWAIL scholar who develops their argument from the position of scholarship.Footnote 100 On this point, an important caveat is that ‘the authority of scholars is not an institutional, procedural, or social one, but purely an epistemic one’.Footnote 101 The authority of interpretative arguments developed by scholars is limited accordingly.

This strategy may also be suited to an NGO or grassroot movement which has been granted the right to appear as amicus curiae in the context of an investment arbitration. For instance, in the context of ICSID proceedings, pursuant to Rule 37(2) of the Rules of Procedure for Arbitration Proceedings, a non-disputing party may be granted a right to intervene in the proceedings. This kind of intervention is meant to ‘assist the Tribunal in the determination of factual or legal issue related to the proceeding by bringing a perspective, particular knowledge or insight that is different from that of the disputing parties’.Footnote 102 Similar provision for non-disputing party intervention is made in the context of NAFTA proceedings.Footnote 103 This represents the opportunity to inject subaltern voices into the proceedings when their interests are otherwise not represented by the State. Using the tool of a non-disputing party intervention, actors may put forward interpretive arguments which highlight the asymmetry inherent in the investor-State relationship, and the adverse effects this has to the rights and interests of local communities. This strategy is of course limited by the tribunal’s willingness to grant standing to non-disputing parties, as well as the scope of such participation.Footnote 104 For instance, the Glamis Gold Tribunal allowed the Quechan Indian Nation to submit their views as a non-disputing party because it felt that the submission would not cause an undue burden or delay.Footnote 105 On the other hand, the Pezold Tribunal rejected indigenous participation on the reasoning that the rights of indigenous communities fell outside of the scope of the dispute and that allowing for such participation may unfairly prejudice the claimant (investor).Footnote 106 Moreover, it has been argued that even if such participation is granted, the extent to which an investment tribunal would seriously consider the interests of subaltern communities is limited.Footnote 107

A tangential opportunity to the one described here is in the training and education activities undertaken by a TWAIL scholar. For instance, in response to TWAIL scholarship, which has called for a conceptual change in the CIL doctrine, d’Aspremont has argued that a more fruitful avenue to pursue this change would be in the early stages of legal education, by targeting the production of ideas and beliefs about customary international law. The objective here would be to use the malleability of the CIL doctrine to empower scholars and practitioners of the periphery to develop persuasive subversive arguments.Footnote 108

5 Concluding Observations

This chapter has presented an idea for a constructive TWAIL approach to the interpretation of customary international investment law. This idea reflects the view that while there is a lot of relevant and legitimate criticism against the existing system of international investment law, desired change cannot be achieved if one completely dismisses the existing system. Thus, I have sketched out the so-called interpretative strategies which rely on existing structures in international law in order to affect systemic change. The argument developed here is an attempt to reconcile some of the harsh but merited TWAIL criticism with a continued engagement with the existing system of international law.

This argument also has its limitations. First, the conclusions reached in Section 3 with respect to the constructive function of interpretation in the context of the customary MST are preliminary, insofar as they were reached on the basis of a small exploratory sample of investment arbitration cases. In this sense, the conclusions can and should be tested on a broader sample of cases, as well as through examples of other customary rules.Footnote 109 Second, as the discussion in Section 4 illustrates, the strategies for interpretation as potentially deployed from the TWAIL perspective are limited by the role and position of the actor who is trying to deploy them. Finally, the strategies proposed here cannot address all the criticism levelled from the TWAIL perspective. The proposals made in Section 4 are limited to issues which arise, may be argued, and potentially resolved at the stage of interpretation.

Footnotes

10 Police Powers in a Pandemic Investment Treaty Interpretation and the Customary Presumption of Reasonable Regulation

* Many thanks to Professor Jorge E Viñuales and the editors for helpful comments. The usual caveat applies. Thanks also to the Robert Stout Law Library of the University of Otago for providing me with access to its collection during my unplanned return to New Zealand.

1 E de Vattel, The Law of Nations; or, Principles of the Law of Nature, applied to the Conduct and Affairs of Nations and Sovereigns (first published 1758, Joseph Chitty ed, 6th edn, Johnson 1844) book II, ch II, [34].

3 COVID-19 describes the disease caused by a coronavirus, provisionally named 2019-nCoV and renamed SARS-CoV-2, which emerged in December 2019. On 11 March 2020, the Director-General of the World Health Organization described the outbreak as a pandemic: WHO, ‘WHO Director-General’s opening remarks at the media briefing on COVID-19’ (World Health Organization, 11 March 2020) <www.who.int/dg/speeches/detail/who-director-general-s-opening-remarks-at-the-media-briefing-on-covid-19---11-march-2020> accessed 10 May 2021.

4 Real Decreto 463/2020, de 14 de marzo, por el que se declara el estado de alarma para la gestión de la situación de crisis sanitaria ocasionada por el COVID-19, Art 13.

5 A Tooze, Shutdown: How Covid Shook the World’s Economy (Allen Lane 2021) 13.

6 See, eg F Paddeu & K Parlett, ‘COVID-19 and Investment Treaty Claims’ (Kluwer Arbitration Blog, 30 March 2020) <http://arbitrationblog.kluwerarbitration.com/2020/03/30/covid-19-and-investment-treaty-claims> accessed 10 May 2021.

7 P Bloomer & ors, ‘Call for ISDS Moratorium During COVID-19 Crisis and Response’ (Columbia Center on Sustainable Investment, 6 May 2020) <http://ccsi.columbia.edu/2020/05/05/isds-moratorium-during-covid-19> accessed 10 May 2021.

9 See, eg G Van Harten & ors, ‘Public Statement on the International Investment Regime’ (Osgoode Hall Law School, 31 August 2010) <www.osgoode.yorku.ca/public-statement-international-investment-regime-31-august-2010> accessed 10 May 2021.

10 cf JE Viñuales, ‘Customary Law in Investment Regulation’ (2014) 23(1) IYIL 23.

11 UNCITRAL, ‘Working Group III: Investor-State Dispute Settlement Reform’ (UNCITRAL, 2021) <https://uncitral.un.org/en/working_groups/3/investor-state> accessed 10 May 2021.

12 J Kurtz, JE Viñuales & M Waibel, ‘Principles Governing the Global Economy’ in JE Viñuales (ed), The UN Friendly Relations Declaration at 50: An Assessment of the Fundamental Principles of International Law (CUP 2020) 359–60.

13 This chapter does not consider exceptions reserved for acute emergency, such as jurisdictional carve-outs for measures protecting essential security interests or the customary plea of necessity as a circumstance precluding wrongfulness. On these modalities, see JE Viñuales, ‘Defence Arguments in Investment Arbitration’ (2020) 18 ICSID Rep 9. See also Chapter 7 of this volume.

14 A Titi, The Right to Regulate in International Investment Law (Nomos 2014) 32–3. Cf LW Mouyal, International Investment Law and the Right to Regulate: A Human Rights Perspective (Routledge 2016) 8.

15 J Arato, K Claussen & JB Heath, ‘The Perils of Pandemic Exceptionalism’ (2020) 114 AJIL 627, 631.

16 See, eg, J Lee, ‘Note on COVID-19 and the Police Powers Doctrine: Assessing the Allowable Scope of Regulatory Measures During a Pandemic’ (2020) 13 CAAJ 229. Cf Section 5 below.

17 Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA) between Canada, of the One Part, and the European Union and its Member States, of the Other Part (adopted 30 October 2016, provisionally entered into force 21 September 2017) [2017] OJ L11/23 Art 8.9.1.

18 OT Johnson & J Gimblett, ‘From Gunboats to BITs: The Evolution of Modern International Investment Law’ in KP Sauvant (ed), Yearbook on International Investment Law & Policy 2010–2011 (OUP 2012).

19 FV García-Amador, ‘The Proposed New International Economic Order: A New Approach to the Law Governing Nationalization and Compensation’ (1980) 12 LawAmer 1, 20 ff.

20 Armed Activities on the Territory of the Congo (Democratic Republic of the Congo v Uganda) (Judgment) [2015] ICJ Rep 168 [244].

21 U Özsu, ‘Neoliberalism and the New International Economic Order: A History of “Contemporary Legal Thought”’ in J Desautels-Stein & C Tomlins (eds), Searching for Contemporary Legal Thought (CUP 2017) 339–40.

22 UNGA, ‘Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States’ (12 December 1974) UN Doc A/RES/3281(XXIX), Art 2(2)(c) (CERDS).

23 UNGA, ‘Permanent Sovereignty Over Natural Resources’ (14 December 1962) UN Doc A/5217 [4] (PSNR).

24 cf AJIL, ‘Mexico – United States: Expropriation by Mexico of Agrarian Properties Owned by American Citizens’ (1938) 32 AJIL Supp 181, 193.

25 CN Brower & JB Tepe, ‘The Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States: A Reflection or Rejection of International Law?’ (1975) 9(2) Intl Law 295, 304–9.

26 See, eg Texaco Overseas Petroleum et al v Libya (Award on the Merits) (1977) 53 ILR 422 [58–91].

27 PSNR (n 23) [8].

29 SS ‘Wimbledon’ (UK & ors v Germany) (Judgment) [1923] PCIJ Series A No 1, 25.

30 See J Paulsson, ‘Arbitration Without Privity’ (1995) 10 ICSID Rev 232.

31 Kurtz & ors (n 12) 351–5.

32 N Schrijver, Sovereignty over Natural Resources: Balancing Rights and Duties (CUP 1997) ch 9.

33 J Crawford, Brownlie’s Principles of Public International Law (9th edn, OUP 2019) 604.

34 See PSNR (n 23) [2–3]; UNGA, ‘Declaration on Principles of International Law Concerning Friendly Relations and Cooperation Among States in Accordance with the Charter of the United Nations’ (24 October 1970) UN Doc A/RES/2625(XXV) Annex, The principle of sovereign equality of States [e]; CERDS (n 22) Art 2(2)(a); Military and Paramilitary Activities in and Against Nicaragua (Nicaragua v USA) (Merits) [1986] ICJ Rep 14 [263–4]; G Abi-Saab, ‘Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources and Economic Activities’ in M Bedjaoui (ed), International Law: Achievements and Prospects (UNESCO 1991) 597–615.

35 Territorial and Maritime Dispute (Nicaragua v Colombia) (Judgment) [2012] ICJ Rep 624 [80–4].

36 Island of Palmas case (Netherlands v USA) (1928) 2 RIAA 829, 839.

37 cf E Shirlow, ‘Deference and Indirect Expropriation Analysis in International Investment Law: Observations on Current Approaches and Frameworks for Future Analysis’ (2014) 29 ICSID Rev 595.

38 Biens britanniques au Maroc espagnol (Spain v GB) (1925) 2 RIAA 615, 645.

39 North Atlantic Coast Fisheries Case (GB v USA) (1910) 11 RIAA 167, 187.

40 Footnote ibid 180, 188.

41 See The Environment and Human Rights (Advisory Opinion OC-23/17 of 15 November 2017) IACHR Series A 23 [141] ff.

42 P Juillard, ‘L’Évolution des Sources du Droit des Investissements’ (1994) 250 RdC 9 [52–3].

43 Oscar Chinn Case (Britain v Belgium) (Judgment) PCIJ Series A/B No 63, 88.

44 S Pahuja & A Saunders, ‘Rival Worlds and the Place of the Corporation in International Law’ in J von Bernstorff & P Dann (eds), The Battle for International Law: South-North Perspectives on the Decolonization Era (OUP 2019) 156.

45 LB Sohn & RR Baxter, ‘Responsibility of States for Injuries to the Economic Interests of Aliens’ (1961) 55 AJIL 545, 551–3. See also Kügele v Polish State (1932) 6 ILR 69 (on taxation); Furst Claim (1960) 42 ILR 153 (on monetary reform).

46 OECD, ‘Draft Convention on the Protection of Foreign Property’ (1967) 7 ILM 117, 125. cf CERDS (n 22) Art 2(2)(a).

47 Dispute regarding Navigational and Related Rights (Costa Rica v Nicaragua) (Judgment) [2009] ICJ Rep 213 [126–8].

48 See, eg, Deutsche Amerikanische Petroleum Gesellschaft Oil Tankers (1926) 2 RIAA 777, 794; USA (Dickson Car Wheel Company) v Mexico (1931) 4 RIAA 669, 681–82.

49 See eg A Pellet, ‘Police Powers or the State’s Right to Regulate: Chemtura v Canada’ in M Kinnear & ors (eds), Building International Investment Law: The First 50 Years of the ICSID Convention (Kluwer 2015).

50 See eg S Legarre, ‘The Historical Background of the Police Power’ (2007) 9 UPaJConstL 745.

51 Footnote ibid 748–61.

53 See respectively JL Sax, ‘Takings and the Police Power’ (1964) 74 YLJ 36; S Berensztein & H Spector, ‘Business, Government, and Law’ in G della Paolera & AM Taylor (eds), A New Economic History of Argentina (CUP 2003) 339–41.

54 See, eg Poggioli Case (1903) 10 RIAA 669, 691.

55 S Rosenne (ed), League of Nations Conference for the Codification of International Law (1930), Vol 2 (Oceana 1975) 684–5.

56 Sohn & Baxter (n 45) 551–3.

57 See eg JF Williams, ‘International Law and the Property of Aliens’ (1928) 9 BYBIL 1, 23–8; AP Fachiri, ‘International Law and the Property of Aliens’ (1929) 10 BYBIL 32, 51–4.

58 American Law Institute, Restatement (Second) of Foreign Relations Law (American Law Institute 1965) [197]; American Law Institute, Restatement (Third) of Foreign Relations Law (American Law Institute 1987) [712].

59 Sedco, Inc v National Iranian Oil Company and Islamic Republic of Iran (Award of 17 September 1985) IUSCT Case Nos 128 and 129 [90]; Too v Greater Modesto Insurance Associates and United States of America (Award of 29 December 1989) IUSCT Case No 880 [26–9].

60 For the first known reference, see SD Myers, Inc v Canada (Statement of Defence of 18 June 1999) UNCITRAL [55].

61 Eg Methanex Corporation v USA (Final Award of the Tribunal on Jurisdiction and Merits of 3 August 2005) pt IV, ch D [15].

62 Eg UAB E energija (Lithuania) v Republic of Latvia (Award of 22 December 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/12/33 [1067–101].

63 Eg Chemtura Corporation (formerly Crompton Corporation) v Canada (Award of 2 August 2010) UNCITRAL [266].

64 Eg AMF Aircraftleasing Meier & Fischer GmbH & Co KG, Hamburg (Germany) v Czech Republic (Final Award of 11 May 2020) PCA Case No 2017–15 [624].

65 Eg Marfin v Cyprus (Award of 26 July 2018) ICSID Case No ARB/13/27 [825–30].

66 Eg Feldman v Mexico (Award of 16 December 2002) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/99/1 [103–6].

67 Eg Lone Pine Resources Inc v Canada (Gouvernement du Canada Contre-Mémoire of 24 July 2015) ICSID Case No UNCT/15/2 [491–528].

68 Statute of the International Court of Justice (adopted 26 June 1945, entered into force 24 October 1945) 1 UNTS 993, Art 38(1)(d).

69 Philip Morris Brand Sàrl (Switzerland), Philip Morris Products SA (Switzerland) and Abal Hermanos SA (Uruguay) v Uruguay (Award of 8 July 2016) ICSID Case No ARB/10/7 [295] (Philip Morris v Uruguay).

70 Suez & Interagua v Argentina (Decision on Liability of 30 July 2010) ICSID Case No ARB/03/17 [128] (Suez v Argentina).

71 cf Investment Agreement for the COMESA Common Investment Area (adopted 23 May 2007, not yet in force) Art 20(8) <https://investmentpolicy.unctad.org/international-investment-agreements/treaty-files/3092/download> accessed 10 May 2021.

72 Eg, Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership (adopted 9 March 2018, entered into force 30 December 2018) [2018] ATS 23, annex 9-B. cf Section 4.2 below. Notably, an interpretative protocol to the very first bilateral investment treaty provided that ‘measures taken for reasons of public security and order, public health or morality shall not be deemed as discrimination’: Treaty between the Federal Republic of Germany and Pakistan for the Promotion and Protection of Investments (Germany & Pakistan) (adopted 25 November 1959, entered into force 28 April 1962) 457 UNTS 24, protocol [2].

73 Philip Morris v Uruguay [295].

74 Viñuales (n 13) [93].

75 C Henckels, Proportionality and Deference in Investor-State Arbitration: Balancing Investment Protection and Regulatory Autonomy (CUP 2015) 119.

76 See, eg AES Summit Generation Limited and AES–Tisza Erömü Kft v Hungary (Award of 23 September 2010) ICSID Case No ARB/07/22 [10.3.9].

77 Suez v Argentina [150].

78 JE Viñuales, ‘Sovereignty in Foreign Investment Law’ in Z Douglas, J Pauwelyn & JE Viñuales (eds), The Foundations of International Investment Law: Bringing Theory into Practice (OUP 2014) 329–36.

79 Award in the Arbitration regarding the Iron Rhine (“Ijzeren Rijn”) Railway between the Kingdom of Belgium and the Kingdom of the Netherlands (Decision of 24 May 2005) 27 RIAA 35 [87].

80 Footnote ibid [163].

81 Dispute regarding Navigational and Related Rights (n 47) [48].

82 Invesmart, BV v Czech Republic (Award of 26 June 2009) UNCITRAL [498].

83 Crawford (n 33) 596.

84 Brewer, Moller & Co Case (Germany v Venezuela) (1903) 10 RIAA 423, 423.

85 R Higgins, ‘International Law and the Reasonable Need of Governments to Govern’ in R Higgins (ed), Themes and Theories: Selected Essays, Speeches and Writings in International Law (OUP 2009) 791.

86 Philip Morris v Uruguay (Concurring and Dissenting Opinion of Gary Born of 8 July 2016) ICSID Case No ARB/10/7 [141] (hereinafter Philip Morris Dissent).

87 Eg, Deutsche Bank AG v Sri Lanka (Award of 31 October 2012) ICSID Case No ARB/09/02 [483–4, 522–4].

88 Eg, Quiborax v Bolivia (Award of 16 September 2015) ICSID Case No ARB/06/2 [201–27].

89 Karkey Karadeniz Elektrik Uretim AS v Islamic Republic of Pakistan (Award of 22 August 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/13/1 [497].

90 Eg, Bahgat v Arab Republic of Egypt (Final Award of 23 December 2019) PCA Case No 2012–07 [230].

91 Les Laboratoires Servier, SAS, Biofarma, SAS and Arts et Techniques du Progres SAS v Republic of Poland (Final Award of 14 February 2012) UNCITRAL [579, 583].

92 Footnote ibid [582].

93 Footnote ibid [584].

94 Footnote ibid [39].

95 For property protection as an element of the minimum standard involving an inquiry of ‘deferential reasonableness’, see M Paparinskis, The International Minimum Standard and Fair and Equitable Treatment (OUP 2013) 218–28. See further Section 5.1 below.

96 USA (LFH Neer) v Mexico (1926) 4 RIAA 60 [4].

97 See, eg Glamis Gold, Ltd v United States (Award of 8 June 2009) UNCITRAL [598–626].

98 Al Tamimi v Oman (Award of 3 November 2015) ICSID Case No ARB/11/33 [443–7].

99 Y Banifatemi, ‘The Law Applicable in Investment Treaty Arbitration’ in K Yannaca-Small (ed), Arbitration under International Investment Agreements (2nd edn, OUP 2018) [19.10].

100 Asian Agricultural Products Ltd v Republic of Sri Lanka (Final Award of 27 June 1990) ICSID Case No ARB/87/3 [21].

101 Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (adopted 23 May 1969, entered into force 27 January 1980) 1155 UNTS 331.

102 Agreement on Encouragement and Reciprocal Protection of Investments Between the Kingdom of The Netherlands and the Czech and Slovak Federal Republic (Netherlands & Czech Republic) (adopted 29 April 1991, entered into force 1 October 1992) 2242 UNTS 205, Art 5.

103 Fisheries Jurisdiction (Spain v Canada) (Jurisdiction) (Judgment) [1998] ICJ Rep 432 [66].

104 Saluka Investments BV v Czech Republic (Partial Award of 17 March 2006) UNCITRAL [254].

105 El Paso Energy International Company v Argentina (Award of 31 October 2011) ICSID Case No ARB/03/15 [240–1] (El Paso v Argentina). Many tribunals improperly invert this inquiry: see, eg Windstream Energy LLC v Canada (Award of 27 September 2016) PCA Case No 2013–22 [284].

106 See generally, C McLachlan, ‘Investment Treaties and General International Law’ (2008) 57 ICLQ 361, 369–74.

107 Oil Platforms (Iran v USA) (Judgment) [2003] ICJ Rep 161 [40–2].

108 P Ranjan, ‘Police Powers, Indirect Expropriation in International Investment Law, and Article 31(3)(c) of the VCLT: A Critique of Philip Morris v Uruguay’ (2019) 9 AsianJIL 98, 107–20.

109 cf J d’Aspremont, ‘International Customary Investment Law: Story of a Paradox’ in T Gazzini & E de Brabandere (eds), International Investment Law: The Sources of Rights and Obligations (Martinus Nijhoff 2012).

110 I Brownlie, ‘Legal Status of Natural Resources in International Law (Some Aspects)’ (1979) 162 RdC 245, 270–1.

111 cf O Corten, ‘The Notion of “Reasonable” in International Law: Legal Discourse, Reason and Contradictions’ (1999) 48 ICLQ 613, 620–4.

112 Mondev International Ltd v USA (Award of 11 October 2002) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/99/2 [113].

113 Ranjan (n 108) 117–18.

114 Footnote ibid 121–4.

115 R Dolzer, ‘Indirect Expropriations: New Developments?’ (2002) 11 NYU Envtl LJ 64, 79 ff.

116 V Lowe, ‘Regulation or Expropriation?’ (2002) 55(1) CLP 447, 450.

117 cf Philip Morris v Uruguay [300–1].

118 Bear Creek Mining Corporation v Perú (Award of 30 November 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/14/21 [472–3] (Bear Creek v Peru).

119 Free Trade Agreement between Canada and the Republic of Peru (Canada & Peru) (adopted 29 May 2008, entered into force 1 August 2009) Can TS 2009 No 15, Art 2201.1(3)(a) (Canada–Peru FTA).

120 Bear Creek v Peru [477].

121 C Henckels, ‘Scope Limitation or Affirmative Defence? The Purpose and Role of Investment Treaty Exception Clauses’ in L Bartels & F Paddeu (eds), Exceptions in International Law (OUP 2020) 367.

122 Bear Creek v Peru [473].

123 Canada–Peru FTA (n 119) annex 812.1(3).

124 C Titi, ‘Police Powers Doctrine and International Investment Law’ in A Gattini, A Tanzi & F Fontanelli (eds), General Principles of Law and International Investment Arbitration (Brill 2018) 338–9.

125 Eco Oro Minerals Corp v Colombia (Decision on Jurisdiction, Liability and Directions on Quantum of 9 September 2021) ICSID Case No ARB/16/41 [626].

126 cf Military and Paramilitary Activities in and Against Nicaragua [178] (treaties may establish ‘mechanisms to ensure implementation’ of customary rules); Legality of the Threat or Use of Nuclear Weapons (Advisory Opinion) [1996] ICJ Rep 226 [25] (‘[t]he test … falls to be determined by the applicable lex specialis’).

127 This standard of due diligence requires governments ‘to take reasonable acts within their power to prevent the injury … when states are, or should be, aware of a risk of injury’: N Junngam, ‘The Full Protection and Security Standard in International Investment Law: What and Who is Investment Fully[?] Protected and Secured From?’ (2018) 7 AUBLR 1, 54. Notably, the classical practice points to a ‘presumption against responsibility’ of a State for injuries to foreign investors caused by non-State actors: FV García-Amador, LB Sohn & RR Baxter, Recent Codification of the Law of State Responsibility for Injuries to Aliens (Oceana 1974) 27.

128 This non-impairment standard largely overlaps with FET: A Reinisch & C Schreuer, International Protection of Investments: The Substantive Standards (CUP 2020) 846–51.

129 J Bonnitcha, LN Skovgaard Poulsen & M Waibel, The Political Economy of the Investment Treaty Regime (OUP 2017) 94.

130 M Sornarajah, Resistance and Change in the International Law on Foreign Investment (CUP 2015) ch 5.

131 M Potestà, ‘Legitimate Expectations in Investment Treaty Law: Understanding the Roots and Limits of a Controversial Concept’ (2013) 28 ICSID Rev 88.

132 See, eg CETA (n 17) Art 8.9.2.

133 C McLachlan, L Shore & M Weiniger, International Investment Arbitration: Substantive Principles (2nd edn, OUP 2017) [7.184].

134 El Paso v Argentina [373–4].

135 Suez v Argentina [148].

136 cf JE Alvarez, ‘The Public International Law Regime Governing International Investment’ (2011) 344 RdC 193, 423.

137 F Ortino, The Origin and Evolution of Investment Treaty Standards: Stability, Value, and Reasonableness (OUP 2020) ch 3.

138 YS Selivanova, ‘Changes in Renewables Support Policy and Investment Protection under the Energy Charter Treaty: Analysis of Jurisprudence and Outlook for the Current Arbitration Cases’ (2018) 33 ICSID Rev 433.

139 Masdar Solar v Spain (Award of 16 May 2018) ICSID Case No ARB/14/1 [490].

140 Greentech Energy Systems A/S, NovEnergia II Energy & Environment (SCA) SICAR, and NovEnergia II Italian Portfolio SA v Italy (Final Award of 23 December 2018) SCC Case No V 2015/095 [450].

141 RREEF v Spain (Decision on Responsibility and on the Principles of Quantum of 30 November 2018) ICSID Case No ARB/13/30 [241] (RREEF v Spain).

142 Footnote ibid [244].

143 Footnote ibid [242].

144 Viñuales (n 13) [94–8].

145 Philip Morris v Uruguay [399].

146 Footnote ibid [399–401].

147 Philip Morris Dissent (n 86) [87], [139]. See also, G Born, D Morris & S Forrest, ‘“A Margin of Appreciation”: Appreciating Its Irrelevance in International Law’ (2020) 61 HarvILJ 65.

148 See fn 86.

149 See, eg RREEF v Spain [468].

150 cf Jahn and others v Germany ECHR 2005-/VI 55 [91].

151 F Paddeu & M Waibel, ‘The Final Act: Exploring the End of Pandemics’ (2020) 114 AJIL 698, 700.

152 Bischoff Case (1903) 10 RIAA 420.

153 Footnote ibid 420.

154 International Health Regulations (adopted 23 May 2005, entered into force 15 June 2007) 2509 UNTS 79 (IHR).

155 C Parry (ed), A British Digest of International Law, Vol 6 (Stevens & Sons 1965) 350.

156 JB Moore, A Digest of International Law, Vol 6 (US GPO 1906) 751–2.

157 Footnote ibid 751.

158 In 1892, the State Department refused to request the relaxation of Colombia’s quarantine because the United States had also imposed rigid measures: JB Moore, A Digest of International Law, Vol 2 (US GPO 1906) 146.

159 MM Whiteman, Damages in International Law, Vol 2 (US GPO 1937) 879–82.

160 Bischoff Case 420.

161 In 1885, the Foreign Office refused to entertain the claims of injured companies that had flouted sanitary regulations: Moore (n 156) 144.

162 Parry (n 155) 292.

164 Paparinskis (n 95) 224.

165 Eg Sporrong and Lönnroth v Sweden IHRL 36 (ECHR 1982) [66–74].

166 Eg Chaparro Álvarez and Lapo Íñiguez v Ecuador (Preliminary Objections, Merits, Reparations, and Costs, Judgment of 21 November 2007) IACHR Series C No 170 [183–218].

167 Elettronica Sicula SpA (ELSI) (USA v Italy) (Judgment) [1989] ICJ Rep 15 [128] (‘a wilful disregard of due process of law, an act which shocks, or at least surprises, a sense of juridical propriety’).

168 See ELSI [128] (‘a wilful disregard of due process of law, an act which shocks, or at least surprises, a sense of juridical propriety’); Saluka v Czech Republic [307] (requiring conduct ‘reasonably justifiable by public policies’ which ‘does not manifestly violate the requirements of consistency, transparency, even-handedness and nondiscrimination’).

169 Paparinskis (n 95) 242.

170 cf measures adopted in a ‘rapidly developing public health emergency’ may be ultra vires but ‘nevertheless reasonable, necessary and proportionate’: Borrowdale v Director-General of Health [2020] NZHC 2090 [290].

171 BA Wortley, Expropriation in Public International Law (CUP 1959) 110.

172 Philip Morris Dissent (n 86) [90].

173 ILC, ‘Survey of International Law in Relation to the Work of Codification of the International Law Commission’ (10 February 1949) UN Doc A/CN.4/1/Rev.1 [58] citing Trail Smelter (United States, Canada) (1941) 3 RIAA 1905.

174 N Howard-Jones, The Scientific Background of the International Sanitary Conferences 1851–1938 (WHO 1975) 12.

175 International Sanitary Convention (adopted 30 January 1892, entered into force 1 November 1893). See further S Murase, ‘Epidemics and International Law’ (2021) 81 Annuaire de l’Institut de Droit International 37, 45–7.

176 Constitution of the World Health Organization (adopted 22 July 1946, entered into force 7 April 1948) 14 UNTS 185, Art 21(a).

177 cf DE Pozen & KL Scheppele, ‘Executive Underreach, in Pandemics and Otherwise’ (2020) 114 AJIL 608.

178 See Section 2 above.

179 Whether underreach could breach the standard of full protection and security falls beyond this chapter. See fn 127.

180 IHR (n 154) Arts 5–12.

181 Footnote ibid Art 1.

182 Footnote ibid Art 49.

183 Footnote ibid Arts 15(2) & 42.

184 See, eg WHO, ‘Statement on the Fourth Meeting of the International Health Regulations (2005) Emergency Committee Regarding the Outbreak of Coronavirus Disease (COVID-19)’ (WHO, 1 August 2020) <www.who.int/news/item/01-08-2020-statement-on-the-fourth-meeting-of-the-international-health-regulations-(2005)-emergency-committee-regarding-the-outbreak-of-coronavirus-disease-(covid-19)> accessed 27 April 2021.

185 IHR (n 154) Art 3(4).

186 Footnote ibid Art 2.

187 Footnote ibid Art 3(1). cf International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (adopted 16 December 1966, entered into force 3 January 1976) 993 UNTS 3, Art 12(2)(c) (on ‘prevention, treatment and control of epidemic’ as ‘steps to be taken … to achieve the full realization’ of ‘the right of everyone to the enjoyment of the highest attainable standard of physical and mental health’).

188 Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (adopted 15 April 1994, entered into force 1 January 1995) 1867 UNTS 493. See DP Fidler, ‘From International Sanitary Conventions to Global Health Security: The New International Health Regulations’ (2005) 4 Chin J Int Law 325, 382–3.

189 WTO, India – Measures Concerning the Importation of Certain Agricultural Products – Report of the Appellate Body (4 June 2015) WT/DS430/AB/R [5.203].

190 cf R Habibi & ors, ‘The Stellenbosch Consensus on Legal National Responses to Public Health Risks: Clarifying Article 43 of the International Health Regulations’ (2022) 19 IOLR 90, 45–51.

191 See eg Continental Casualty v Argentina (Award of 5 September 2008) ICSID Case No ARB/03/9 [192].

192 See fn 123–6.

193 cf Philip Morris v Uruguay (n 69) [37–9].

194 On the potential significance of WHO’s scientific evidence and legal submissions, see CE Foster, ‘Respecting Regulatory Measures: Arbitral Method and Reasoning in the Philip Morris v Uruguay Tobacco Plain Packaging Case’ (2017) 26(3) RECIEL 287.

195 IHR (n 154) Art 15.3.

196 See M Waibel, ‘Subject Matter Jurisdiction: The Notion of Investment’ (2021) 19 ICSID Rep 25.

197 R Yotova, ‘Systemic Integration: An Instrument for Reasserting the State’s Control in Investment Arbitration?’ in A Kulick (ed), Reassertion of Control over the Investment Treaty Regime (CUP 2016) 185.

198 cf Continental Casualty v Argentine Republic [244–5].

199 F Baetens, ‘Protecting Foreign Investment and Public Health Through Arbitral Balancing and Treaty Design’ (2022) 71 ICLQ 139.

200 Mamidoil Jetoil Greek Petroleum Products Societe Anonyme SA v Albania (Award of 30 March 2015) ICSID Case No ARB/11/24 [629].

201 Philip Morris v Uruguay [430].

202 Genin, Eastern Credit Limited, Inc and AS Baltoil v Estonia (Award of 25 June 2001) ICSID Case No ARB/99/2 [348, 364].

203 Eg, Teinver v Argentina (Award of 21 July 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/09/1 [668–78].

204 cf Urbaser v Argentina (Award of 8 December 2016) ICSID Case No ARB/07/26 [1205–10]. See fn 187.

205 Tethyan Copper v Pakistan (Decision on Stay of Enforcement of the Award of 17 September 2020) ICSID Case No ARB/12/1 [155–7].

206 Arato, Claussen & Heath (n 15) 635.

11 Bilateral Investment Treaties, Investor Obligations and Customary International Environmental Law

1 Reciprocal Investment Promotion and Protection Agreement Between the Government of the Kingdom of Morocco and The Government of the Federal Republic of Nigeria (Morocco & Nigeria) (adopted 3 December 2016, not yet in force) Art 14 (Hereinafter Nigeria–Morocco BIT).

2 Nigeria–Morocco BIT (n 1) Art 18(3).

3 The language of the precautionary principle clause in the Nigeria–Morocco BIT is identical to the language in the South African Development Committee (SADC) Model BIT and the ECOWAS Common Investment Code. The SADC Model BIT also states that the application of the precautionary principle by investor and investments shall be described in the environmental impact assessment. The ECOWAS Common Investment Code further highlights various aspects of EIA and mandates that environmental and social impact assessment be made available to the general public and local affected communities. In addition, the investor is required to perform restoration, using appropriate technologies for any damage caused to the natural environment and provide necessary environmental information to the competent national environmental authorities, together with measures and costs necessary to avoid and mitigate against potentially harmful effects.

4 See P Muchlinski, ‘Negotiating International Investment Agreements: New Sustainable Development Oriented Initiatives’ in S Hindelang, M Krajewski & ors (eds), Shifting Paradigms in International Investment Law: More Balanced, Less Isolated and Increasingly Diversified (OUP 2016) 41.

5 P Marie-Dupuy & JE Viñuales, International Environmental Law (CUP 2015) 61, 68.

6 OW Pederson, ‘From Abundance to Indeterminacy: The Precautionary Principle and its Two Camps of Custom’ (2014) 3(2) TEL 323, 327.

7 The Tribunals in Urbaser v Argentina and David Aven v Costa Rica were confronted with the question of whether multinational corporations had the same international human rights and environmental obligations as state actors. Both Tribunals concluded that there was a certain degree of responsibility on multinational corporations to ensure that they operated within the host state’s legal obligations. However, those obligations were not identical to those of nation states and in both cases, the relevant investment frameworks did not impose any direct obligation. See Urbaser v Argentina (Award of 8 December 2016) ICSID Case No ARB/07/26 [1207–10]; and David Aven v Costa Rica (Final Award of 18 September 2018) ICSID Case No UNCT/15/3 [743].

8 Urbaser v Argentina [1210]; David Aven v Costa Rica [743].

9 Footnote ibid [1210].

10 See J Wouters & AL Chane, ‘Multinational Corporations in International Law’ in M Noorman, A Reinisch & C Ryngaert (eds), Non-State Actors in International Law (Bloomsbury 2017) 239.

11 K Miles, The Origins of International Investment Law: Empire, Environment and the Safeguarding of Capital (CUP 2013) 19–20. Miles argues that the content and form of foreign investment protection cannot be separated from its socio-political context and the rules on foreign investment protection evolved throughout the ‘colonial encounter’ as a tool to protect the interests of capital exporting States and their nationals. She further argues that colonial capital exporting States portrayed the European form and content of international law, along with its particular conceptions of property, private wealth, economy and regulation as being the basis for the evolution of international investment law as a mechanism which protected only the investor.

12 KJ Vandevelde, ‘A Brief History of International Investment Agreements’ (2005) 12 UCDavis JInt’l L& Pol’y 57.

13 Footnote ibid 174. Terming it the Global Era, Vandevelde observes that the victory of market ideology following the collapse of the Soviet Union and loss of alternatives to foreign investment as a source of capital acted as a catalyst for the growth of international investment agreements.

14 K Tienhaara, ‘Regulatory Chill and the Threat of Arbitration’ in C Brown & K Miles (eds), Evolution in Investment Treaty Law and Arbitration (CUP 2011).

15 Two early cases where the United States found itself as a respondent were Methanex v USA (Final Award of the Tribunal on Jurisdiction and Merits of 3 August 2005) UNCITRAL and Glamis Gold, Ltd v USA (Award of 8 June 2009) UNCITRAL. In the former, the Canadian investor producing Methanol challenged the California ban of the additive MTBE of which Methanol was a component. In the latter, the Canadian investor sough compensation from California for a regulation that required the restoration and backfilling of Native American sites. In both cases, the Tribunal held that expropriation had not occurred.

16 An analysis of the Database of BITs on the International Centre for Settlement of Investment Disputes website shows that more BITs were signed between 1978 and 1995 and onwards, rather than before 1978. Moreover, several BITs signed in the 1980s and 1990s were between developing nations. See ICSID, ‘Database of Bilateral Investment Treaties’ (ICSID, 2022) <https://icsid.worldbank.org/resources/databases/bilateral-investment-treaties> accessed 1 June 2022.

17 The 2012 US Model BIT, Art 12(5) specifically states that nothing shall prevent the State parties from taking measures or undertaking regulations to protect the environment. Likewise, Annex B of the Treaty excludes non-discriminatory regulatory objectives to protect the environment from the scope of expropriation. Of course, these provisions are also present in the 2004 US model BIT. The increased scope of regulation in the US Model BIT is a reflection of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) (adopted 17 December 1992, entered into force 1 January 1994) 32 ILM 289; Canada, ‘2004 Model Agreement for the Promotion and Protection of Investments’ (Canadian Government, 2004) <https://investmentpolicy.unctad.org/international-investment-agreements/treaty-files/2820/download> accessed 1 June 2022; USTR, ‘2012 U.S. Model Bilateral Investment Treaty’ (USTR, 2012) <https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/BIT%20text%20for%20ACIEP%20Meeting.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022; USTR, ‘2004 Model Bilateral Investment Treaty’ (USTR, 2004) <https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/U.S.%20model%20BIT.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022.

18 A way in which states attempt to promote sustainable development and green economy objectives is the use of exceptions and reservations in IIAs. By exceptions, States ensure that their ability to regulate certain fields will not be restricted by investment treaties. Exceptions can be in several forms, ie, sector-specific treaty reservations, general exceptions such as measures relating to the protection of ‘human, animal or plant life or health’ or Non-Precluded Measures which are intended to exempt certain subject areas such public health, public security and morality from the scope of the treaty or specific treaty obligations.’ These are standardised clauses found in almost all treaties. See MW Gehring & A Kent ‘International Investment Agreements and the Emerging Green Economy: Rising to the Challenge’ in F Baetens (ed), Investment Law Within International Law (CUP 2013) 187, 204. A clause which allows cause for exceptions to a country’s liability in an international investment agreement regarding matters such as public health, public order, environmental matters, essential security interests, etc. Non precluded measures preclude the wrongfulness of a nation’s regulatory liability in such areas. They are a form of exception clauses.

19 See M Krajewski, ‘A Nightmare or a Noble Dream? Establishing Investor Obligations Through Treaty-Making and Treaty-Application’ (2020) 5(1) BHRJ 105, 128. Krajewski observes that recent treaty-making practice in international law does not seem to move towards including clear and precise binding human rights obligations for investors. Consequently, it seems unlikely that investor obligations to respect human rights will emerge in the foreseeable future in international treaty making or treaty-application. The Nigeria–Morocco BIT appears to be an exception to the rule.

20 See H Mann, K Van Moltke, LE Peterson & ors, ‘International Institute for Sustainable Development Model International Agreement on Investment for Sustainable Development, Negotiators Handbook’ (IISD, Aril 2006) <www.iisd.org/system/files/publications/investment_model_int_handbook.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022 (hereinafter IISD Model BIT).

21 See African Union Commission, ‘Draft Pan African Investment Code’ (December 2016) <https://au.int/sites/default/files/documents/32844-doc-draft_pan-african_investment_code_december_2016_en.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022 (hereinafter Draft PAIC).

22 Nigeria–Morocco BIT (n 1) Art 14(1).

23 Footnote ibid, Art 14(3).

24 Footnote ibid, Art 18(3).

25 IISD Model BIT (n 20) Art 12(a).

26 Footnote ibid, Art 12(d).

27 Nigeria–Morocco BIT (n 1) Art 18(3); Footnote ibid 14(d).

28 SADC, ‘SADC Model Bilateral Investment Treaty Template: With Commentary’ (SADC, July 2012) Art 13.1 <www.iisd.org/itn/wp-content/uploads/2012/10/sadc-model-bit-template-final.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022.

29 ECOWAS, ‘ECOWAS Common Investment Code (ECOWIC)’ (July 2018) arts 27(1)(b-d) <https://wacomp.projects.ecowas.int/wp-content/uploads/2020/03/ECOWAS-COMMON-INVESTMENT-CODEENGLISH.pdf> accessed 1 March 2022.

30 Draft PAIC (n 20) Art 37(4).

31 Supra SADC (n 28).

32 P Sands, J Peel, A Fabra & ors, Principles of International Environmental Law (CUP 2012) 34–5.

33 Marie-Dupuy & Viñuales (n 5) 61. The main thesis of the precautionary principle is that in the face of serious risk to or grounds (as appropriately qualified) for concern about the environment, scientific uncertainty or the absence of complete proof should not stand in the way of positive action to minimise risks or take actions of a conservatory, preventative or curative nature; see also Southern Bluefin Tuna Cases (NZ v Japan; Australia v Japan) (Provisional Measures, Order of 27 August 1999) 1999 ITLOS Rep 280, Separate Opinion of Judge Laing [14].

34 UNGA, ‘Report of the United Nations Conference on Environment and Development’ (16 March 1992) UN Doc A/RES/47/190 (Rio Declaration) principle 15.

35 Pederson (n 6) 329.

36 For a detailed list of treaties containing the precautionary principle or incorporating a precautionary approach, See J Peel, The Precautionary Principle in Practice (Federation Press 2005). For example, some treaties define the precautionary principle and then apply it. The Convention to Ban the Importation into Forum Island Countries of Hazardous and Radioactive Wastes and to Control the Transboundary Movement and Management of Hazardous Wastes within the South Pacific Region (adopted 16 September 1995, entered into force 21 October 2001) 2161 UNTS 91, Art 1: ‘“Precautionary principle” means the principle that in order to protect the environment, the precautionary approach shall be widely applied by Parties according to their capabilities. Where there are threats of serious or irreversible damage, lack of full scientific certainty shall not be used as a reason for postponing cost effective measures to prevent environmental degradation’, Art 13(3) of the same convention; likewise, the preamble of the Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety to the Convention on Biological Diversity (adopted 29 January 2000, entered into force 11 September 2003) 39 ILM 1027, reaffirms the precautionary approach contained in Principle 15 of the Rio Declaration on Environment and Development. Article 1 states that ‘In accordance with the precautionary approach contained in Principle 15 of the Rio Declaration on Environment and Development, the objective of this Protocol is to contribute to ensuring an adequate level of protection in the field of the safe transfer, handling and use of living modified organisms resulting from modern biotechnology that may have adverse effects on the conservation and sustainable use of biological diversity, taking also into account risks to human health, and specifically focusing on transboundary movements’.

37 Sands & ors (n 32) 61: ‘Even if the existence of a customary precautionary principle could be admitted, its content would still have to be defined. Is it an obligation to take action despite the lack of sufficient evidence about the danger that an activity poses to the environment? Or is it, rather, a simple authorisation to take such measures?’.

38 According to the non-custom camp, since the principle is ill defined, it is difficult to prove empirically, see Pederson (n 6) 329.

39 Footnote ibid 334. According to Pederson, this dialectic plays out where controversy arises concerning the enactment of a legal directive or norm. Preference may be given to rules over principles, depending on which virtues and vices or vice versa. The non-custom camp prefers the conception of rules over broader principles.

40 The custom camp primarily relies on widespread State practice to bolster its stand that the precautionary principle is CIL. Since opinio juris is a state of mind, there is difficulty in attributing it to a State, and therefore, it has to be deduced from a State’s actions and pronouncements. A rule is often considered to be CIL by being codified in multilateral conventions – in fact, so much so, that a judge no longer has to ascertain from the practice what the alleged rule requires, see H Thirlway, The Sources of International Law (OUP 2005) 80. The ICJ, in Military and Paramilitary Activities in and against Nicaragua (Nicaragua v USA) (Merits) [1986] ICJ Rep 16, 98 [186], explained that for a rule to be considered customary it dd not consider that the corresponding practice must be in absolute conformity with the rule. Rather, it is sufficient that the conduct of States should, in general, be consistent with such rules.

41 Southern Bluefin Tuna Cases (NZ v Japan; Australia v Japan) (Provisional Measures, Order of 27 August 1999) 1999 ITLOS Rep 280 [28–9].

42 Footnote ibid [34].

43 Footnote ibid [77].

44 Footnote ibid, Separate Opinion of Judge Laing [19].

45 Footnote ibid, Separate Opinion of Judge Treves [8].

47 WTO, European Communities – Measures Affecting Asbestos and Asbestos-Containing Products – Report of the Appellate Body (12 March 2001) WT/DS135/AB/R [53].

48 In the Nuclear Tests case, Judge Palmer (dissenting) observed that the norm involved in the precautionary principle has developed rapidly and may now be a principle of customary international law. Judge Weeramantry (dissenting) observed that reversing the burden of proof was an essential element to guarantee an effective protection of the environment and give full force to the legal obligations tending to ensure this protection. New Zealand argued that France should prove the absolute innocuity of nuclear tests in the South Pacific. See Request for an Examination of the Situation in Accordance with Paragraph 63 of the Court’s Judgment of 20th December 1974 in the Nuclear Tests (New Zealand v France) [1995] ICJ Rep 288, Dissenting opinion by Judge ad hoc Sir Geoffrey Palmer [91] & Dissenting opinion by Judge Weeramantry 343.The reluctance to directly refer to the precautionary principle as custom is reflective of the lack of uniform conception of the principle. In the Pulp Mills decision, the ICJ observed that the precautionary principle may be relevant in the interpretation and application of the provisions of the disputed treaty. Within the context of the Nigeria–Morocco BIT, the inclusion of the precautionary principle may provide clear guidance as to the environmental management procedures to be followed by the investors; see Pulp Mills on the River Uruguay (Argentina v Uruguay) (Merits) [2010] ICJ Rep 14 [164].

49 WTO, European Communities – Measures Concerning Meat and Meat Products (Hormones) – Report of the Appellate Body (13 February 1998) WT/DS26/AB/R, WT/DS48/AB/R [124].

50 Convention on Environmental Impact Assessment in a Transboundary Context (adopted 25 February 1991, entered into force 10 September 1997) 1989 UNTS 309. In the Case Concerning Pulp Mills [204] the ICJ observed, ‘that a practice has developed which in recent years has gained so much acceptance among states that it may now be considered a requirement under general international law to undertake an environmental impact assessment where there is a risk that the proposed industrial activity may have a significant adverse impact in a transboundary context, in particular, on a shared resource’.

51 Thirlway (n 40) 72.

53 India has recently diluted its environmental screening procedures to attract greater investment. It allows certain projects of strategic importance to be cleared without screening and has reduced the timeline for public participation. Therefore, even if a BIT were to include the application of a precautionary approach, it would depend on whether domestic law provides for that approach. See Indian Government, ‘Ministry Of Environment, Forest And Climate Change: Notification’ (Gazette of India, 23 March 2020) Extraordinary, pt II, sect 3, subsect (ii) <http://environmentclearance.nic.in/writereaddata/Draft_EIA_2020.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022.

54 H Davies, ‘Investor-State Dispute Settlement and the Future of the Precautionary Principle’ (2016) 5(2) Br J A Leg Studies 449, 454.

55 Bilcon v Canada (Award of 17 March 2015) PCA Case No 2009–04.

56 Footnote ibid [534].

57 Footnote ibid [597–8].

58 MW Gehring, ‘Impact Assessments of Investment Treaties’ in MC Cordonier Segger, MW Gehring & AP Newcombe (eds) Sustainable Development in World Investment Law (Kluwer Law 2011) 149–50.

60 PA Allard v Barbados (Award of 27 June 2016) PCA Case No 2012–06 [3].

62 Footnote ibid [226].

63 Footnote ibid [224].

64 There may also be a certain benefit in the investor co-operating with the host State in conducting an environmental screening of the investment. Bear Creek Mining Corporation v Peru (Award of 30 November 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/14/21 [39]. In Bear Creek Mining Corporation v Peru (Partial Dissenting Opinion of Professor Philippe Sands of 30 November 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/14/21, Sands argued in his dissenting opinion that investors are obliged to adhere to human rights in particular, to minimise any potential damages which investors could suffer. See also, T Ishikawa, The Role of International Environmental Principles in Investment Treaty Arbitration: Precautionary and Polluter Pays Principles and Partial Compensation (Brill 2016) 245.

65 Urbaser v Argentina [1207].

66 JH Fahner & M Happold, ‘The Human Rights Defence in International Investment Arbitration: Exploring the Limits of Systemic Integration’ (2019) 68(3) ICLQ 741, 758.

67 See, Peel (n 36), where most environmental treaties place the onus of applying the precautionary principle on State parties.

68 For the full text of the DR-CAFTA, see Free Trade Agreement between Central America, the Dominican Republic and the United States of America (DR-CAFTA) (adopted 5 August 2004, entered into force 1 January 2009).

69 David Aven v Costa Rica [385].

71 Footnote ibid. Article 17.2 of the DR-CAFTA recognises a Party’s right to enforce its environmental laws. Article 17.12 further recognises that the implementation of multilateral environmental agreements is critical to achieving the objectives of those agreements. Article 10.11 allows a State Party to adopt, maintain or enforce any measure, consistent with its investment obligations, to ensure that investment activity in its territory is undertaken in a manner sensitive to environmental concerns.

73 Footnote ibid [394].

74 Footnote ibid [444].

76 Footnote ibid [417–18].

77 Footnote ibid [552].

78 Footnote ibid [553].

79 Footnote ibid [552–3].

80 Urbaser v Argentina [1210]. The Tribunal observed that the investor was only bound by the BIT and domestic law – ensuring the human right to water was the responsibility of the host State.

81 Footnote ibid [1207].

82 David Aven v Costa Rica [743].

83 Please see Section 2.1 of this chapter.

84 Urbaser v Argentina [1156].

87 Footnote ibid [1167].

88 Footnote ibid [1158].

89 Footnote ibid [1201].

90 Footnote ibid [1210].

91 Footnote ibid [1207].

92 See R Yotova, ‘Compliance with Domestic Law: An Implied Condition in Treaties Conferring Rights and Protections on Foreign Nationals and Their Property?’ in J Klingler, Y Parkhomenko & C Salonidis (eds), Between the Lines of the Vienna Convention? Canons and Other Principles of Interpretation in Public International Law (Kluwer 2018) 307. She observes that compliance with domestic law rarely extends to obligations of conduct – most requirements of compliance are in regard to admission of investments, the definition of investment or limit the application of the treaty to investments made in accordance with the laws of the host State. However, this does not mean that investors are necessarily bound by the environmental obligations of the host State.

93 Urbaser v Argentina [1195].

94 See Wouters & Chane (n 9) 239. See UN Sub-Commission on the Promotion and Protection of Human Rights, ‘Economic, Social and Cultural Rights: Norms on the Responsibilities of Transnational Corporations and Other Business Enterprises with Regard to Human Rights’ (26 August 2003) UN Doc E/CN.4/Sub.2/2003/12/Rev2 (Draft Norms); UNHRC, ‘Report of the Special Representative of the Secretary-General on the Issue of Human Rights and Transnational Corporations and Other Business Enterprises, John Ruggie’ (21 March 2011) UN Doc A/HRC/17/31 [13]; and UNHRC, Text of the third revised draft legally binding instrument with the concrete textual proposals submitted by States during the seventh session, UNHRC, ‘Text of the Third Revised Draft Legally Binding Instrument with the Textual Proposals Submitted by States During the Seventh Session of the Open-Ended Intergovernmental Working Group on Transnational Corporations and Other Business Enterprises With Respect to Human Rights’ (28 February 2022) UN Doc A/HRC/49/65/Add.1.

95 Miles (n 10).

96 JE Alvarez, ‘Are Corporations “Subjects” of International Law’ (2011) 9(1) Santa Clara Journal of International Law 1, 31. Alvarez suggests that multinational corporations cannot have the same obligations as State parties – rather, they have obligations to protect and respect the human rights obligations of the host State through the conception of due diligence. To arrive at this reasoning, he borrows from the UN Draft Norms on the Responsibilities of Transnational Corporations and Other Business Enterprises with Regard to Human Rights, which requires multinational corporations to respect human rights and to avoid causing adverse human rights impacts. See, UNHRC ‘Report of the Special Representative of the Secretary General on the Issue off Human Rights and Transnational Corporations and Other Business Enterprises, John Ruggie’ (7 April 2008) UN Doc A/HRC/8/5 [3].

98 Krajewski (n 19).

12 The Role of Customary International Law in International Investment Law Remedies The Curious Case of Natural Resources

* The article is part of the research project number 2018/28/C/HS5/00087 financed by the National Science Centre Poland.

1 Traditionally, the term ‘compensation’ was used in connection with the consequences of a legal act, whereas the term ‘damages’ in connection with the consequences of an illegal act. At present, that distinction is often blurred in practice. See S Ripinsky & K Williams, Damages in International Investment Law (BIICL Law 2008) 4; TW Wälde & B Sabahi, ‘Compensation, Damages and Valuation’ in P Muchlinski, F Ortino & C Schreuer (eds), The Oxford Handbook of International Investment Law (OUP 2008) 1052–3. For the purposes of this chapter, the author decided to avoid the semantic dispute on the use of terminology and uses the term ‘compensation’ with respect to the consequences of both legal and illegal acts, following the wording of the ILC Articles.

2 Case Concerning the Factory at Chorzów (Germany v Poland) (Merits) [1928] PCIJ Series A No 17, 47.

4 Amoco v Iran (Partial Award (Award No 310-56-3) of 14 July 1987) IUSCT Case No 56, 15 IUSCT 189 [191].

5 For example: Case Concerning the Gabčíkovo-Nagymaros Project (Hungary/Slovakia) (Judgment) [1997] ICJ Rep 7 [149]; Arrest Warrant of 11 April 2000 (Congo v Belgium) (Judgment) [2002] ICJ Rep 3 [76]; Avena and Other Mexican Nationals (Mexico v USA) (Judgment) [2004] ICJ Rep 12 [119]; Legal Consequences of the Construction of a Wall in the Occupied Palestinian Territories (Advisory Opinion) [2004] ICJ Rep 136 [152]. In investor-State arbitrations, see, for example: Unglaube v Costa Rica (Award of 16 May 2012) ICSID Case No ARB/08/1 & ARB/09/20 [306]; ADC Affiliate Limited v Hungary (Award of 2 October 2006) ICSID Case No ARB/03/16 [484–5]. In other fora, see also, for example: The M/V ‘Saiga’ (No 2) (Saint Vincent and the Grenadines v Guinea) (Judgment) [1999] ITLOS Rep 10 [170]; Papamichalopoulos and Others v Greece (Article 50) (1995) Series A No 330–B [36].

6 See, for example, MW Reisman & RD Sloane, ‘Indirect Expropriation and its Valuation in the BIT Convention’ (2004) 74 BYBIL 115, 133, who describe the Chorzów Factory principle as a ‘lodestar’ for the general principles of international law on compensation. For the two elements of custom see, for example: J Crawford, Brownlie’s Principles of Public International Law (9th edn, OUP 2019) 22–5.

7 E De Brabandere, Investment Treaty Arbitration as Public International Law (CUP 2014) 177.

8 J Crawford, ‘State Responsibility’ [2020] MPEPIL 1093 [31]; N Rubins, V Sinha & B Roberts, ‘Approaches to Valuation in Investment Treaty Arbitration’ in CL Beharry (ed), Contemporary and Emerging Issues on the Law of Damages and Valuation in International Investment Arbitration (Brill Nijhoff 2018) 172; De Brabandere (n 7) 178; Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 32; Nykomb v Latvia (Arbitral Award of 16 December 2003) SCC Case No 118/2001, 38; LG&E v Argentina (Award of 25 July 2007) ICSID Case No ARB/02/1 [31]; Siemens AG v Argentina (Award of 17 January 2007) ICSID Case No ARB/02/8 [350]; Biwater Gauff v Tanzania (Award of 24 July 2008) ICSID Case No ARB/05/22 [773]; Tza Yap Shum v Peru (Award of 7 July 2011) ICSID Case No ARB/07/6 [253–4]. The Tribunal in OperaFund v Spain summarised: ‘the relevant principles of customary international law are derived from the PCIJ Judgment in the Chorzów Factory Case and are recorded in Articles 31–38 of the ILC Draft Articles’ (OperaFund v Spain (Award of 6 September 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/15/36 [609]).

9 ILC, ‘Draft Articles on Responsibility of States for Internationally Wrongful Acts with Commentaries’ (23 April–1 June and 2 July–10 August 2001) UN Doc A/56/10, reproduced in [2001/II – Part Two] YBILC 31, 87–8, commentary to Art 28 [3] (‘ILC Articles’); in similar vein: ILC Articles, 95, commentary to Art 33 [4].

10 ILC Articles (n 9) Art 33(2)

11 PM Protopsaltis, ‘Shareholders’ Injury and Compensation in Investor-State Arbitration’ in P Pazartzis & Panos Merkouris (eds), Permutations of Responsibility in International Law (Brill Nijhoff 2019) 188–9. See, for example, SD Myers v Canada (Partial Award of 13 November 2000) UNCITRAL [312–15]; CME Czech Republic BV v Czech Republic (Partial Award of 13 September 2001) UNCITRAL [583]; Arif v Moldova (Award of 8 April 2013) ICSID Case No ARB/11/23 [559]; cases mentioned in (n 8). Only occasionally the tribunals recognise that the ILC Articles do not apply – for example: Wintershall v Argentina (Award of 8 December 2008) ICSID Case No ARB/04/14 [113].

12 De Brabandere explains that ‘the rules and principles relating to the forms of reparation are, however, similar when it is a nonstate entity that is entitled to invoke the responsibility of a state’ – De Brabandere (n 7) 178, fn 12.

13 For broader considerations see: F Balcerzak, Investor–State Arbitration and Human Rights (Brill Nijhoff 2017) 236–8.

14 Examples of cases referred to in (n 8) and (n 11).

15 ILC Articles (n 9) Art 55.

16 By way of an example, see ‘The Energy Charter Treaty’ (adopted 17 December 1994, entered into force 16 April 1998) 2080 UNTS 95, Art 26(8) (‘ECT’); ‘Agreement Between the United States of America, the United Mexican States, and Canada (‘USMCA’)’ (adopted 10 December 2019, entered into force 1 July 2020) Art 14.D.13(1)(b), which replaced the North American Free Trade Agreement (‘NAFTA’) (adopted 17 December 1992, entered into force 1 January 1994) 32 ILM 289, Art 1135, which has a similar wording; see also, ‘Convention on the Settlement of Investment Disputes Between States and Nationals of Other States’ (adopted 18 March 1965, entered into force 14 October 1966) 575 UNTS 159, Art 54(1), which refers solely to enforcing ‘the pecuniary obligations’ imposed by arbitral awards.

17 For example, the final sentence of the preamble to the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (adopted 23 May 1969, entered into force 27 January 1980) 1155 UNTS 331 (VCLT), states: ‘Affirming that the rules of customary international law will continue to govern questions not regulated by the provisions of the present Convention’.

18 I Marboe, ‘Assessing Compensation and Damages in Expropriation Versus Non-Expropriation Cases’ in CL Beharry (ed), Contemporary and Emerging Issues on the Law of Damages and Valuation in International Investment Arbitration (Brill Nijhoff 2018) 134–5. It is ‘a double-edged sword in the sense that it not only enables flexibility when responding to the variety of factual situations but also introduces subjectivity and discretion in the application of the legal principles’ – Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 21.

19 Metalclad v Mexico (Award of 30 August 2000) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/97/1 [122]. Foresight v Spain can serve as another example, where the Tribunal decided that ‘the Claimants are in principle entitled to full compensation for Spain’s violation of Article 10(1) ECT. The Tribunal shall now turn to the Parties’ respective submissions on quantum’ – Foresight v Spain (Final Award of 14 November 2018) SCC Case No 2015/150 [438].

20 There is a ‘primacy of restitution’ – ILC Articles (n 9) 96, commentary to Art 35 [3]; it is a ‘first-ranked’ remedy – Wälde & Sabahi (n 1) 1057.

21 Factory at Chorzów, 47. This should happen together with ‘damages for loss sustained which would not be covered by restitution in kind or payment in place of it’, which opens the floor for a discussion of moral damages. However, that issue falls outside the scope of this chapter.

22 Rubins et al (n 8) 172.

23 ILC Articles (n 9) 95, commentary to Art 34 [2] 95.

24 For example: C Schreuer, ‘Non-Pecuniary Remedies in ICSID Arbitration’ (2004) 20(4) Arbitration International 325, 331–2.

25 Pezold v Zimbabwe (Award of 28 July 2015) ICSID Case No ARB/10/15 [700, 723], in [1020.1] which actually ordered restitution. In other cases, tribunals have confirmed that this is possible, but decided on facts of the case not to order restitution – for example: Enron v Argentina (Decision on Jurisdiction of 14 January 2004) ICSID Case No ARB/01/3 [79, 81]; Micula (I) v Romania (Final Award of 11 December 2013) ICSID Case No ARB/05/20 [1309–11]; Micula (I) v Romania (Decision on Jurisdiction and Admissibility of 24 September 2008) ICSID Case No. ARB/05/20 [166–8]; Al-Bahloul v Tajikistan (Final Award of 8 June 2010) SCC Case No V (064/2008) [63]; cases mentioned in (n 32).

26 C Malinvaud, ‘Non-pecuniary Remedies in Investment Treaty and Commercial Arbitration’ in AJ van den Berg (ed), 50 Years of the New York Convention: ICCA International Arbitration Conference (Kluwer Law International 2009) 210. Compensation is ‘perhaps the most commonly sought in international practice’ in general, not merely in investor-State arbitration. See ILC Articles (n 9) 99, commentary to Art 36 [2].

27 See examples in (n 16). Even though ECT, NAFTA and USMCA formally allow restitution, they require restitution orders to permit the alternative of paying compensation.

28 ILC Articles (n 9) 120, commentary to Art 43 [6].

29 Wälde & Sabahi (n 1) 1059. This principle is expressed in the Latin maxim non ultra petita.

30 Malinvaud (n 26) 221; Schreuer (n 24) 329; Balcerzak (n 13) 221–2. Sometimes, after initially presenting the claim for restitution, it was abandoned in the course of the proceedings – for example: South American Silver v Bolivia (Award of 22 November 2018) PCA Case No 2013–15 [797].

31 Rubins et al (n 8) 171.

32 Eiser v Spain (Final Award of 4 May 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/13/36 [155, 425]; Masdar Solar v Spain (Award of 16 May 2018) ICSID Case No ARB/14/1 [554–5]; Antin v Spain (Award of 15 June 2018) ICSID Case No ARB/13/31 [631]; RREEF v Spain (Decision on Responsibility and on the Principles of Quantum of 30 November 2018) ICSID Case No ARB/13/30 [11, 473]; RWE v Spain (Decision on Jurisdiction, Liability and Certain Issues of Quantum of 30 December 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/14/34 [681–3]; PV Investors v Spain (Final Award of 28 February 2020) PCA Case No 2012–14 [665] (although the claim for restitution ‘was abandoned’ in the course of the proceedings); Watkins Holdings v Spain (Award of 21 January 2020) ICSID Case No ARB/15/44 [632–4]. Notably, the claimants in all of these cases were represented by the same law firm.

33 Although the Tribunal in Cube v Spain observed that ordering restitution is ‘beyond the proper scope of the powers of the Tribunal and is moreover plainly materially impossible and disproportionately burdensome’. The claimant did not request restitution, so this observation was made by the tribunal without having heard the parties’ submissions on that issue. See Cube v Spain (Decision on Jurisdiction, Liability and Partial Decision on Quantum of 19 February 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/15/20 [460].

34 ILC Articles (n 9) 99, commentary to Art 36 [3].

35 Masdar v Spain [563].

36 Eiser v Spain [425]; Antin v Spain [636–7] (‘disproportional to its interference with the sovereignty of the State compared to monetary compensation’); Watkins v Spain [674] (restitution ‘is an inappropriate remedy because the Respondent has a sovereign right to take appropriate legislative and regulatory measures to meet public interests’).

37 Masdar v Spain [559]. In similar vein RREEF v Spain [473].

38 RWE v Spain [685], adding that breaches of the ECT were found only with respect to part of the claimant’s plants.

39 NAFTA, Art 1135(1)(b). The same wording was repeated in USMCA, Art 14.D.13(1)(b), which replaced NAFTA. Similarly, ECT, Art 26(8), provided that the respondent ‘may pay monetary damages in lieu of any other remedy granted’.

40 Marboe (n 18) 117.

41 For example: RREEF v Spain [597]; Cube v Spain [532].

42 Bernhard von Pezold v Zimbabwe [925, 1020.2].

43 Rubins et al (n 8) 172–3.

44 Marboe (n 18) 117.

45 ILC Articles (n 9) 95, commentary to Art 34 [2].

46 Rubins et al (n 8) 172–3.

47 ILC Articles (n 9) Art 37(1).

48 ILC Articles (n 9) 106–7, commentary to Art 37 [6]; the Tribunal in Europe Cement v Turkey expressly recognised ‘the reasoning and conclusions set out in this Award’ as ‘a form of “satisfaction” for the Respondent’ (Europe Cement v Turkey (Award of 13 August 2009) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/07/2 [181]).

49 For example: United Nations Convention on Transparency in Treaty-based Investor-State Arbitration (Mauritius Convention on Transparency) (adopted 10 December 2014, entered into force 18 October 2017) No 54749.

50 ILC Articles (n 9) Art 37(2).

51 Which binds tribunals (n 29).

52 For example: Enkev v Poland (First Partial Award of 29 April 2014) PCA Case No 2013–01 [121]; RREEF v Spain [11].

53 Or, to word it differently, between ‘treaty violative’ and ‘treaty compliant’ expropriations. See S Ratner, ‘Compensation for Expropriations in a World of Investment Treaties: Beyond the Lawful/Unlawful Distinction’ (2017) 111(1) AJIL 7, 16.

54 MN Shaw, International Law (8th edn, CUP 2017) 627.

55 R Dolzer & C Schreuer, Principles of International Investment Law (2nd edn, OUP 2012) 136; Siag v Egypt (Award of 1 June 2009) ICSID Case No ARB/05/15 [428]. On the division between compensable (expropriatory) and non-compensable (non-expropriatory) States’ actions see, for example: M Żenkiewicz, ‘Compensable vs. Non-Compensable States’ Measures: Blurred Picture Under Investment Law’ (2020) 17(3) MJIEL 362.

56 For example: art VI of the Agreement Between the Government of Canada and the Government of the Republic of Poland for the Promotion and Reciprocal Protection of Investments (Canada & Poland) (adopted 6 April 1990, entered into force 22 November 1990) (‘BIT Poland - Canada (1990)’). This reflects the Hull formula – Wälde, Sabahi (n 1) 1068.

57 For example, ‘genuine’ having the same meaning as ‘adequate’, ie ‘fair market value’. See Rusoro Mining v Venezuela (Award of 22 August 2016) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/12/5 [646–7].

58 For example, the Agreement Between the Government of Canada and the Government of the Republic of Poland for the Promotion and Reciprocal Protection of Investments (Canada & Poland) (adopted 6 April 1990, entered into force 22 November 1990) (‘BIT Poland - Canada (1990)’) Art VI (‘Such compensation shall be based on the real value of the investment at the time of the expropriation, shall be made within two months of the date of expropriation, after which interest at the rate agreed between the investor and the Contracting Party concerned and in no case less than the London Inter Sank Offered Rate (L1S0R) shall accrue until the date of payment […]’).

59 Marboe (n 18) 123; Guideline IV(3) of the World Bank, ‘Legal Framework for the Treatment of Foreign Investment, Vol 2: Report to the Development Committee and Guidelines on the Treatment of Foreign Direct Investment’ (World Bank Report, 25 September 1992) reproduced in (1992) 31 ILM 1363, Guideline IV(3); see also, Poland Business and Economic Relations Treaty (USA & Poland) (adopted 21 March 1990, entered into force 6 August 1994) Art VII(1): ‘Compensation shall be equivalent to the fair market value of the expropriated investment […]’.

60 Rusoro Mining v Venezuela [751]; see also, Khan Resources v Mongolia (Award on the Merits of 2 March 2015) UNCITRAL [378].

61 Marboe (n 18) 122.

62 De Brabandere (n 7) 179; ADC v Hungary [481].

63 Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 65–6; Marboe (n 18) 132–3; ADC v Hungary [499]; Siemens v Argentina [352]; Tza Yap Shum v Peru [253]; Quiborax v Bolivia (Award of 16 September 2015) ICSID Case No ARB/06/2 [326]; Tidewater v Venezuela (Award 13 March 2015) ICSID Case No ARB/10/5 [142]; ConocoPhillips v Venezuela (Decision on Jurisdiction and Merits of 3 September 2013) ICSID Case No ARB/07/30 [342–3].

64 For example, Pezold v Zimbabwe [497–8]; Unglaube v Costa Rica [305]; Crystallex v Venezuela (Award of 4 April 2016) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/11/2 [716].

65 For example: Tidewater v Venezuela [140]; Venezuela Holdings v Venezuela (Award of 9 October 2014) ICSID Case No ARB/07/27 [301] (this award was annulled, but not in the part referred to – Venezuela Holdings v Venezuela (Decision on Annulment of 9 March 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/07/27 [196(4)]).

66 Tidewater v Venezuela [145].

67 Venezuela Holdings v Venezuela (Award) [306]. Similarly, ConocoPhillips v Venezuela [362].

68 MW Friedman & F Lavaud, ‘Damages Principles in Investment Arbitration’ in JA Trenor (ed), The Guide to Damages in International Arbitration (3rd edn, Global Arbitration Review 2018) 104.

69 Marboe (n 18) 126.

70 In addition, compensation for unlawful expropriation can cover additional harm, beyond the loss of the property. See Ratner (n 53) 21.

71 For example: ADC v Hungary [497, 499]; Pezold v Zimbabwe [813]; Quiborax v Bolivia [370, 377]; Siemens v Argentina [352]; Kardassopoulos v Georgia (Award of 3 March 2010) ICSID Case No ARB/05/18 [514]; El Paso Energy International Company v Argentina (Award of 31 October 2011) ICSID Case No ARB/03/15 [704, 706].

72 Factory at Chorzów 47.

73 Phillips Petroleum v Iran (Award of 29 June 1989 (Award No 425-39-2)) Case No 39, 21 IUSCT 79 [110].

74 See (n 60).

75 Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 256; El Paso Energy v Argentina [704]; Quiborax v Bolivia [370, 379].

76 Amco v Indonesia (Award of 31 May 1990) ICSID Case No ARB/81/8 [186].

77 Quiborax v Bolivia [377].

78 Marboe (n 18) 132–3.

79 Hulley Enterprises v Russia (Final Award of 18 July 2014) PCA Case No AA 226 [1768]; Yukos Universal Ltd v Russia (Final Award of 18 July 2014) PCA Case No AA227 [1768]; Veteran Petroleum v Russia (Final Award 18 July 2014) PCA Case No AA 228 [1768]. Another scenario is that the value of the expropriated investment initially increased after the expropriation but decreased later. To allow the claimant to choose the most favorable moment between the expropriation date and the date of the award, the claimant would need to satisfy the burden of proof that it would have disposed of the property at the ‘peak’ of its value, which would rarely be capable of being established.

80 For example: Unión Fenosa v Egypt (Award of 31 August 2018) ICSID Case No ARB/14/4 [10.96]; Murphy v Ecuador (Award of 6 May 2016) PCA Case No AA434 [423]; Lemire v Ukraine (Award of 28 March 2011) ICSID Case No ARB/06/18 [149]; White Industries v India (Final Award of 30 November 2011) UNCITRAL [14.3.3]; Novenergia II v Spain (Final Award of 15 February 2018) SCC Case No 2015/063 [807].

81 The use of non-financial remedies for non-expropriatory treaty violations include examples such as an order to refrain from discriminatory treatment, to re-issue an administrative or judicial decision in full compliance with due process, or to seek other administrative remedies that provide full satisfaction – Wälde & Sabahi (n 1) 1115–16.

82 For example: Vivendi (I) v Argentina (Final Award of 20 August 2007) ICSID Case No ARB/97/3 [8.2.8]; in BG Group v Argentina the Tribunal observed that while it was ‘disinclined to automatically import’ standard of fair market value envisaged for lawful expropriation, ‘this standard of compensation is nonetheless available by reference to customary international law’ and applied it to breach of the fair and equitable treatment and prohibition of unreasonable measures – BG Group v Argentina (Final Award of 24 December 2007) UNCITRAL [422]. The standard of compensation for expropriation is ‘relatively well established’ when compared to compensation for breaches of other standards commonly found in investment treaties. See Wälde & Sabahi (n 1) 1082.

83 ILC Articles (n 9) 105, commentary to Art 36 [33].

84 Although, for example, in Novenergia v Spain, the value of the claim for expropriation was lower than the claim for violation of other ECT standards – Novenergia v Spain [811].

85 Antin v Spain [688].

86 Eiser v Spain [473]. Tribunal in Masdar v Spain rejected test of ‘confidence approaching absolute certainty’ – Masdar v Spain [576]. Tribunal in Infrared v Spain observed: ‘no model or methodology for assessing damages can determine with absolute precision the loss visited on an investor by a regulatory change, given the many uncertainties and variables inherent in projecting revenues, costs and risk over time. The method used must rather be reasonable in the light of all the circumstances’ – Infrared v Spain (Award of 2 August 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/14/12 [533].

87 Novenergia v Spain [820].

88 Rubins et al (n 8) 185; Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 193, 214. It remains unclear how to categorise asset-based methodologies, which value investments by summing up their individual assets (Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 218). This group consists of book value, replacement value and liquidation value methodologies. Whilst book value is clearly a backward-looking methodology (Rubins et al (n 8) 198), classification of the remaining two into this category is more debatable.

89 Wälde & Sabahi (n 1) 1072–3.

90 Footnote ibid 1066, in the context of the backward-looking methodologies and the traditional division between damnum emergens and lucrum cessans. Similarly, on Footnote ibid 1073, when they provide an example of investment in petroleum, where most exploration wells are unsuccessful (dry), but they ‘get compensated by the few successful results of a drilling campaign. This means that the value of the successful exploration is – often by a multiple – much more than the expenditures incurred. In essence, expenses have either to be multiplied by the exploration risk (historic method) or in this situation (and other comparable situations where a particular high risk is overcome) one needs to look at comparable transactions and forecasts of future income. A combination of historic cost (adjusted by exploration risk), future income, and market-value-based valuations is here called for’.

91 Their object is considered to ‘ensure full reparation in accordance with the Chorzów principle’ – I Uchkunova & O Temnikov, ‘A Procrustean Bed: Pre- and Post-award Interest in ICSID Arbitration’ (2014) 29(3) ICSID Rev 648, 651; for example: Occidental v Ecuador (Award of 5 October 2012) ICSID Case No ARB/06/11 [834]; Vivendi (I) v Argentina [9.2.6].

92 ILC Articles (n 9) 108, commentary to Art 38, [7], a contrario 105, commentary to Art 36 [33].

93 CL Beharry, ‘Prejudgment Interest Rates in International Investment Arbitration’ (2016) 8(1) JIDS 56, 56–7. Gotanda defines interest as compensation ‘for the temporary withholding of money’ or ‘for the loss of the use of money’. See JY Gotanda, ‘Compound Interest in International Disputes’ (2003) 34(2) Law & PolIntBus 393, 395–6.

94 Beharry (n 93) 61.

95 Quiborax v Bolivia [513].

96 This is possible when using forward-looking methodologies. For example, the Tribunal in Quiborax v Bolivia included interest accrued on past cash flows in the total value of past cash flows calculated using the Discounted Cash Flow method. See Quiborax v Bolivia [515].

97 For example: Eiser v Spain [474].

98 However, some authors classify the market-based approach as a backward-looking methodology – Wälde & Sabahi (n 1) 1070–1, 1074.

99 Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 195; see also G Rush, K Sequeira & M Shopp, ‘Valuation Techniques for Early-Stage Businesses in Investor-State Arbitration’ in CL Beharry (ed), Contemporary and Emerging Issues on the Law of Damages and Valuation in International Investment Arbitration (Brill Nijhoff 2018) 273.

100 This is understood as meaning that a business is in operation and has a track record of cash flows – Antin v Spain [689]. This is the prevailing approach in the case law, but from the financial perspective it is not necessarily a pre-condition for applying the DCF method – KF Schumacher & H Klönne, ‘Discounted Cash Flow Method’ in CL Beharry (ed), Contemporary and Emerging Issues on the Law of Damages and Valuation in International Investment Arbitration (Brill Nijhoff 2018) 212.

101 Ripinsky & Williams (n 1) 279, 289.

102 Footnote ibid 212.

103 ‘Market capitalization’, calculated based on a price of shares on the stock market would also fall within the category of market-based methodology – Rubins et al (n 8) 190.

104 Rush et al (n 99) 262, 288; Schumacher & Klönne (n 100) 207.

105 For example, CIMVAL Standards and Guidelines 2003 provide that an income-based approach may be a suitable method of valuation for any type of mineral property save for an exploration property (CIMVAL, ‘Standards and Guidelines for Valuation of Mineral Properties: Special Committee of the Canadian Institute of Mining, Metallurgy and Petroleum on Valuation of Mineral Properties’ (CIMVAL, 2003) 22 <https://mrmr.cim.org/media/1020/cimval-standards-guidelines.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022). This was confirmed in CIMVAL Code 2019 (CIMVAL, ‘The CIMVAL Code for the Valuation of Mineral Properties’ (CIMVAL, 2019) 16 <https://mrmr.cim.org/media/1135/cimval-code-november2019.pdf> accessed 1 June 2022).

106 Rubins et al (n 8) 200.

107 Bear Creek Mining Corporation v Peru (Award of 30 November 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/14/21 [604].

108 Khan Resources v Mongolia [392].

109 Al-Bahloul v Tajikistan [96].

110 Caratube v Kazakhstan (Award of 27 September 2017) ICSID Case No ARB/13/13 [1094].

111 Khan Resources v Mongolia [398].

112 South American Silver v Bolivia [838]; similarly, Caratube v Kazakhstan [1133].

113 Bear Creek v Peru [604]; South American Silver v Bolivia [866]; Caratube v Kazakhstan [1164].

114 Khan Resources v Mongolia [410–1].

115 For example, the Tribunal in Khan Resources v Mongolia [392] observed: ‘in this particular case, there are a number of additional factors and uncertainties which, in the Tribunal’s view, make the use of the DCF method unattractive and speculative’. The Tribunal in Al-Bahloul v Tajikistan [74–6] observed that ‘under exceptional circumstances DCF-analysis might be appropriate where the investment project at issue had not started operation’, which ‘might be justified, inter alia, where the exploration of hydrocarbons is at issue. The determination of the future cash flows from the exploitation of hydrocarbon reserves need not depend on a past record of profitability. There are numerous hydrocarbons reserves around the world and sufficient data allowing for future cash flows projections should be available to allow a DCF-calculation’. The Tribunal did not apply DCF because ‘no hydrocarbons have yet been found’ in the disputed concessions.

116 Tethyan Copper v Pakistan (Award of 12 July 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/12/1 [330, 335].

117 Crystallex v Venezuela [878, 880, 882–3], relied on estimations of proven and probable reserves and measured and indicated resources in accordance with international standards.

118 Gold Reserve Inc v Venezuela (Award of 22 September 2014) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/09/1 [830]: ‘Although the Brisas Project was never a functioning mine and therefore did not have a history of cashflow which would lend itself to the DCF model, the Tribunal accepts the explanation of both Dr Burrows (CRA) and Mr Kaczmarek (Navigant) that a DCF method can be reliably used in the instant case because of the commodity nature of the product and detailed mining cashflow analysis previously performed’.

119 From a financial perspective, the limitations identified by tribunals ‘are not impediments per se to applying the DCF method’, but rather factors to be included in the DCF models – Schumacher & Klönne (n 100) 211–12.

120 Crystallex v Venezuela [880]; Khan Resources v Mongolia [391].

121 Crystallex v Venezuela [879].

122 Rusoro Mining v Venezuela [759].

124 Khan Resources v Mongolia [392].

125 R Caldwell, D Chodorow & F Dorobantu, ‘Valuing Natural Resources Investments’ in CL Beharry (ed), Contemporary and Emerging Issues on the Law of Damages and Valuation in International Investment Arbitration (Brill Nijhoff 2018) 293.

126 Eiser v Spain [465]; Novenergia v Spain [818, 820]; Masdar v Spain [575, 581]; Antin v Spain [688–91]; Foresight v Spain [474, 530]; Cube v Spain [478]; Infrared v Spain [521]; OperaFund v Spain [621]; Watkins v Spain [689]; PV Investors v Spain [691, 697]; SolEs v Spain (Award of 31 July 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/15/38 [488]; 9REN v Spain (Award of 31 May 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/15/15 [407]. The ECT was the applicable investment treaty in these cases.

127 Caldwell et al (n 125) 302–3.

128 Footnote ibid 294. The difference is that although the development of a renewable energy power plant is a long process which takes several years, it is still shorter than an investment in developing a mine, which is preceded by exploration activities.

129 Novenergia v Spain [820]. See also Cube v Spain [478]; Infrared v Spain [535].

130 In Eiser v Spain [121] the plants began operation in 2012; in Masdar v Spain [98–9] – at the end of 2011; in Infrared v Spain [57–8] in 2012; in RREEF v Spain [169, 173] one of the power plants became operational in 2013, although the other one was operational already in 2008. Contested violations of the ECT concerned a series of measures taken between 2012 and 2014, whereas the respondent ‘crossed the line’ in June 2014; for example: Eiser v Spain 458; see also: Caldwell et al (n 125) 300–1; in NextEra v Spain, however, an operational history of less than 1 year was the basis for refusing to apply the DCF method – NextEra v Spain (Award of 12 March 2019) ICSID Case No ARB/14/11 [643, 647].

13 A TWAIL Engagement with Customary International Investment Law Some Strategies for Interpretation

* Nina Mileva is a PhD candidate and lecturer at the University of Groningen. This contribution is based on research conducted in the context of the project ‘The Rules of Interpretation of Customary International Law’ (‘TRICI-Law’). This project has received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Research and Innovation Programme (Grant Agreement No 759728).

1 JT Gathii, ‘The Promise of International Law: A Third World View’ (2021) 36(3) American University International Law Review 377; JT Gathii, ‘The Agenda of Third World Approaches in International Law’ in J Dunoff & M Pollack (eds), International Legal Theory: Foundations and Frontiers (CUP 2022) ch 7.

2 A Bianchi, International Law Theories: An Inquiry into Different Ways of Thinking (OUP 2016) 203–4.

3 Gathii 2022 (n 1). For an additional commentary on the geographical counterparts of these categories, see JC Okubuiro, ‘Application of Hegemony to Customary International Law: An African Perspective’ (2018) 7 Global Journal of Comparative Law 232.

4 L Eslava & S Pahuja, ‘Between Resistance and Reform: TWAIL and the Universality of International Law’ (2011) 3 Trade, Law and Development 103, 104; See also K Mickelson, ‘Rhetoric and Rage: Third World Voices in International Legal Discourse’ (1998) 16(2) Wisconsin International Law Journal 353.

5 Bianchi calls this TWAIL’s ‘ambivalent posture towards international law’, variously regarding international law as either the problem or the solution to the world’s injustices. Bianchi (n 2) 207–8.

6 BS Chimni, ‘Customary International Law: A Third World Perspective’ (2018) 112(1) AJIL 1, 4–12; GRB Gallindo & C Yip, ‘Customary International Law and the Third World: Do Not Step on the Grass’ (2017) 16(2) Chin J Int Law 251; JP Kelly, ‘Customary International Law in Historical Context: The Exercise of Power without General Acceptance’ in BD Lepard (ed), Reexamining Customary International Law (CUP 2017) 47; see also KJ Heller, ‘Specially Affected States and the Formation of Custom’ (2018) 112(2) AJIL 191.

7 Kelly (n 6) 59–73 particularly focusing on the origins of the customary MST; A Anghie, Imperialism, Sovereignty and the Making of International Law (CUP 2007) 214.

8 Anghie (n 7).

9 M Sornarajah, ‘Mutations of Neo-Liberalism in International Investment Law’ (2011) 3 Trade Law and Development 203; M Sornarajah, The International Law on Foreign Investment (3rd edn, CUP 2010).

10 UNGA, ‘Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States’ (12 December 1974) UN Doc A/RES/3281(XXIX); See also, M Bedjaoui, Towards a New International Economic Order (Holmes & Meier 1979).

11 Bianchi (n 2) 213.

12 See, however, Bianchi who argues that the NIEO effort yielded changes in the international law-making process by introducing the notion of soft-law, and introducing a relative vision of normativity in this respect. Bianchi (n 2) 214.

13 A Anghie & BS Chimni, ‘Third World Approaches to International Law and Individual Responsibility in Internal Conflicts’ (2003) 2 Chin J Int Law 78.

14 Sornarajah 2011 (n 9) 204.

15 J Linarelli, ME Salomon & M Sornarajah, The Misery of International Law: Confrontations with Injustice in the Global Economy (OUP 2018) 145–74.

16 Sornarajah 2011 (n 9) 205.

17 IT Odumosu, ‘The Law and Politics of Engaging Resistance in Dispute Settlement’ (2007) 26 Penn State Int Law Rev 251.

18 Kelly (n 6) 51–74.

19 Anghie (n 7) 210–15.

20 S Pahuja, Decolonising International Law: Development, Economic Growth and the Politics of Universality (CUP 2011) 102–71.

21 Linarelli, Salomon & Sornarajah (n 15) 147; G Abi-Saab, ‘The Third World Intellectual in Praxis: Confrontation, Participation, or Operation behind Enemy Lines’ (2016) 37(11) Third World Quarterly 1957, 1969.

22 See, for example, the reasoning of the Tribunal in Técnicas Medioambientales Tecmed, SA v Mexico (Award of 29 May 2003) ICSID No ARB(AF)/00/2 [119–32].

23 Odumosu (n 17) 265–99.

24 See, for instance, North Sea Continental Shelf Cases (Federal Republic of Germany/Netherlands; Federal Republic of Germany/Denmark) (Judgment) [1969] ICJ Rep 3, Dissenting Opinion of Judge Tanaka, 183; Arrest Warrant of 11 April 2000 (Congo v Belgium) (Judgment) [2002] ICJ Rep 3 [52–4]; Pulp Mills on the River Uruguay (Argentina v Uruguay) (Judgment) [2010] ICJ Rep 14 [101–2, 204]; Mondev International Ltd v USA (Award of 11 October 2002) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/99/2 [113]; See also, P Merkouris, Article 31(3)(c) VCLT and the Principle of Systemic Integration: Normative Shadows in Plato’s Cave (Brill 2015) 241.

25 For an earlier discussion of this concept of a CIL timeline, see N Mileva, ‘The Role of Domestic Courts in the Interpretation of Customary International Law: How Can We Learn from Domestic Interpretive Practices?’ in P Merkouris, J Kammerhofer & N Arajärvi (eds), The Theory, Practice, and Interpretation of Customary International Law (CUP 2022) 453, 458–61, <https://www.cambridge.org/core/services/aop-cambridge-core/content/view/630E681903F80296865C48617CCA5C14/9781316516898c21_453-480.pdf/role_of_domestic_courts_in_the_interpretation_of_customary_international_law.pdf>.

26 Merkouris (n 24) 134–5.

27 O Chasapis Tassinis, ‘Customary International Law: Interpretation from Beginning to End’ (2020) 31(1) EJIL 235, 240–4.

28 On this point, see for more details, ILC, ‘Draft Conclusions on Identification of Customary International Law, with Commentaries’ (30 April–1 June and 2 July–10 August 2018) UN Doc A/73/10, reproduced in [2018/II – Part Two] YBILC 122, Conclusion 6, Conclusion 10.

29 See, for instance, A Roberts, ‘Traditional and Modern Approaches to Customary International Law: A Reconciliation’ (2001) 95(4) AJIL 757; N Banteka, ‘A Theory of Constructive Interpretation for Customary International Law Identification’ (2018) 39(3) MichJInt’l Law 301; DB Hollis, ‘The Existential Function of Interpretation in International Law’ in A Bianchi, D Peat & M Windsor (eds), Interpretation in International Law (OUP 2015) 78.

30 M Waibel, ‘Interpretive Communities in International Law’ in A Bianchi, D Peat & M Windsor (eds), Interpretation in International Law (OUP 2015) 147, 155–8; see also, Azaria who speaks of the interpretive authority of the ILC, D Azaria, ‘Codification by Interpretation: The International Law Commission as an Interpreter of International Law’ (2020) 31(1) EJIL 171.

31 See A Bianchi, ‘Epistemic Communities’ in J d’Aspremont & S Singh (eds), Concepts for International Law: Contributions to Disciplinary Thought (Edward Elgar 2019) 251; Waibel (n 30) 147; I Johnstone, ‘Treaty Interpretation: The Authority of Interpretive Communities’ (1991) 12(2) MJInt’l Law 371. See also, Linderfalk who discusses various interpreters through the distinction between operative interpretation (performed by national courts, civil servants, military officials, diplomatic personnel, international courts and arbitration tribunals, international organisations, and other authorities empowered to decide on issues concerning the application of international agreements) and doctrinal interpretation (performed by scholars). U Linderfalk, On the Interpretation of Treaties: The Modern International Law as Expressed in the 1969 Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (Springer 2007) 12.

32 See R Mackenzie, C Romano & Y Shany (eds), The Manual on International Courts and Tribunals (2nd edn, OUP 2010); G Hernandez, ‘Interpretative Authority and the International Judiciary’ in A Bianchi, D Peat & M Windsor (eds), Interpretation in International Law (OUP 2015) 166.

33 A Bianchi, ‘The Game of Interpretation in International Law: The Players, the Cards, and Why the Game is Worth the Candle’ in A Bianchi, D Peat & Windsor (eds), Interpretation in International Law (OUP 2015) 34, 41.

34 Hernandez (n 32) 167.

35 Footnote ibid, 166; See also, A Zidar, ‘Interpretation and the International Legal Profession: Between Duty and Aspiration in A Bianchi, D Peat & M Windsor (eds), Interpretation in International Law (OUP 2015) 133, 134; H Kelsen, Pure Theory of Law (UC Press 1967) 354–5.

36 Hernandez (n 32) 166 [emphasis added]. See also, Waibel who discusses the centrality of judicial interpretation in international law with a particular focus on national courts as interpreters of international law. Waibel (n 25) 155–8.

37 For an earlier discussion of these two functions, see P Merkouris & N Mileva, ‘ESIIIL Reflection: Introduction to the Series “Customary Law Interpretation as a Tool”’ (2022) 11(1) ESIL Reflections 1 <https://esil-sedi.eu/wp-content/uploads/2022/08/ESIL-Reflection-Merkouris-Mileva.pdf> accessed 24 June 2023.

38 S Sur, ‘La créativité du droit international’ (2013) 363 RdC 21, 295; A Orakhelashvili, The Interpretation of Acts and Rules in Public International Law (OUP 2008) 496.

40 For a discussion on this, see CA Bradley, ‘Customary International Law Adjudication as Common Law Adjudication’ in CA Bradley (ed), Custom’s Future: International Law in a Changing World (CUP 2016) 34; BD Lepard, ‘Customary International Law as a Dynamic Process’ in CA Bradley (ed), Custom’s Future: International Law in a Changing World (CUP 2016) 62; O Sender & M Wood, ‘Custom’s Bright Future: The Continuing Importance of Customary International Law’ in CA Bradley (ed), Custom’s Future: International Law in a Changing World (CUP 2016) 360; J Tasioulas, ‘Customary International Law and the Quest for Global Justice’ in A Perreau-Saussine & JB Murphy (eds), The Nature of Customary International Law: Legal, Historical and Philosophical Perspectives (CUP 2007) 307.

41 On this point, see N Mileva & M Fortuna, ‘Environmental Protection as an Object of and Tool for Evolutionary Interpretation’ in G Abi-Saab et al (eds), Evolutionary Interpretation and International Law (Hart 2019) 152.

42 P Dumberry, The Formation and Identification of Rules of Customary International Law in International Investment Law (CUP 2016) 97.

44 See on this the reasoning of Germany with respect to customary rules applying to cyber operations. German Government, ‘On the Application of International Law in Cyberspace – Position Paper’ (Auswärtiges Amt, March 2021)

<www.auswaertiges-amt.de/blob/2446304/32e7b2498e10b74fb17204c54665bdf0/on-the-application-of-international-law-in-cyberspace-data.pdf> accessed 26 July 2022.

45 J d’Aspremont, ‘International Customary Investment Law: Story of a Paradox’ in Gazzini, T & de Brabandere, E (eds), International Investment Law: The Sources of Rights and Obligation (Brill 2012) 5, 34.

46 E Root, ‘The Basis of Protection to Citizens Residing Abroad’ (1910) 4 ASIL Proc 16, 21. ‘There is a standard of justice, very simple, very fundamental, and of such general acceptance by all civilized countries as to form a part of the international law of the world’.

47 See on this the detailed analysis in M Paparinskis, The International Minimum Standard and Fair and Equitable Treatment (OUP 2013) 39–63.

48 USA (LFH Neer) v Mexico (Award of 15 October 1926) 4 RIAA 60 [4]. See Patrick Dumberry also flags other contemporaneous cases as relevant to the emergence of the minimum standard. Dumberry (n 42) 65, referencing USA (Harry Roberts) v Mexico (Award of 2 November 1926) 4 RIAA 77; France (Affaire Chevreau) v UK (Award of 9 June 1931) 2 RIAA 1113; and USA (Hopkins) v Mexico (1926) 4 RIAA 41.

49 Paparinskis (n 47) 48–54.

50 See, for instance, the positions of both USA and Canada as expressed during the proceedings of ADF Group Inc v USA. ADF Group Inc v USA (Canada’s Second Article 1128 Submission of 19 July 2002) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/00/1 [8–10]; ADF Group Inc v USA (Transcript of Hearing: Day 2 of 16 April 2002) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/00/1, 492–3.

51 Paparinskis (n 47) 64, 65–7. See also the discussion in the ILC on State responsibility, discussing also an international standard in relation to the protection of property of aliens. ILC, ‘Summary Records of the 8th Session’ (23 April–4 July 1956) [1956/1] YBILC 1, 233–8.

52 H Dickerson, ‘Minimum Standards’ [2013] MPEPIL 845 [12–13].

53 See discussion in Section 2 above.

54 Case concerning Elettronica Sicula SpA (ELSI) (USA v Italy) (Judgment) [1989] ICJ Rep 15 [111]. This makes sense in light of the fact that the relevant treaty provision provided for ‘the full protection and security required by international law’.

55 Footnote ibid. In the particular circumstances, however, the court found that the temporal delay in proceedings complained by the applicant did not amount to such a denial. Footnote ibid [112].

56 Pope & Talbot Inc v Canada (Award in Respect of Damages of 31 May 2002) UNCITRAL [63].

57 Mondev International Ltd v USA (Award of 11 October 2002) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/99/2 [113–15].

58 Footnote ibid [116]. ‘[…] In the light of these developments it is unconvincing to confine the meaning of “fair and equitable treatment” and “full protection and security” of foreign investments to what those terms – had they been current at the time – might have meant in the 1920s when applied to the physical security of an alien. To the modern eye, what is unfair or inequitable need not equate with the outrageous or the egregious’.

59 Footnote ibid [119–20].

60 Footnote ibid [121–5].

61 Footnote ibid, referring to Elettronica Sicula SpA (ELSI) [128].

62 Azinian v Mexico (Award of 1 November 1999) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/97/2 [99–103].

63 Loewen Group, Inc and Raymond L Loewen v USA (Award of 26 June 2003) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/98/3 [131–3].

64 Waste Management, Inc v Mexico (“Number 2”) (Award of 30 April 2004) ICSID Case No ARB(AF)/00/3 [98].

65 P Dumberry, ‘Fair and Equitable Treatment: Its Interaction with the Minimum Standard and its Customary Status’ (2017) 1(2) Brill Research Perspectives in International Investment Law and Arbitration 1, 17–18; See also, A Newcombe & L Paradell, Law and Practice of Investment Treaties: Standards of Treatment (Kluwer 2009); Paparinskis (n 47).

66 Giannakopoulos and Monga refer to this as a ‘feedback loop’. C Giannakopoulos & M Monga, ‘History as Interpretative Context in the Evolutionary Interpretation of FET in International Investment Law’ in G Abi-Saab et al (eds), Evolutionary Interpretation and International Law (Hart 2019) 297, 308.

67 Dickerson (n 52) [23].

68 JH Fahner, ‘Maximising Investment Protection under the Minimum Standard – A Case Study of the Evolutive Interpretation and Application of Customary International Law in Investment Arbitration’ (2023) 12(1) ESIL Reflections 1 <https://esil-sedi.eu/esil-reflection-maximising-investment-protection-under-the-minimum-standard-a-case-study-of-the-evolutive-interpretation-and-application-of-customary-international-law-in-investment-arbitration-2/> accessed 24 June 2023.

69 See, for instance, Windstream v Canada (Award of 27 September 2016) PCA Case No 2013–22 [379]; Eco Oro Minerals Corp v Colombia (Decision on Jurisdiction, Liability and Directions on Quantum of 9 September 2021) ICSID Case No ARB/16/41 [805–21].

70 Fahner (n 68).

71 Bilcon v Canada (Award on Jurisdiction and Liability of 17 March 2015) PCA Case No. 2009–04 [433–6].

72 Footnote ibid [603].

73 The pertinent portion of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) (adopted 17 December 1992, entered into force 1 January 1994) 32 ILM 289, Art 1105 is: ‘Each Party shall accord to investments of investors of another Party treatment in accordance with international law, including fair and equitable treatment and full protection and security’. In an interpretative note issued in 2001, NAFTA parties clarified that Art. 1105 prescribes the customary MST as the relevant standard of treatment to be afforded to investments, that this standard includes fair and equitable treatment and full protection of security, and these latter two do not require treatment in addition to or beyond the customary MST.

74 See on this point Fahner (n 68) criticising the reasoning in Pope & Talbot in these terms.

75 Dickerson (n 52) [23].

76 However, see Dumberry discussing Article 8.10 of the EU-Canada Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agrement (CETA) as bypassing the uncertainty inherent in the customary MST by codifying particular obligations which ostensibly derive from the customary standard. Dumberry (n 65) 42–45.

77 Pahuja (n 20) 1.

78 Footnote ibid, 260.

79 Abi-Saab (n 21) 1957.

80 See, for instance, BS Chimni, ‘Third World Approaches to International Law: A Manifesto’ in A Anghie et al (eds), The Third World and International Order: Law, Politics and Globalization (Brill 2003) 47.

81 R Collins & A Bohm, ‘International Law as Professional Practice: Crafting the Autonomy of International Law’ in J d’Aspremont et al (eds), International Law as a Profession (CUP 2017) 67.

82 JT Gathii, ‘Third World Approaches to International Economic Governance’ in R Falk, B Rajagopal & J Stevens (eds), International Law and the Third World (Routledge 2008) 255; G Van Harten, ‘TWAIL and the Dabhol Arbitration’ (2011) 3(1) Trade, Law and Development 131; AR Hippolyte, ‘Correcting TWAIL’s Bind Spots: A Plea for a Pragmatic Approach to International Economic Governance’ (2016) 18 ICLR 34.

83 Gathii (n 82) 255–6.

84 Van Harten (n 82) 147–60.

85 Footnote ibid, 137.

86 Footnote ibid, 148–60.

87 Hippolyte (n 82) 50–2.

88 Odumosu (n 17) 271–87.

89 See on this point Georges Abi-Saab: ‘The interpretative operation yields a final product, also referred to as “interpretation”, consisting of a rendering of the meaning of the interpreted text. In evaluating the “authority” of this final product, ie, the weight it carries in the eyes of the community, particularly the legal community, one has to keep in mind the interpreter’s status and position: interpretation by whom and for what purpose?’. G Abi-Saab, ‘Introduction: A Meta-Question’ in G Abi-Saab et al (eds), Evolutionary Interpretation and International Law (Hart 2019) 7, 10.

90 Giannakopoulos & Monga (n 66) 303–4.

91 J Paine, ‘The Judicial Dimension of Regime Interaction beyond Systemic Integration’ in S Trevisanut, N Giannopoulos & R Roland Holst (eds), Regime Interaction in Ocean Governance: Problems, Theories and Methods (Brill 2020) 184.

92 Abi-Saab argues that ‘In contrast to the WTO […] when it comes to ICSID arbitrations, the enemy is clearly there. Not only is the procedure tilted in favor of foreign investors (for example, they can initiate arbitration against the host State, but the reverse is not possible), but so are also a good majority of the players in the system, who do not hesitate grossly to misinterpret the rules of international law to suit their private purposes.’ Abi-Saab (n 19) 1969.

93 J Batura, J Hettihewa & P Kulish, ‘“I resigned because Russia had become an absolutely indefensible client”: an Interview with Alain Pellet’ (Völkerrechtsblog, 4 July 2022) <https://voelkerrechtsblog.org/de/i-resigned-because-russia-had-become-an-absolutely-indefensible-client/> accessed 25 July 2022.

94 See on this point T Sparks, N Nedeski & G Hernández, ‘Judging Climate Change Obligations: Can the World Court Rise to the Occasion? Part II: What Role for International Adjudication?’ (Völkerrechtsblog, 30 April 2020) <https://voelkerrechtsblog.org/judging-climate-change-obligations-can-the-world-court-raise-the-occasion-2/> accessed 25 July 2022.

95 See as an example of this strategy the argument developed by Sornarajah (n 9) 208.

96 Footnote ibid, 225–6.

97 See, for example, Sparks, Nedeski and Hernández who argue that ‘[i]n the context of catastrophic climate change legal analysis must understand State responsibility collectively: as shared responsibility’, and thus, argue for an interpretation of the no-harm rule which imposes more demanding obligations on states for their share in global emissions. T Sparks, N Nedeski & G Hernández, ‘Judging Climate Change Obligations: Can the World Court Rise to the Occasion? Part I: Primary Obligations to Combat Climate Change’ (Völkerrechtsblog, 30 April 2020) <https://voelkerrechtsblog.org/judging-climate-change-obligations-can-the-world-court-raise-the-occasion/> accessed 25 July 2022.

98 The ‘inherent plasticity’ of CIL is a term borrowed from the work of Chasapis Tassinis, and refers to the ability of custom to be molded into different shapes and lead to rules of different scope, without the need to add new state practice and opinio juris to the pool of evidence each time. Chasapis Tassinis (n 27) 248–55.

99 Odumosu (n 17) 269.

100 See, for example, the call of BS Chimni for a ‘postmodern approach’ to custom. Chimni (n 6).

101 A Peters, ‘Realizing Utopia as a Scholarly Endeavour’ (2013) 24(2) EJIL 533.

102 ICSID Rules of Procedure for Arbitration Proceedings (Arbitration Rules) (adopted 25 September 1967, entered into force 1 January 1968) Rule 37(2)

103 FTC, ‘Statement of the Free Trade Commission on Non-Disputing Party Participation’ (FTC, 7 October 2003) <www.sice.oas.org/tpd/nafta/commission/nondispute_e.pdf> accessed 25 July 2022.

104 For instance, Rule 37(2) of the ICSID Rules of Procedure for Arbitration Proceedings indicates that ‘After consulting both parties, the Tribunal may allow a person or entity […] to file a written submission’ and that such a submission may not ‘disrupt the proceeding or unduly burden or unfairly prejudice either party’. ICSID Rules of Procedure for Arbitration Proceedings (n 102) Rule 37(2).

105 Glamis Gold, Ltd v United States (Decision on Application and Submission by Quechan Indian Nation of 16 September 2005) UNCITRAL [11–13].

106 Pezold v Zimbabwe (Procedural Order No 2 of 26 June 2012) ICSID Case No ARB/10/15 [48–63].

107 Odumosu (n 17) 256–7.

108 J d’Aspremont, The Discourse on Customary International Law (OUP 2020) 84–7. In particular, d’Aspremont argues that ‘[i]nstead of striving to reinvent the doctrine of customary international law, we must invest in strategies that draw on the malleability and fluidity of the current doctrine of customary law and facilitate the types of argumentation that “de-centre” the First World’.

109 See, however, an analysis with similar conclusions about the constructive role of interpretation with respect to the customary rule of prevention. N Mileva, ‘The Role of Customary International Law Interpretation in the Balancing of Interests at Sea: The Example of Prevention’ (TRICI-Law Research Paper Series 010/2020, 2020) <https://tricilawofficial.files.wordpress.com/2021/06/mileva_rps-010-2020.pdf> accessed 25 July 2022.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×