Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-cjp7w Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-27T09:41:43.805Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - The King’s Money

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 March 2023

Noah Kaye
Affiliation:
Michigan State University

Summary

The ramified monetary system of the Attalid kingdom is described and its relationship to other monetary systems of the eastern Mediterranean in the Hellenistic period explained. The character of the cistophoric coinage was neither fully royal nor civic, but should rather be understood as a “coordinated coinage” that required the cooperation of both polis and Attalid authorities. Local monetary needs could dictate the shape of the money supply, as in the signal case of Tralles. The burden and profits of epichoric coinage at regional scale were shared, while the kings ceded symbolic space on the coin types for representations of civic identity. Cooperation can also be glimpsed in countermarks and proxy coinages. Unlike Ptolemaic Egypt, the Attalid kingdom was not a closed currency zone, though the cistophori helped integrate vast new territories. Their reduced weight standard economized on silver, but Pergamene mines existed in Anatolia and should be factored into explanatory models.

Type
Chapter
Information
The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
Money, Culture, and State Power
, pp. 129 - 187
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Up until now, our analysis of the Attalid political economy has traced patterns of interaction between royal and civic actors that help explain the success of the Pergamene imperial project. Whether taxing or gifting, the characteristic Attalid finesse was always on display. Genuine negotiation produced the proliferation of earmarking arrangements. As we shall see in Chapter 5, it also had the effect of channeling royal benefaction into the civic gymnasia. As techniques of domination and accommodation, none of this was new. On the contrary, these were time-honored, culturally privileged solutions to the problems of governance. What was new was the intensity with which the Attalids pursued administrative and ideological cohesion, producing new collectivities as fiscal structures aligned interests. However, we have yet to consider what is usually regarded as the most strikingly new, distinctive, and still mysterious feature of their rule, namely, the coinage and, specifically, the cistophori (plural for cistophorus).

These are curious coins. They were minted on a peculiar weight standard. They also lack the royal portraits that genre prescribed. Their very strangeness has provoked radically divergent interpretations. For Fred Kleiner, whose Early Cistophoric Coinage is the standard reference work on the subject, the cistophori were “the king’s money,” a straightforwardly royal coinage.Footnote 1 That position, it must be understood, is polemical. There is a long tradition, stretching back to Alexandre Panel and Joseph Eckhel in the eighteenth century, with Henri Seyrig and Wolfgang Szaivert as its most recent exponents, which regards the cistophori as the federative coinage of cities.Footnote 2 In an authoritative study, George Le Rider writes of the “cistophoric coinage of the Attalids,” but tentatively puts forward a more nuanced vision, suggesting that the kings negotiated the cistophori into existence, and then shared with the cities of Asia Minor the attendant responsibilities and rewards.Footnote 3 This chapter argues that the cities’ cooperation was key not only to the birth of the cistophori but to the maintenance of the entire Attalid monetary system. As an arena of negotiation between city and king, the coinage elicits our attention.

Neither purely royal nor civic, the cistophori defy labels and epitomize the eclecticism of the Attalid state. On closer inspection, we will find other confounding forms of Attalid money, such as the Wreathed Coinages and the so-called “cistophoric” countermarks. From ca. 170 BCE, we enter a transformative period in the history of Greek coinage. The relationship between sovereignty and coinage becomes ever more difficult to untangle. As Olivier Picard has pointed out, to make sense of large new coinages such as the Athenian New Style or Macedonian Meris coinage, we need to lose old labels such as “imitation” or “pseudo-Roman.”Footnote 4 Indeed, this chapter will propose one new schema: coordinated coinage. Achaemenid antecedents aside, the monetary system of the Attalid kingdom at its acme involved civic institutions and promoted civic identities to an unprecedented and ultimately unmatched degree. Paradoxically, this had the effect of extending the kings’ reach over much new territory. In other words, coinage had a role to play in fostering the integration of the various micro-regions of the Attalid state. It is interesting to contrast the testimony of Polybius, for whom coinage was merely an index of state formation and integration (symphronêsis) (2.37.8–11). For the Megalopolitan, the federal coinage of the Achaean Koinon is just one measure of the remarkable transformation of the Peloponnese into, in his formulation, a single polis but for the walls. It is an expression, not a tool of integration. We can go further, attributing to a Hellenistic coinage the power to bind the smaller polities of a royal state to each other and to the crown.

The narrow question of what to call the cistophori – the binary choice of royal or civic coinage – is a fruitless question of cui bono. The cistophoric system generated profits, through the procurement and transfer of bullion, and through the exchange and reminting of old coin. Yet given the present state of our evidence, we cannot so much as guess at the size of these profits and the extent to which the Attalids shared them with the cities. We can, however, observe in the cistophoric system features of both centralized and decentralized control. This hybridity permits us to state with confidence that the inherent profits were shared. Decentralization is emphasized in the explanation of the cistophori set out in what follows mainly because previous scholarship seems to overstate the case for centralization. To emphasize cooperation is not to lose sight of the Attalids as the prime movers behind this coinage, nor to discount their role as the indispensable coordinating force behind the system – to ignore the obvious asymmetries of power. It is instead a means, first, of situating the cistophori in the broader context of Attalid money and, second, of highlighting the distinctiveness of Attalid monetary practice. The chapter first lays out a new understanding of the cistophori: neither royal nor civic, but what we term a coordinated coinage. Second, it proposes an explanation of the various changes in the coinage of the Attalid kingdom, 188–133, set against the wider backdrop of the eastern Mediterranean. But before we can explain them, we need to introduce the coins.

Overview of the Coinages of the Attalid Kingdom, 188–133 BCE

The most current numismatic research on the mint of Pergamon undercuts the notion of a decisive change in 188.Footnote 5 The Attalids had always minted an Attic-weight, which is to say, international silver coinage, and they continued to do so after the Treaty of Apameia (Marcellesi nos. 26 and 42; Fig. 3.1).Footnote 6 The Philetairoi, Attic tetradrachms bearing the face of the founder, have been divided into seven groups by Ulla Westermark.Footnote 7 With minor modifications, Westermark’s groups have been retained, but their absolute dates are not fixed. Andrew Meadows has recently posited a gap in the production of Philetairoi from ca. 190 to ca. 180–175.Footnote 8 Yet the Attalids were minting an Attic-weight silver coinage in the 180s, if indeed their posthumous Alexanders continue from the late third century into this period (Marcellesi no. 32). Meadows has placed a subset of Attalid Alexanders (Price nos. 1491–95) in the 180s, arguing that “Alexander coinage is likely to have been the principal coinage produced by the Pergamene kings during the period of their conflict with Antiochos III, and in the subsequent decade of reorganization of the Pergamene kingdom.”Footnote 9 In other words, the Attalids seem to have preferred to make payments in Alexanders during the crucial start-up years of the enlarged kingdom. Pergamon now joined Miletus and a host of other cities in the region already minting Alexanders. With an eye to making their coinage acceptable and their royalty inconspicuous, the Attalids paused production of the Philetairoi in favor of generic Alexanders.Footnote 10

Figure 3.1 Silver tetradrachm of Eumenes II minted in the name of Philetairos, Westermark Group VII.

(16.35 g, ANS 1944.100.43195; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

At some point in the 180s, a new wave of Attic-weight silver entered the enlarged Attalid kingdom in the form of countermarked tetradrachms of four Pamphylian cities: Phaselis, Perge, Aspendos, and Side.Footnote 11 The Sidetan issues, which predominate, bore that city’s own types; the rest, like many other civic coinages of this period, were Alexanders. A second minting authority placed a countermark on the obverse of the host coin, consisting of a bow-in-case alongside an abbreviated city name or ethnic (Fig. 3.2). These have been named “cistophoric countermarks” on account of the bow-in-case symbol, shared with the cistophori proper, which would seem to refer to the Heraklid origins of the House of Telephos. The cities evoked by the marks were also all in post-Apameian Pergamene territory: Ephesus, Tralles, Sardis, Synnada, Apameia, Laodikeia-on-the-Lykos, Stratonikeia-on-the-Kaikos, Adramyttium, Toriaion, the long unidentified ΕΛΗΣ, ΕΛ/ΛΗ, ΕΛΛΗ, and Pergamon itself.Footnote 12 However, these countermarks and the cistophoric coinage itself were not contemporaneous. The so-called cistophoric countermarking seems to end in the early 170s, just before the cistophori, on the “low chronology,” begin.Footnote 13 Indeed, seven of the twelve known cities referred to by the countermarks correspond to cistophoric cities. While Sardis appears on the countermarks the most, Ephesus barely registers. This is significant because Sardis plays a minor role and Ephesus a major one in the production of cistophori, implying shifting priorities or purpose.Footnote 14

Figure 3.2 Silver tetradrachm of Side minted ca. 210–190 BCE, bearing countermark of bow-in-case + ΠΕΡ.

(15.91 g, ANS 2015.20.1206; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

The cistophori are one of the great numismatic puzzles of Classical Antiquity. The term cistophorus is an ancient one, usually used by Moderns to refer to the tetradrachms of a system that included didrachms and eventually drachms.Footnote 15 It is the tetradrachm alone, however, which, bears on its obverse the wicker chest or ritual basket, the so-called cista mystica, with its lid ajar and a serpent emerging (Marcellesi no. 45; Fig. 3.3). An ivy wreath wraps around the field. On the reverse, the tetradrachm displays two snakes on either side of a bow in its case (gorytos). The reverse also bears various symbols and the name of a city – or an ethnic – usually in abbreviated form, for example, ΕΦΕ or, less often, as a monogram.Footnote 16 The didrachms (Marcellesi no. 46; Fig. 3.4) and post-Attalid drachms (Marcellesi no. 49; Fig. 3.5) share types: on the obverse, a club draped with a lion skin, wrapped in a wreath; on the reverse, a bunch of grapes on a vine leaf, and again, various marks and the shortened version of a city’s name/ethnic. The tetradrachm, which will be referred to here as the cistophorus, per the convention, is the dominant denomination; the didrachms and the later drachms, which will be referred to as the fractions, are rare by comparison. (By “cistophori,” we mean all three denominations.) The cistophoric tetradrachm was minted at a theoretical weight of ca. 12.6 g, the didrachm at 6.15 g, and the drachm at 3.05 g.Footnote 17 This weight standard is singular, if also relatable to its contemporaries, with a cistophorus weighing roughly the same as three Attic-weight drachms or Roman denarii, and the drachm a negligible 0.05 g heavier than the Rhodian plinthophoros.Footnote 18

Figure 3.3 Cistophoric silver tetradrachm of Pergamon, ca. 160–150 BCE.

(12.58 g, ANS 1951.5.13; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

Figure 3.4 Cistophoric silver didrachm of Tralles, ca. 145–140 BCE.

(5.91 g, ANS 1944.100.37564; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

Figure 3.5 Cistophoric silver drachm, ca. 134–128 BCE.

(2.58 g, ANS 1984.5.35; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

The iconography of the mythological repertoire glimpsed on the cistophori is bewilderingly complex.Footnote 19 Perhaps it was meant to be so, and therefore it managed to appeal to a broad range of users, Greek and Anatolian, while remaining politically and culturally anodyne. Alternatively, the peculiar combination of myths depicted eludes conclusive interpretation because it is not preserved in any other media. Commentators since Warwick Wroth in the nineteenth century have emphasized different divine attributes, the snake of Asklepios, ivy and grapes of Dionysos, arms and lion skin cloak of Herakles, without offering a comprehensive interpretation of the visual program.Footnote 20 One tends now to describe cistophoric iconography as a mixed bag. For example, asserting that the Attalids “considered Pergamon as a sort of Athens of the east,” Elizabeth Kosmetatou argues that the cista and snake of the obverse represent the myth of Erichthonius and Athena, while also allowing that the visual frame of the ivy wreath may refer to the dynasty’s favored cult of Dionysus Kathegemon.Footnote 21 For Marie-Christine Marcellesi, the coins are a savvy mix of Bacchic and Heraklid imagery. The cista, then, would be part of the paraphernalia of the mystery cult of Dionysos Kathegemon, while the citizens of Pergamon, as the descendants of Telephos, would be vindicated by the symbols of Herakles.Footnote 22 In fact, any number of these conclusions is open to debate. For example, in an exhaustive study of the cults of Pergamon, Erwin Ohlemutz finds no sign of the mystery cult of Dionysos Kathegemon on the coins.Footnote 23 Rather, an ancient viewer may have seen the cult of Demeter and Persephone in the image of a snake-in-a-box.Footnote 24 We tend to focus on the cista, at least in part, because we happen to have it in a Greek and later Latin term for the coin. Yet the most dominant motif overall is the snake – with one on the obverse and two on the reverse. To a different ancient viewer, these could have been the “snake-bearing coins (ophiophoroi).”

It is worth bearing in mind that some or all of these snakes may belong to a class of benevolent serpents (drakônes).Footnote 25 This distinguishes the cistophori from famous coin types such as the silver of classical Chalchis, which exhibits a predatory eagle holding a serpent in its beak and claws, and the hunch can lead us in several interesting directions.Footnote 26 The heraldic pair of standing snakes on the reverse of the cistophorus almost seems to guard the gorytos of Herakles. Are these snakes in fact friendly to the house of Telephos? Apparently, some serpents were friendly to the Pergamene hero. In a possibly Sophoclean version of the myth, a snake stood up to prevent the hero from consummating his marriage with his mother Auge, the very scene depicted on Panel 21 of the Great Altar’s inner frieze.Footnote 27 Moreover, an important precedent among the coin types of Pergamon should be brought into the discussion. A large number of bronzes were minted in the name of Philetairos from the 270s until the early second century that bear a standing snake on the reverse (Marcellesi no. 18; Fig. 3.6). A reference to the popular, pre-Attalid cult of Asklepios is certainly plausible given echoes on the god’s own bronze and that of Hygieia (Marcellesi nos. 59–60, 62), but the snake on the Philetairos bronze, lacking omphalos or staff, also bears a striking resemblance to the one saving Telephos from Oedipal sin on the Great Altar (Fig. 3.7). Indeed, if we cast a wider net, we find plenty of contemporary myths of foundation that involve friendly snakes, most relevant among them, the argolai, which are said to have aided Alexander in Alexandria.Footnote 28 The Alexander Romance suggests that household snakes as friendly spirits (agathoi daimones) had well-known associations with Hellenistic royalty.Footnote 29 Meanwhile, Iron Age Anatolia seems to have contained its own tales of founder-snakes and serpentine progenitors. Strabo tells us of the snake-men as heroes of the tribes of the conspicuously pro-Attalid city of Parion, and a recurrent motif on the coinage of Pisidian Etenna shows that non-Greek myth mixed easily with Greek when it came to friendly snakes.Footnote 30

Figure 3.6 Standing serpent on reverse of large module (hemiobol?) bronze coin in the name of Philetairos, ca. 270s–200 BCE.

(4.27 g, BNF Fonds général 1486; courtesy of Bibliothèque nationale de France)

Figure 3.7 Fragmentary bedroom scene from the Telephos Frieze with standing serpent warning hero and Auge.

(T.I. 37, © Antikensammlung, Staatliche Museen zu Berlin – Preussischer Kulturbesitz; Photo: Johannes Laurentius)

From an administrative standpoint, the cistophori are slightly less mysterious. We can be reasonably certain of the identity of most of the pre-133 cistophoric mints – at least the major ones (Map I.3). There are two tiers in terms of volume of production: the large, regular mints, which are Pergamon, Ephesus, Tralles, Apameia, and, to a lesser extent, Sardis (Synnada in Phrygia was once thought to be Sardis-Synnada);Footnote 31 and the small, irregular ones: Laodikeia-on-the-Lykos; Adramyttion, which is attested by a single pre-133 coin, though it became a major mint from the time of the Revolt of Aristonikos;Footnote 32 and, finally, a smattering of small mints whose identity is contested, but at least four seem to be south Phrygian: Blaundos, Dionysoupolis, Dioskome, and Lysias (or Synnada?). The mystery mint ΚΟΡ may be Kormasa in the Milyas.Footnote 33 Quantitatively speaking, an overall volume of roughly 50 obverse die equivalents per year points to Attalid initiative and bullion resources behind coins that deliberately obscure – and indeed efface – the kings’ role. Meanwhile, the cistophori represent Attalid minting on an unprecedented scale. François de Callataÿ has estimated the value of the cistophori at 6.5 times that of the annual average of pre-170 Philetairoi.Footnote 34

Dating the Cistophori

The terms of the debate on the vexed question of the date of the introduction of the cistophoric system have narrowed in recent years.Footnote 35 For the high chronology, Karl Harl and Marcellesi rely on the testimony of Livy, who records the display of cistophori in four Roman triumphs between 190 and 187. Marcellesi sees the Attalids minting the new coins at Pergamon in the run-up to the war with Antiochos III. After the victory, the system was expanded to include the other mints in the new territories.Footnote 36 Many other numismatists dismiss Livy’s testimonia as anachronism, and have instead concentrated on the period between 188, when the political geography of Asia Minor was redrawn, and ca. 166–ca. 150, when the coins start to turn up in the Delian accounts. The debate turns on the dating of a portion of Westermark Group VII Philetairoi, reclassified as Nicolet-Pierre issues 19–25.Footnote 37 These Philetairoi share control marks with what are understood to be early cistophori. Leaving aside for a moment the important point that the Attalids struck the cistophori and this Attic-weight regal coinage simultaneously, one needs to decide on dates for this group of the latest Philetairoi. Their presence in the Maaret-en-Nouman hoard (northwest Syria) provides a terminus ante quem of 162.Footnote 38 But it is difficult to determine how much earlier they began, and how long they took to travel from Pergamon to Syria and into the ground. For the overlap of Philetairoi and cistophori, Meadows argues for the lowest chronology yet, ca. 165–ca. 160, and points to a coin of Alabanda minted in 167/6 on the cistophoric standard as supplementary evidence of their existence.Footnote 39

Many scholars posit 181 as a further terminus ante quem for the launch of the cistophori on the basis of Richard Ashton’s interpretation of a letter of Eumenes II to Artemidoros, the Attalid governor of the Lycian outpost of Telmessos (D3).Footnote 40 The letter concerns benefactions for the inhabitants of the Kome Kardakon, who had fallen on hard times.Footnote 41 The key passage reads: “Since it is necessary for them to pay arrears on the poll-tax, each of them four Rhodian drachmas and one obol, but since, in light of their suffering, this is not within their means, let this amount be remitted this year, and from next year, let them pay one Rhodian drachma and one obol (καὶ ἐπεὶ τῆς συντάξεως δεῖ διορθοῦσθαι αὐτοὺς ἑκά̣στου σώματος ἐνηλίκου Ῥοδίας δραχμὰς τέσσαρας ὀβολόν, ἀσ̣θενοῦντες δὲ τοῖς ἰδίοις βαρύνονται, τά τε παραγραφόμενα αὐτοῖς ἐκ τοῦ ἑκκαιδεκάτου ἔτους ἐκ τούτων ἀφεῖναι, ἀπὸ δὲ τοῦ ἑπτακαιδεκάτου ἔτους Ῥοδίαν δραχμὴν καὶ ὀβολόν)” (lines 10–14). Ashton calls attention to the significance of what he deems the curiously unrounded number of the tax. He takes it as given that the poll-tax was normally paid at a rate of four “Rhodian” drachms and one obol, which, if the Rhodian coins are indeed Rhodian plinthophori, is equivalent to a total of ca. 12.6 g of silver, the weight of the cistophorus. This would mean that in Telmessos, in the vicinity of the Rhodian zone of control, the Attalids had decided to collect a tax collected elsewhere in the kingdom as a cistophorus in an equivalent amount of Rhodian coined silver. Therefore, the curiously unrounded number of the tax levied at Telmessos tells us that the cistophorus already existed in the kingdom at large. It is an ingenious conjecture, but should not be mistaken for an unimpeachable fact. The decree only states that the Attalids had been unable to collect the 12.6 g of Rhodian silver coins from the Kardakoi. Significantly, they then permanently lowered the tax rate to a figure, one Rhodian drachm and one obol (3.5–6 g), which bears little relation to the weight of the cistophoric drachm (3.05 g).Footnote 42 Was the attempt to integrate the Lycian outpost into the new monetary system so quickly abandoned? Rather, the Telmessos text only demonstrates that in 181 the Attalids were employing a unit of account that would later be expressed in the cistophorus. The origin of the unit of 12.6 g may lie in fiscal experimentation, but 181 cannot be posited as a terminus ante quem for the cistophoric system, which was introduced some time after ca. 175.Footnote 43

Attic-Weight Coinage

Whether we date the cistophoric reform to the 170s or 160s, it is becoming increasingly clear that the introduction of the cistophorus did not spell the end of production of Attic-weight coinage in the kingdom.Footnote 44 In fact, we are only just coming to recognize the impressive scale of Attic-weight, “international” coinages minted in the final decades of Attalid rule. Of those that are patently royal, to the aforementioned Group VII Philetairoi we must add an extremely rare issue of tetradrachms bearing a portrait of Eumenes II, dated by Hélène Nicolet-Pierre to 166–159 (Fig. 3.8).Footnote 45 Two other silver coinages known from a very small number of specimens seem to be related to officially sanctioned cultic activity: the tetradrachms of Athena Nikephoros, usually placed in the mid-160s (Fig. 3.9), and a tetradrachm from Teos, but issued in the name of a group with deep ties to the Attalid court, the Association of the Artists of Dionysus, dated by Catherine Lorber and Oliver Hoover to the 150s. Meadows has added a further coinage to the mix from the mid- to late 140s. These are tetradrachms that show Demeter on the obverse and the Kabeiroi encircled by a wreath on the reverse, in much the same fashion as the reverse of the Eumenes II portrait coins. Their legend, however, reads not ΒΑΣΙΛΕΩΣ ΕΥΜΕΝΟΥ (“of King Eumenes”), but ΘΕΩΝ ΚΑΒΕΙΡΩΝ ΣΥΡΙΩΝ (“of the Syrioi Kabeiroi”). If Meadows is correct in attributing this coinage to the Attalids, it would be of more than antiquarian interest. By the looks of the die counts, this was a very large coinage, on the same scale as the cistophori in the same period of production.Footnote 46

Figure 3.8 Silver tetradrachm of Eumenes II, ca. 166–162 BCE.

(15.24 g, BM 1849,0717.10 © The Trustees of the British Museum)

Figure 3.9 Silver tetradrachm in the name of Athena Nikephoros, reign of Eumenes II, ca. 180–165 BCE.

(16.06 g, BM 1975,0208.1 © The Trustees of the British Museum)

Several cities within the Attalid kingdom also minted Attic-weight coinage after the introduction of the cistophorus. For example, the gold drachms of Tralles, minted on the Attic standard, share control marks with the cistophori Kleiner-Noe series 9 and 41.Footnote 47 Signaling the city’s autonomy, it seems that Tralles minted the two gold issues at two distinct periods of its history. Of much greater importance to the regional money supply were the many Ephesian silver drachms with bee on obverse, stag on reverse (Fig. 3.10). Philip Kinns has established an early phase for this coinage that ends ca. 170, as well as a later phase for which he gives only the terminus ante quem of ca. 150.Footnote 48 It is indeed likely that Ephesus was producing Attic drachms and cistophori in parallel. The cases of Ephesus and Tralles, cities awarded to the Attalids at Apameia as gifts (dôreai; Polyb. 21.46.10), point up the difficulty of using coinage to determine the political or fiscal status of a community after 188.Footnote 49 The same can be said of Temnos, which, while under tight Attalid control, continued to mint its Alexanders in the 150s and 140s.Footnote 50 Monetary production is just one arena for the negotiation of sovereignty. As Thomas Martin has shown, the ancient Greeks possessed little loyalty to an abstract connection between sovereignty and the right to mint.Footnote 51 For the cities of the Attalid kingdom, it is not possible to extrapolate monetary behavior from the political status assigned at Apameia.Footnote 52

Figure 3.10 Silver drachm of Ephesus with legend “of the Ephesians,” ca. 150 BCE.

(4.02 g, BNF Fonds général 511 = Kinns 1999 obverse 70; courtesy of Bibliothèque nationale de France)

Finally, the most significant Attic-weight coinages produced in the Attalid kingdom in these years are the so-called Wreathed Coinages.Footnote 53 These are silver tetradrachms bearing the civic types and ethnics of coastal cities, the obverse framed by the wreath that gives them their name (Fig. 3.11). The cities in question are Aigai, Kyme, Myrina, and Smyrna in the Aeolian core; Lebedos; Magnesia-on-the-Maeander; and Herakleia-under-Latmos. With good hoard evidence and die studies available, Callataÿ has been able to date the Wreathed Coinages ca. 154–135, although the mints operated on different schedules.Footnote 54 Still, even on the lowest chronology, the cistophori and the Wreathed Coinages are contemporary developments. It should be noted that several other coinages of the middle two quarters of the second century share the wreath design, for example, coins of Macedonia under Philip V, of Eretria and Cyzicus, and the Athenian New Style tetradrachms. This is evidence not of a monetary union, as some have hypothesized, but of a popular fashion in coin design that may have served to enhance the coins’ acceptability.Footnote 55

Figure 3.11 “Wreathed” silver tetradrachm of Myrina, ca. 160–135 BCE.

(14.51 g, ANS 1944.100.44235; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

The Wreathed Coinages circulated similarly to other Attic-weight coinages of Asia Minor. They do not appear in the thin hoard record for mid-second-century Asia Minor, but they do turn up in Levantine hoards of the 150s and 140s.Footnote 56 We do not need ad hoc political or military explanations to explain why silver moved from the Aegean to the Near East, where the higher value of silver relative to gold had since Achaemenid times attracted Greek coinage to the Levant.Footnote 57 Indeed, the Wreathed Coinages participated in an old circulation pattern that intensified in this period. What needs to be explained is the size of these coinages, which share common designs and originate in cities firmly under Attalid control. Callataÿ estimates a total of 76.8 Attic-drachm equivalent obverses per year for the Wreathed Coinages – compared with just 51.9 for the pre-133 cistophori!Footnote 58 Tipped off by the size of the issues, scholars since Rostovtzeff have suspected Attalid involvement.Footnote 59 The notion of a “proxy coinage” may seem less conspiratorial after the discussion below. Leaving open for now the question of the precise nature of Attalid involvement with the Wreathed Coinages, it is difficult to understand how these cities minted in such quantities without injections of bullion from the outside.

Explaining the Cistophori

Scholars have struggled to define the character of the cistophoric coinage, vacillating between civic, royal, and federal models of minting. The inherited paradigms fail us, in part, because the coins look so strange. However, their visual strangeness need not be explained away in our analysis. Attalid silver and indeed bronze had always born the portrait of Philetairos, nearly always with the legend ΦΙΛΕΤΑΙΡΟΥ, “of Philetairos.” That combination of image and text was standard practice across the Hellenistic world. In their design, the cistophori mark a radical break with the past – and with convention, in a medium that is famously conservative.Footnote 60 Not only do these coins renounce the claims of the typical Hellenistic coin legend; they also replace the dynastic portrait with imagery sufficiently generic or enigmatic, it seems, to evoke a wide range of associations. They leave us asking, “Whose money is it?” On the other hand, the coins bear symbols, control marks, which without question derive from the iconographic repertoire of the various cities involved. This is best observed in Ephesus, where the bee and stag (along with the quiver of Artemis), appear on the cistophori; meanwhile, Ephesus had for centuries placed that same imagery on its own coinage, and in fact continued to do so, even after the introduction of the cistophori, on its common Attic-weight drachms.Footnote 61 In the markets adjacent to its new harbor, the one built by the engineers of Attalos II, traders handled both coinages in tandem. Or consider the case of Tralles. It provides another clear instance of identifiably civic badges on the cistophori: the humped bull, the meander pattern, and, perhaps, Zeus Larasius. The bull we find on the aforementioned gold coinage of Tralles, and the meander pattern, so important to the civic and regional identity of the city, appears already on pre-188 bronze.Footnote 62 Kleiner sought to limit the phenomenon to Tralles and Ephesus, but his own catalogue shows its breadth. Some Apameian cistophori bear flutes (of Marsyas), and Laodikeian ones display the punning wolf (lykos) for the Lykos River.Footnote 63 To match image with text, then, we are justified in following Le Rider, who restores cistophoric legends as ethnics, not mintmarks, as, for example, ΕΦΕ[ΣΙΩΝ], “(coin) of the Ephesian (citizens).”Footnote 64 The coins represented the citizens – of their respective poleis – just as much as the kingdom.

To cast the cistophori as either strictly royal or civic in nature is to explain away their visual strangeness. Either one argues that the combination of civic iconography and muted reference to the crown signals the withdrawal of the Attalids from the domain of coinage, a restatement of the laissez-faire, constitutional vision of Attalid imperialism, or the coins dissemble and mask the kings’ interventions. In that sense, as Kleiner puts it: “The cistophoric coinage is not what it appears to be.”Footnote 65 Yet a coin in this world was always, in some sense, what it appeared to be. According to the classic formulation of an inscription from Sestos honoring the late Attalid courtier Menas, the benefits of introducing any new epichoric coinage were of two kinds (I.Sestos 1 lines 44–45).Footnote 66 First, the community was able to place its own charaktêr on its coins. Second, the coinage would become a source of revenue (prosodos) for the community through mandatory exchange, reminting fees, and so on. Unfortunately, on the present state of the evidence, we cannot say anything about who laid claim to the surely considerable profits of the cistophoric system, or in what proportions. Tellingly, Kleiner relates the fiscal structure of the cistophoric system to the practice of earmarking. In his view, they were both forms of bait-and-switch fiscality, tribute disguised as taxation and redistribution.Footnote 67 On the other hand, we must admit that the Attalids ceded away a certain part of the charaktêr of this coinage, and the text from Sestos provides explicit confirmation of the significance of that aspect of coinage for late Hellenistic cities. Meadows has gone so far as to suggest that the political significance of minting with epichoric types was changing and in fact intensifying in precisely this period.Footnote 68 Therefore, it seems prudent to take the cistophori at “face value,” even if this means ruling out conventional models of royal or civic coinage. The strange appearance of the coins hints at the same Attalid sensitivity to civic identity and the same reliance on civic institutions that undergirded the practice of earmarking. Yet any new characterization of the cistophori must rest on the evidence of the coins themselves for the administration of the system.

The Devil in the Administrative Details: The Evidence for Centralization

To underline the point, the coins do not give us a balance of accounts, how much city and king – or indeed third parties, like merchants – each invested in the system, and how much each took out. And this problem is not unique to Attalid Asia Minor. In a programmatic essay on late Hellenistic coinage, Picard has sized up our aporia with the question, “Where does the metal come from?”Footnote 69 No metallurgical analysis is available to trace the origin of the various stocks of silver bullion used to mint early cistophori.Footnote 70 On the other hand, we can at least try to determine where the minting took place, and how the shape of the money supply and the rhythm of monetary production were managed. To begin with the organization of the cistophoric mints, Kleiner’s Early Cistophoric Coinage (ECC) appears to have overstated the case for centralized production. Le Rider and Otto Mørkholm have offered criticisms of ECC on this score, but given the status of Kleiner’s book as the standard of reference for the coinage, its arguments deserve further scrutiny, since for Kleiner, what he calls “inter-city linkage” would “necessitate a complete reconsideration of the nature of the cistophoric coinage.”Footnote 71

ECC does not postulate two tiers of mints, large and small, as we have above. The system of ECC contains just three central mints that produce all the coins, whichever their charaktêr: Ephesus, Tralles, but, most importantly, Pergamon itself, the administrative hub, minting for a number of smaller pseudo-mints. Central to Kleiner’s argument is a notion of intercity linkage that includes not only die links, but also shared symbols, monograms, and, crucially, the stylistic links that Kleiner observes throughout the coinage. Numismatic method privileges the evidence of die links over stylistic links, but the number of die links in the ECC corpus is surprisingly low.Footnote 72 In fact, there are only two instances of verifiable die-sharing between mints, both involving Pergamon.Footnote 73 The first is the link between Kleiner’s P24 of Pergamon and S10 (series 6) from “Sardis-Synnada.”Footnote 74 Noting that “Sardis-Synnada” series 6 is itself die-linked to the then as yet un-deciphered ΒΑ ΣΥ ΑΡ cistophori, Kleiner argued for the unlikelihood of a single die traveling between the royal capital, Lydia, and Phrygia. Since then, Le Rider has suggested that “Sardis-Synnada” is actually two mints, Sardis and Lysias in south Phrygia; that the monogram on the reverse of the obverse die-linked coin at issue should be read “Dionysoupolis”; and that the ΒΑ ΣΥ ΑΡ coins come from Blaundos, both Dionysoupolis and Blaundos themselves also lying in south Phrygia.Footnote 75 All this still leaves us with the circulation of at least one die between two or perhaps three regions. Its possible mintmark notwithstanding, Blaundos, for example, does not seem to have been urbanized under the Attalids.Footnote 76 So the need for greater centralization in rural south Phrygia makes sense. We cannot rule out a traveling mint that accompanied the retinue of Eumenes II, who might have faced the Galatians at both Sardis and Synnada.Footnote 77 Edward Robinson demonstrated a roving mint for Aristonikos.Footnote 78 Whatever the arrangement here, it was short-lived, irregular, and confined to an early stage, perhaps under the peculiar conditions of the Galatian War.

Much more suggestive of centralization is the second case of die sharing, known from an impressive five links between Pergamon and Apameia: Kleiner’s A17/P38, A24/P46, A28/P54, A38/P75, and A40/P79. Moreover, Kleiner’s observation that the pace of production at both mints was increasing simultaneously is intriguing. It at least implies that both mints faced a sharp increase in demand for coinage at the same time and coordinated a response. But were these actually two distinct mints? If one assigns to Pergamon the 16% of production currently credited to Apameia, a more centralized system emerges with just three mints functioning. However, many of the die linkages have been challenged.Footnote 79 It was also quite common for dies and die-cutters to pass between mints.Footnote 80 The detailed study of Christophe Flament on the mechanics of minting in Classical Greece highlights the pitfalls of using hand studies to demonstrate centralized production.Footnote 81 Yet Kleiner’s observations of hands is what sustains much of his model of centralization, from Apameia to the mystery mint ΚΟΡ to his claim that Tralles struck for Laodikeia.Footnote 82 There are clear signs of coordination by a central authority, but we also find hints of local participation and information sharing. Apameia seems to have minted its first civic bronze coinage about now, which shares the symbol of the pilos with early cistophori.Footnote 83 For the late cistophori, the civic mint was certainly involved, as the magistrate ΚΟΚΟΥ appears on both the silver cistophori and the civic bronze coinage.Footnote 84 In sum, it still seems probable that Apameia possessed a mint under the Attalids.

It must be admitted that the cistophori display remarkable uniformity of type. The imagery is consistent, as is the placement of the ethnic and the symbols (Figs. 3.3 and 3.12). The weight of the coin and the size of the flan do not change much either.Footnote 85 Most importantly, the repetition of symbols on the coins of different mints implies a coherent administrative system. On the other hand, we find striking anomalies, such as the letters on a limited number of series from Ephesus (33–35) and Apameia (27–28), usually taken to be regnal years. Whether the letters on either of these coinages actually represent regnal dates, and why these cities alone and not Pergamon itself would have marked time in this way are both open questions.Footnote 86 The salient point is that different administrative systems were at work in different places. This implies that local actors and institutions influenced the production of the cistophori. We get a sense of just how important local officials might have been under the Attalids from the behavior of their mints immediately after 133. While the Ephesians were quick to place their city’s civic era on the coins, the citizens of Pergamon minted cistophori bearing the names of their prytaneis.Footnote 87 Had those magistrates shared the responsibility for minting with royal officials all along?

Figure 3.12 Cistophoric silver tetradrachm of Ephesus, ca. 150–140 BCE.

(12.58 g, ANS 1944.100.37502; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

The Peculiar Role of Tralles

… that they think it just the same, whether they arrive in Tralles or in Formia …

(Cicero, Q.Fr. 1.1.17)Footnote 88

Die sharing is just one of the twin pillars of the case for centralization. The other is the specialization of the mint of Tralles in the production of small denominations. These are the didrachms and drachms that survive in much smaller numbers than the cistophoric tetradrachms (Figs. 3.4 and 3.5). This unmistakable peculiarity of Tralles in this respect fulfilled the needs of local users on the border between two large regional monetary systems. Thus, ECC lists 16 obverse drachm dies and 18 obverse didrachm dies for Tralles.Footnote 89 No other mint comes close.Footnote 90 However, the traditional view is that the Attalids arbitrarily assigned small change to Tralles. “It is unlikely that the silver currency needs of Tralles differed substantially from those of the other large Attalid cities,” writes Kleiner.Footnote 91 On this interpretation, royal needs motivated Tralles’ designation, which represents the ultimate instantiation of the “royal design” behind the cistophoric system. Even those who model decentralized production assume centralized control of the shape of the supply of coin. For example, Callataÿ: “The fact that the mint of Tralles was in charge of nearly all the fractions points too in the direction of a general policy established at a higher level.”Footnote 92 It is also commonly assumed that the Attalids decided unilaterally to focus the production of fractional coinage in Tralles. As Thonemann writes, “The cistophori were produced at a number of decentralized mints. Their production, however, was closely directed from the centre.… [Tralles’ specialization] strongly suggests that the distribution and scale of the mints did not necessarily reflect the coinage’s circulation.”Footnote 93

In fact, the special role of Tralles was neither arbitrary nor the outcome of a unilateral royal decision. Further, the case of Tralles may even shed light on circulation patterns. Consider first that the city continued to specialize in fractions – and even intensified its production of small denominations after the fall of the Attalid dynasty. In his study of the very large coinage known as the “late cistophori,” minted from ca. 133 to ca. 67, Kleiner found that Tralles retained its traditional role.Footnote 94 The only hoard of late cistophori that contains fractions is IGCH 1460 (unknown provenance in Asia Minor). It contains 2 drachms and 7 didrachms, all of them, except for a single drachm of Ephesus, from Tralles. Kleiner did not make a companion die study of the late cistophori, but he does note that the late fractions of Tralles are overwhelmingly dominant in both public and private collections.Footnote 95 In trying to understand the persistence of the pattern, it is important to remember that early Roman administrators were cautious and practical. We could see here simply the rote reproduction of an administrative procedure and the inertia of bureaucracy.

However, a meaningful pattern emerges when we consider a yet later stage in the long history of the cistophori. When production of the late cistophori ended ca. 68/7 in the context of Pompey’s operations in the East, a 10-year hiatus ensued.Footnote 96 Around 58, the cistophori appeared again, this time bearing the names of cities, but also two personal names, one Greek and one Latin. These are the so-called proconsular cistophori, which carry the names of Roman proconsuls and local Greek magistrates. The coinage ends ca. 49 BCE with the issue of the propraetor L. Aemilius Lepidus Paullus. Gerd Stumpf’s corpus of proconsular cistophori does not record any fractions.Footnote 97 Yet this is because the one fraction that can be associated with the proconsular cistophori does not bear the typical two names, but just the Greek one. The coin is a didrachm minted by a certain ΑΡΙΣΤΟΚΛ[ΗΣ] (BMC Lydia 335, no. 55).Footnote 98 The same Aristokles of Tralles, we presume, is known to have minted proconsular cistophori (tetradrachms, bearing the city’s ethnic) for both C. Claudius Pulcher (Fig. 3.13) and C. Fannius (Stumpf nos. 55, 63, and 65). It is unclear whether Aristokles’ name appears alone on the didrachm due to considerations of space in the visual field or whether this is an expression of a different institutional arrangement. Either way, it appears that Tralles – and perhaps only Tralles – was minting fractions after a decade-long hiatus.

Figure 3.13 Proconsular cistophoric silver tetradrachm, signed by C. Pulcher and Aristokles, 55–53 BCE.

(11.95 g, ANS 1959.48.6; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)

After all the intervening disruption, why was it Tralles, yet again, which specialized in fractions? We need not imagine that its citizens held a monopoly on the technological know-how. Rather, we need to take seriously the possibility that the monetary needs of this city had been distinctive all along. In other words, we need to examine the economic and historical geography of the Maeander Valley. Thonemann’s study of the long-term history of the Maeander region illustrates how it can either connect or separate different stretches of Anatolia. He views Apameia both as a limit point for the Attalid imperial space and as an interchange between the steppe of inner Anatolia and the coastal lowlands.Footnote 99 The Maeander after 188 was very much a political frontier, chosen to mark the boundary between Rhodes’ domain on the mainland (peraia) and the expanded Attalid kingdom. In economic terms, perhaps this frontier was more permeable. Thonemann’s study does not offer us any idea of what an interchange would look like that connected the Rhodian zone of southwestern Asia Minor to the Attalid Maeander and beyond. Tralles fits the bill perfectly.

Positioned at the junction of several important trans-Anatolian routes, Tralles also joined Attalid Lydia to Rhodian Caria (Map 3.1). Branching off from the primary route between the coastal delta and the upper Maeander, the major route south into Caria took off from Tralles. In Pergamene terms, it connected Tralles to Alabanda, and, ultimately, Telmessos. But another branch connected Alabanda to Lagina, Stratonikeia, and, finally, Physkos (Marmaris), on the mainland opposite Rhodes.Footnote 100 The road from Alabanda to Tralles connected Caria to the Attalid’s southern highway, a stretch of the road that was to become one of the main arteries of the Roman province of Asia.Footnote 101 Strabo’s source Artemidoros of Ephesus (fl. 104–101 BCE) traveled it. In his testimony, Artemidoros is explicit about how he conceptualizes the road. For him, the road was part of a route from Physkos to Ephesus. Thus, Strabo: “Artemidoros says that the journey from Physkos, on the coast opposite Rhodes, towards Ephesus, as far as Lagina is 850 stadia; thence to Alabanda 250 stadia; to Tralles 160. About halfway, on the road to Tralles, the Maeander is crossed, and here are the boundaries of Caria. The whole number of stadia from Physkos to the Maeander, along the road to Ephesus, is 1180 stadia” (14.2.29).Footnote 102 For Artemidoros, note, Tralles was the middle point on this route, in terms of both distance and conceptual geography. Tralles was the end of Caria.Footnote 103

Map 3.1 The Maeander Valley and Rhodian Caria.

By location, therefore, Tralles was a monetary interchange between, on the one hand, the Rhodian zone to the south, where Rhodian and pseudo-Rhodian coinages on epichoric standards dominated for centuries, and, on the other, the young cistophoric zone. After 188, but seemingly before the advent of the cistophorus, the Rhodians reformed their own coinage, minting the plinthophoros.Footnote 104 The Rhodians may have designed the plinthophoros to be even more epichoric than other Rhodian and pseudo-Rhodian coinages in circulation.Footnote 105 In any case, the plinthophori, like other coinages on the various “Rhodian” standards, circulated throughout the Rhodian peraia and rarely left the zone. For their part, the cistophori almost never left the Attalid kingdom. The Maeander Valley, then, formed the border between two large, relatively impermeable regional monetary systems.Footnote 106 Passage between the two would have necessitated an exchange of currencies. And if the volume of those exchanges were higher than elsewhere, the demand for small denominations would also have been elevated. Indeed, if we accept that Tralles linked the Rhodian zone to the cistophoric zone, then as an interchange between two major epichoric systems, Tralles was sui generis as an Attalid mint.Footnote 107

To test the hypothesis of high-volume currency exchange in and around Tralles, we may look to the thin but suggestive hoard record. As noted, fractions of Tralles dominate the only known hoard of late cistophoric fractions, which is the unprovenanced IGCH 1460. For the cistophori of the Attalids, we are luckier. We still have just one hoard containing fractions, but it has a provenance. IGCH 1328 (Şahnalı) contains 18 pieces of cistophoric silver, 10 of them fractions. Again, among the fractional mints, Tralles predominates, with four didrachms. But the other mints are represented too: one didrachm apiece from Pergamon, Ephesus, Apameia, and “Synnada.”Footnote 108 While the Şahnalı hoard provides further confirmation of Tralles’ special role, it also sheds light on circulation patterns in the system. In other words, it is important to notice that the hoard contains coins from all the major mints, both cistophoric tetradrachms and fractions. It could be what numismatics call, with all due caution, a “circulation hoard,” the proverbial snapshot of what was in circulation at a given place and point in time.Footnote 109 The hoard was found near the site of ancient Euhippe, which lies just opposite Tralles, south across the plain of the Maeander, not far to the east from where the route of Artemidoros entered and exited the Valley, on the way from Tralles to Alabanda in Caria.Footnote 110 We simply do not have the hoard evidence to test the representativeness of the Şahnalı hoard in terms of circulation, though it is unquestionably representative in terms of content; that is, the common fractions of Tralles predominate. This is an isolated piece of evidence, but it suggests a pattern of circulation that concentrates fractions from all over the Attalid kingdom in the vicinity of Tralles, on the very edge of the cistophoric zone.

The hypothesis of heavy traffic between the Rhodian and cistophoric zones, channeled through Tralles, which produced a high volume of currency exchange, motivating the special role of Tralles in the cistophoric system, finds support in the behavior of mints south of the Maeander after the introduction of the cistophorus. In reaction to the creation of the cistophoric zone, these cities minted a portfolio of coinages on different standards, which allowed them to maintain their economic ties to the Maeander and profit from their own position of connectivity. After 167, the Rhodian political hegemony in Caria and Lycia began to collapse, but southwest Asia Minor was still very much part of the Rhodian monetary koinê.Footnote 111 In Caria, Alabanda in the 160s minted not only Attic-weight Alexanders, but also a coinage on the cistophoric standard.Footnote 112 With this coinage, Alabanda was not pledging fealty to Pergamon. It remained outside the Attalid kingdom, even if Eumenes II was inching into the power vacuum.Footnote 113 The Alabandan “cistophori” imply significant traffic back and forth along the first stretch of the Tralles-Physkos corridor, and represent one state’s attempt to integrate the two regional systems to its advantage. Similarly, Carian Stratonikeia, which lay further south along the same route, minted a curious denomination in this period, an Attic tridrachm alongside an Attic drachm in a system otherwise dominated by plinthophoric drachms and hemidrachms.Footnote 114 Meadows has pointed out that the weight standard of Stratonikeia’s Attic-weight tridrachm, ca. 12–12.5 g, made it interchangeable with a cistophorus. In northern Lycia, Oinoanda may have pursued a similar strategy, minting silver didrachms that equated nicely with the cistophorus at the ratio 3:2.Footnote 115 Another north Lycian city, late Hellenistic Kibyra followed Alabanda and minted its own cistophoric tetradrachms and drachms (BMC Phrygia, pp. 131–32, nos. 1–5). The north Lycian cases are without firm dates, floating between the mid-second and early first centuries BCE. For our purposes, it need not matter. Clearly, the spread of the cistophorus into southwestern Asia Minor was a slow, intermittent, century-long process, still being completed in the early first century BCE.Footnote 116 Along the way, it was useful for those cities situated on major routes in and out of the Maeander Valley to mint an appropriately flexible coinage.

Another measure of the extent to which Tralles straddled two monetary zones is the poor survival rate of its coins. Low survival rates may provide indirect evidence that cistophoric fractions were leaking out of the cistophoric zone faster than the cistophori themselves. The loss of small denominations is a case of the notorious “problem of small change” studied by economic historians Thomas Sargent and François Velde.Footnote 117 The drachms of Tralles are known from 18 specimens (n) and 16 dies (D), a ratio of nearly 1:1; the didrachms are 30 (n) and 20 (D), exactly 3:2.Footnote 118 Numismatists, with theoretical backing from statisticians, typically seek a sample of n/D = 3:1 before undertaking a die study.Footnote 119 Using a lower ratio is dangerous because it is not possible to estimate the original number of dies with any degree of certainty. In other words, we must admit that we do not have any idea of the scale of Tralles’ production of cistophoric fractions. However, we do know that Tralleian fractions survive very poorly. The average n/D for the entire cistophoric coinage (166–123 BCE) is 2.75 (1,142/416).Footnote 120 So, while the sample size is small, the fractions of Tralles are significantly below the average at 1.5 for the didrachms and 1.125 for the drachms. But how do those rates compare with other small silver of second-century Asia Minor? Kinns’ study of the copious silver drachms of Ephesus (ca. 202–150 BCE), produced an n/D of 8.43 (590/7).Footnote 121 On the other hand, the Rhodian plinthophori (ca. 185–84 BCE) survive at a much more comparable rate of 1.91 (1,583/829), as do the Stratonikeian hemidrachms (130–90 BCE) (4.92 = 305/62) and the pseudo-Rhodian drachms of Mylasa (165–30 BCE) (5.79 = 619/107). Hoarding practice may account for the problem. It could be that small silver in a multidenominational system was hoarded differently – that is, less – and so survives less often. An apposite comparison is available from Bithynia of the reign of Prousias II (189–149 BCE). His silver drachms are extremely rare by comparison to his tetradrachms.Footnote 122 We may also consider the possibility that the high volume of currency exchange on either side of the “cistophoric frontier” just south of Tralles contributed to a distinctive circulation pattern for the fractions, and so a lower rate of survival. The plinthophoric drachm weighed about as much as the cistophoric drachm (3.05 g), but we can hardly suppose that money changers were willing to make the exchange for free.Footnote 123 Did those who went south take the fractions of Tralles with them, exchanging these coins inside the plinthophoric zone, where they eventually met the melting pot?

The weight of the evidence shows that local needs and preferences determined the choice of Tralles as the chief fractional mint in the cistophoric system. Or to put it another way, regionalism inflected the shape of the money supply in the Attalid kingdom. Consider again the regional situation along the Maeander, but now against the backdrop of the wider Hellenistic world. As Picard has illustrated, the typical late Hellenistic monetary system was built around large silver and fiduciary bronze, with little coinage at the intermediary values.Footnote 124 Few regional systems reserved an important role for small silver. The exceptions to this rule were two: the symmachic Peloponnese and the Rhodian zone that intersected with the cistophoric zone at Tralles. In the late third or early second century, Rhodes even raised a tax (or a public subscription?) called the didrachmia (SEG XLI 649).Footnote 125 Moreover, the imitative cistophoric production of Kibyra in northern Lycia seems also markedly biased toward the fraction. No comprehensive study exists, but a survey of major collections reveals a nearly 3:1 advantage for Kibyra’s cistophoric drachms over its tetradrachms (30:9).Footnote 126 The Tralleian cistophoric fractions are representative of the affinity of southwest Asia Minor for small silver. In the end, there were good reasons for Tralles to specialize; the choice was not arbitrary.

In sum, the case of Tralles is a far cry from proof that the Attalids held fiat power when it came to the shape of the money supply. Naturally, the people of Tralles possessed some notion of how to shape it themselves. Recall that they minted Attic-weight gold staters in two issues ca. 167–133. They may very well have minted civic bronzes in this period too.Footnote 127 It also remains possible that civic authorities in Tralles applied a countermark of their own, the bull protome, to certain Attic-weight silver tetradrachms from outside the kingdom.Footnote 128 Therefore, one can conceivably find local inflection up and down the complete range of value. Yet for poleis, just as important as the shape of the money supply was the rhythm of monetary production. As noted, the cistophoric system contains several administrative anomalies. From Tralles, we have intriguing signs that the rhythm of minting was not set on high. These are the unusual combinations of letters and monograms on Kleiner-Noe series 33–35, tetradrachms, didrachms, and drachms, which Ashton has read as Macedonian months.Footnote 129 Again, the sample size is small, and the die links imply a perhaps short-lived experiment. None of this disproves the existence of a central authority in the cistophoric system. It merely alerts us to the existence of countervailing forces of decentralization. When it came to money, Tralles wanted what every Greek state wanted in order to combat the “anarchy” of the ancient monetary world: some measure of control over the rhythm of the production of coinage – and with it, the shape of the money supply; some room for supple reactions to changing conditions.Footnote 130

Closure and Closed Currency Systems: The Ptolemaic Model

So much about Tralles was royal. It had fallen to the Attalids as a “gift” city at Apameia, and it seems to have displaced Sardis as the chief administrative center of the region. In Tralles, the Attalids constructed a palace and may have received extraordinary cultic honors.Footnote 131 However, the city’s minting reminds us of the complexity of the relationship between sovereignty and coinage in ancient Greece.Footnote 132 Yet, prima facie, Tralles seems unlikely to have exercised influence over the design of the scaffolding of the cistophoric system. Just outside the city’s gates was an open-air royal military encampment.Footnote 133 If the introduction of the cistophorus necessitated negotiation, Tralles was not in a position of strength. Yet the character of the cistophoric coinage was not “royal,” if by royal we mean that the coinage expresses raw domination. We must reckon with the iconoclastic appearance of the coins, while the role of royal authority in the system also cannot be denied. This is because the cistophoric zone was a closed monetary system. The only state around capable of launching and maintaining an epichoric coinage on this scale and territory was Pergamon, even if nothing was possible without the cooperation of the cities.

Confronted with a closed currency system within a Hellenistic kingdom, scholarship has always turned to well-documented Ptolemaic Egypt as both the historical and interpretive model for the cistophori. From Rostovtzeff to Mørkholm, the Attalids were seen to have taken direct inspiration from the Ptolemies.Footnote 134 For Le Rider and Callataÿ, the Attalids imitated the Ptolemies, but the model belonged to no one; closed currency systems were simply the norm in both classical and Hellenistic Greece.Footnote 135 Lost in all this is the distinctiveness of the Attalid case. In other words, even more than the term “royal,” the notion of closure lacks nuance in most accounts and potentially leads us astray. Unchallenged, the inapt Ptolemaic comparison impedes our understanding.Footnote 136

Leaving aside the question of its origins and motivations, how did the Ptolemaic system work in practice?Footnote 137 We know surprisingly little, but it is clear from the hoards that foreign coinage, both Attic-weight and foreign epichoric, ceased to circulate in Egypt ca. 310–ca. 300.Footnote 138 Over this period, the weight of the Ptolemaic silver coinage descended progressively from the Attic standard of ca. 17.25 g to its own epichoric standard of ca. 14.25. Around the same time, Ptolemy I also introduced reduced-weight gold and bronze coinages.Footnote 139 According to Gresham’s law, the reduced-weight coinages in precious metals would have forced the full-weight (i.e., Attic-weight) coinage, much of it foreign, out of circulation; and market forces alone would have kept Ptolemaic gold and silver coins from leaving Egypt, since their local value so exceeded their international one.Footnote 140 Yet it appears that the Ptolemaic state had a more active role to play in creating the homogeneity of the hoards. Relying on the indirect evidence of P.Cair.Zen. I 59021 of the year 258, one generally sees an official prohibition on the use of foreign coinage in the form of a prostagma issued ca. 300. Unfortunately, we do not possess the text of a law, just that famous letter of the mint official Demetrios to the royal dioikêtês Apollonios. It depicts a frustrated foreign merchant class waiting to change foreign (epichorion) gold coins and old Ptolemaic trichrysa into new Ptolemaic mnaieia after the reform of Ptolemy II. Their money is lying idle. The lesson is that, in Egypt, there were no options. The Ptolemaic state created a system in which the exclusive legal tender was whatever local coinage the king ruled valid. Buying and selling, all payments public and private, were to be conducted in the local coinage sanctioned by the Ptolemaic state.Footnote 141

Therefore, part of the standard reconstruction of economic life in Ptolemaic Egypt is the following scenario. A foreign trader arrives at port. To buy an export cargo, he will have to obtain Ptolemaic coinage. To buy Ptolemaic coinage, he must bring his foreign coinage into the country. It is possible that the import of coinage was taxed.Footnote 142 Having paid customs, the trader goes to a bank, where he changes foreign coinage into Ptolemaic coinage at officially prescribed rates of exchange – taking a 17% (?) loss on silver, perhaps even more on gold.Footnote 143 Of course he keeps some amount of foreign coinage on hand in anticipation of his final departure from Egypt. He wants to avoid repurchasing foreign coinage from the bank, coinage that he will need when he arrives at his next port of call. Foreign coinage was not contraband in Ptolemaic Egypt, but unacceptable as legal tender. This is why it is so rarely found in hoards post-ca. 300, but, occasionally, it does turn up.

To compare the situation in second-century Asia Minor, when the Attalids introduced the cistophorus at a weight 25% below the Attic standard, they ensured that the coins would not travel far. Royal authority clearly granted them a premium above their international value as silver bullion. This explains why we essentially never find a cistophoric coin in a hoard outside the Attalid kingdom – and indeed the singular example of one such coin in the Larissa hoard is usually considered an intrusion (IGCH 237; buried ca. 165). The cistophoric zone was closed in the sense that the cistophori did not slip out too easily. As Meadows points out, these silver coins behave just like any epichoric bronze: with all their fiduciary value, they are meant to stay put.Footnote 144 Yet the Ptolemaic – or Olbian – notion of closure was something else.Footnote 145 There, exchange as such was closed to foreign coinage, whether gold, silver, or bronze. In other words, whatever its real value in Egypt as precious metal, or its fiduciary value elsewhere as coin, non-Ptolemaic coinage could not serve as a means of payment in the Ptolemaic state. Contrary to popular belief, there is no firm basis for the view that the Attalids similarly banned the use of non-cistophoric coinage within the territory of their kingdom or even within some “cistophoric core,” the existence of which is scarcely visible in the hoard record and is in fact contradicted by the epigraphic record.Footnote 146 Ultimately, the cistophoric system outlived the Attalids and all their edicts. Yet to argue for a “hard” notion of closure, one often points to the hoard record for pre-133 cistophori, which, again, is poor in the extreme.Footnote 147 Almost all of the hoards contain only cistophori. However, the earliest hoard to include cistophori is mixed, the 1962 “Asia Minor” hoard IGCH 1453, containing 71+ silver coins, 42 of them cistophori, the rest, various Attic-weight coins, including five Pergamene. Meadows dates the deposit of this hoard to ca. 150 but is agnostic about its findspot.Footnote 148 To preserve the picture of a Ptolemaic-style closed system, Christof Boehringer, in publishing the hoard, placed it on the frontier between the cistophoric zone and the neighboring Attic-weight zone within the boundaries of the kingdom of Bithynia.Footnote 149 Yet consider also the fact that an unmixed hoard of 37 cistophori was found at Türktaciri on the Upper Sangarius, in the hinterland of Pessinous (CH VIII 446). That hoard, known as the Polatlı hoard, does not make the Galatian frontier part of the cistophoric core. Rather, it reminds us that the borders of the monetary zone as much as the kingdom were permeable and mutable. Among its 37 coins is a range of some of the earliest and latest series, right down to autonomous cistophoric issues of Ephesus securely dated 131/0.Footnote 150 In addition, all five of the largest mints are represented, in regular proportion to their size, making trade, as much as warfare, a plausible explanation for it on the Sangarius. Either trade or warfare could also explain the Ahmetbeyli hoard from the opposite, Aegean fringe (CH IX 535). Further, a large hoard of 120+ cistophoroi was found in the nineteenth century in Afyonkarahisar (IGCH 1415). Does it derive from a single military campaign or from healthy trade at the great emporion of Apameia?Footnote 151 We must admit our ignorance. In the end, what the evidence of hoards tells us is that the ancient user generally kept separate stores of cistophoric and non-cistophoric coinage, not that the Attalids proscribed the use of foreign coin. Hoarding practice does not necessarily reflect what was used or in circulation.Footnote 152

The logic of such a hoarding practice is that the monetary system is ramified. Different payments require different currencies. For the Attalid kingdom, then, we can reconstruct the following scenario. A foreign trader arrives at an Attalid port or at an inland interchange like Tralles, and he first pays customs. To what extent does he then change his foreign coinage, Attic-weight or epichoric, into cistophori, assuming he does not possess a reserve of them like the merchants of the Antikythera shipwreck?Footnote 153 The answer is that it depends on what kinds of payments he will make – and this is the crucial difference between the Ptolemaic and Attalid situations. For in the Attalid system, cistophoric coinage must have been required only for a certain a set of payments. Chief among these payments would have been official payments: taxes, fees, rents, and others, and so our hypothetical foreign trader could certainly not have avoided purchasing some cistophori. Of the official status of the money changer that he went to, we can say nothing. Yet in light of the comparative evidence, we can be fairly certain that the Attalid state fixed either the exchange rate or the exchange fee (agio), or perhaps both. In the fifth century, the Athenians set an official agio for the exchange of foreign coinage into owls in the so-called Coinage Decree (ML 45 line 5).Footnote 154 The citizens of Pontic Olbia set an official rate of exchange for their coinage against Cyzicene electrum staters (Syll.3 218 lines 24–26). In the end, this is part of the logic of any epichoric coinage: the state, whether it be a polis like Sestos or the Ptolemaic kingdom, gained revenue by forcing people into currency exchanges, and then profiting from its position of monopoly power over some aspect of those exchanges.Footnote 155

For a host of other payments inside the Attalid kingdom, one might have preferred or been compelled to make payments in Attic-weight silver or gold; or in a different epichoric coinage, the Rhodian, in places with strong economic ties to Rhodes, its peraia, and the Cyclades; or for small transactions, in the local epichoric bronze that cities minted without Attalid participation and without reference to the cistophoric standard.Footnote 156 It may have been that the deeper one went inland, the greater the number of payments requiring cistophori. But it need not have been so. Wherever you went, people were making payments in multiple coinages.

The Attalid Model

If we adopt a ramified vision of coinage in the Attalid kingdom, we can resolve several outstanding problems. The first is the troublesome matter of the extraordinarily high cost of exchanging non-cistophoric coinage for cistophoric. Assuming one exchanged an Attic-weight silver tetradrachm for a cistophorus, the commission was 25%, plus whatever agio was charged. The conventional agio in ancient Greece seems to have been ca. 5–7%, so the total premium of the cistophorus would have been near 30%.Footnote 157 Again, the Ptolemies are seen to have set a precedent with the high rate of exchange of 17%, their agio being around 10%, for a similarly high total premium of around 30%. Yet how can we compare the alluring resources of Ptolemaic Egypt with those of Attalid Asia Minor? To buy Egyptian grain, the premium was evidently palatable, and the Ptolemies in the Nile Valley enjoyed the perfect ecological niche for enforcing monopoly. In an analogous fashion, and perhaps with Ptolemaic support, the cities of Byzantium and Chalcedon profited from their peculiar ecology on the Bosphorus, but overreached ca. 235–220 when they tried to force an exchange rate of ca. 19% on users.Footnote 158 This is a limiting case: it seems that Rhodes went to war over the issue, and the closed currency system failed. Byzantium and Chalcedon lacked the resources to sustain the enterprise. For their part, the Attalids enjoyed neither a preciously unique ecological niche nor a productive base that could have justified a demanded premium of 25+%. There are no echoes in the sources of resistance to such measures, which surely would have represented a painful restructuring of economic life, nor signs of the kind of coercive enforcement necessary to sustain a truly closed currency system on this territory. It is impossible to explain how the Attalids managed to impose and maintain the kind of closed system that succeeded in Egypt but ultimately failed in the Propontis. However, this is a question mal posée. Those are inappropriate points of comparison.

We can now also make sense of the large amount of Attic-weight silver minted in Attalid Asia Minor after the cistophoric reform, with both royal (Marcellesi nos. 42–44) and civic types. First, we can dispense with the idea that these were “export coinages.” By sheer volume, they must have been an important part of the money supply of Asia Minor. Consider, for example, that Myrina produced a total of 445 Attic drachm obverse equivalents in Wreathed Coinage, while Ephesus coined a total of 486 in Attalid-era cistophori.Footnote 159 Of course, as international coinage, these coins were particularly useful for exchange with outsiders. Yet we need not doubt that they passed between insiders too, if we can accept that there existed a series of nonofficial payments for which these coins were legal tender. Selene Psoma restricts these transactions to the fairs of religious festivals, where in her view, locals were required to use Attic-weight coinage to make purchases.Footnote 160 These were largely big-ticket items like slaves and livestock, and the vendors were outsiders. She adduces the tetradrachm of the technitai of Dionysus (of Ionia and the Hellespont), and the Attic silver called for in the Archippe dossier from Kyme, prescribed for the purchase of a victim. Indeed, one could explain the rare gold staters of Tralles similarly. Like Kyme, the city needed to buy a bull for a festival sacrifice. Yet why should the city be required to purchase the bull (1) from an outsider and (2) under the special conditions of festival commerce? The associations of the technitai, after all, were regional; in Asia Minor, they were intimates of the Attalid court – these were not outsiders. Psoma’s point is salutary, but she has isolated only one of the contexts for which Attic-weight coinage would have been usable and useful.

It is difficult to shine a light directly on those other contexts for Attic-weight coinage in the Attalid kingdom, but we possess tantalizing clues such as the Athenian New Style tetradrachm with the countermark of bull protome (Thompson no. 184b). Margaret Thompson dated the issue of the coin, in Athens, to 175/4, but the whole series has long been downdated. On David Lewis’ influential chronology, the Athenians issued the coin some 33 years later.Footnote 161 Picard’s downward shift is only 20 years, but he also questions the assumption of uninterrupted minting.Footnote 162 On any of these chronologies, a coin minted at least one or two decades before 133 can plausibly be imagined to have entered circulation in the Attalid kingdom. The same is true of a related coin, the Sidetan tetradrachm that recently surfaced at auction bearing both the bull protome countermark and a cistophoric countermark – this Attic-weight coin obviously circulated in the late Attalid kingdom.

The problem is a familiar one of how to interpret the countermark. Rather than see it as remonetizing a coin that is no longer money once it travels inside the cistophoric zone, we can see it as expanding the range of transactions for which the coin is acceptable. Whoever conveyed this tetradrachm considered it money. The countermark only extended its acceptability, and perhaps cleared up some ambiguity about its value. For example, was the slightly lightweight New Style tetradrachm really worth four Attic drachms? The countermark did not remonetize the coin, but may have allowed it to enter the transactional sphere of local taxes. It is a stark reminder that civic fiscality had its own relationship with coinage to maintain.Footnote 163

Dispensing with the Ptolemaic model also allows us to clarify the role of bronze coinage in the Attalid monetary system after the cistophoric reform. In Egypt, closure meant the application of standard ratios of value between Ptolemaic gold, silver, and bronze. Thus, when the Ptolemies altered the weights and denominational structure of their bronze, the papryi reflect the consistent application of the new ratio. Around 260, Philadelphos was even able to impose a heavy bronze coin at value equal to his silver drachma.Footnote 164 Granted, the Attalid state will have had a hand in fixing the rates at which moneychangers in the kingdom sold their cistophori, rates that were reckoned in gold, bronze, or other silver. The state had to safeguard its profit with a fixed exchange rate – precisely what the Athenians do in the Coinage Decree, or what we see the Roman emperor Hadrian attending to in an Imperial-period decree from Pergamon (OGIS 484). Yet the Attalids minted no gold and, at the beginning of the second century, appear to have stopped minting bronze in the name of Philetairos.Footnote 165 New bronze issues appear in the era of the cistophori, a civic bronze in the name of the citizens of Pergamon (Marcellesi nos. 63–67) and coins in the name of deities such as Athena Nikephoros and Asklepios Soter (Marcellesi nos. 53–62). Crucially, their denominational structure and, therefore presumably, the values affixed to bronze coinages changed little from the third to the second century. Larger denominations (obols and diobols) are added in the second century.Footnote 166 Yet we see no reform of the bronze to match the cistophoric reform in silver, such as is visible in the case of the Rhodian plinthophori.Footnote 167 Effectively, the Attalids had at most an indirect influence over the value of bronze coins trading in an entire sea of transactions.Footnote 168

The value of bronze coins was not determined solely by the asking price for cistophori, but far more directly by the issuing authorities. And those authorities were the cities of the Attalid kingdom, which granted a fiduciary value to their own bronze coins. This has often escaped notice because it has long been conventional to use 133 as a terminus post quem for many late Hellenistic bronzes of Asia Minor, to assume, unjustifiably, an Attalid prohibition of civic bronze.Footnote 169 Long-running excavations in the imperial metropole have turned up a restricted range of other cities’ bronze.Footnote 170 The picture that emerges is of each city attending to its own needs for bronze, choosing the value and acceptability of coin for this tier of the monetary system. We are very far indeed from Ptolemaic Egypt.

The Cistophori: A Coordinated Coinage

Part of the justification for examining in detail the incongruence of the Ptolemaic and Attalid systems is that we can now distinguish the banal from the exceptional. A ramified monetary system, which coupled closure, in the form of a silver coinage removed from the international standard of its day, with an openness absent from Egypt (and Rhodes?) was in fact commonplace. The impermeable Ptolemaic system and the open system of the Seleukids were, in fact, the outliers of the Hellenistic world. The norm for most Greek states was a mixed regime: epichoric coinage was required for one set of transactions, while the rest, to paraphrase the decree of Olbia, was a matter of persuasion.Footnote 171 This is just what we have envisioned for the Attalid kingdom. It is instructive here to recall that in the late 180s, the Attalids had twice asked the Kardakes for a certain tax to be paid in Rhodian coin. It should then be no stretch of the imagination to propose that after ca. 167, the Pergamene state was prescribing a specific coinage – the cistophori – for a certain set of official payments. This exposes what is truly strange about the cistophoric system: its size. Instead of imitating the Ptolemies, the Attalids acted rather like a polis with an exceptionally large chora.Footnote 172

However, as we have shown, the Attalids did not act alone. They decentralized minting, and they seemed to have ceded to local actors some measure of control over the shape of the money supply and the rhythm of its production. Indeed, the cistophoric experiment succeeded only with the help of the cities. Just consider once more how currency exchange would have worked, our lack of epigraphical or literary sources notwithstanding. Either the exchange rate or the agio (or both) would have been fixed and standard across the kingdom. This is what all our comparative evidence tells us – this is the logic of an epichoric coinage. We have no way of knowing which kinds of banks performed the exchange, but we can be sure that many were in the agoras of cities, not confined to royal customs stations on a kind of cistophoric frontier encircling the kingdom.Footnote 173 We know from the subscription of Colophon in 310 and the audit of Teos in the third century that, in western Asia Minor, people were used to holding portfolios of different currencies.Footnote 174 By the mid-second century, could things have changed so much? In these conditions, it was difficult to prevent people from making private deals that allowed them to avoid paying the state its due premium. The challenge had motivated earlier Greek cities to appoint official enforcers and impose heavy penalties for noncompliance.Footnote 175 The problem was endemic to the ancient Mediterranean, and it still plagued the city of Pergamon in the time of Hadrian. There, the agoranomoi failed to suppress an active black market in the city’s bronze coins.Footnote 176 The problem of compliance was formidable enough in the marketplace or territory of a single polis, but the Attalids needed surveillance, policing, and communication across the wide expanse of their newly expanded kingdom. They needed, in a word, cooperation.Footnote 177

In their prolegomenon to the study of what they call “cooperative coinages,” Emily Mackil and Peter van Alfen have drawn attention to a broad category of inter- and intrastate minting arrangements that remain poorly understood. Emphasizing the costs and complexities of the enterprise, Mackil and van Alfen seek explanations for why distinct polities submitted to mint together. Reacting against a tradition that read these coins as a straightforward expression of political union or domination, they propose a variety of economic explanations: “If, however, in each case it is possible to provide an economic explanation for the (functional) cooperation of multiple cities in minting coinage, then we need to ask whether any hegemonic factor is really significant.”Footnote 178 The point is particularly trenchant for our understanding of a multiscalar polity like the koinon. In the case of the early Boiotian Koinon, for example, cooperative minting preceded political federation. In most other cases, it appears at about the same time as other formal institutions at the regional level. In other words, cooperative minting is not an expression of a new political hegemony, but rather a way to institutionalize preexistent economic interdependence. In fact, instead of a hegemon, an ecological imperative can compel cities to cooperate.Footnote 179

By contrast, the cistophoric coinage entailed a coordinated form of cooperation. Mackil and van Alfen seem to cast kingdom (basileia) as another multiscalar polity, but it is left out of their discussion.Footnote 180 Yet here, there can be no doubt: political hegemony precedes the cooperative arrangement of minting and using these coins. Here, the significance of the hegemonic factor can be explained. It was the singular role of the Attalid state to coordinate between the different polities. Revenues may very well have been shared, but the fiscal benefits of the system were still distinctly advantageous for Pergamon. Across the kingdom, it became cheaper for the king to collect taxes and make gifts. Also, Attalid Asia Minor was an artificial conglomeration of regional economies, unlike the fragile but coherent economies of Achaia or Boiotia or, to compare an ethnos-based kingdom, Antigonid Macedonia with its economically complementary regional divisions (merides), purposively shattered by the Romans. For their part, the Attalids imposed a political hegemony on a group of regional economies oriented variously and only loosely interconnected. On Pamphylia, the Propontis, the Troad, and the Maeander Valley, they had to impose economic as well as political integration.Footnote 181 The cistophori differ from many other cooperative coinages in that the accent is on the production of new economic behaviors, patterns, and links, rather than on the regularization and maintenance of old ones.

The cistophori, then, represent a special class of cooperative coinage, which is usefully termed “coordinated coinage.” We retain the economic raison d’être, but we also take account of the role of the political hegemon, the coordinator. Because a coordinated coinage presupposes the cooperation of civic institutions, it is again important to keep in mind the developmental trajectory of those institutions in the second century. In creating the cistophoric system, the Attalids drew on a reservoir of civic institutional know-how long in the making. They were also able to rely on a network of civic elites, who, increasingly rich and powerful, were asserting ever more control over local institutions.Footnote 182 These were men such as Menas of Sestos, who was both an Attalid official and a civic moneyer, someone who cared for the affairs of the king but also for the pride of his city (I.Sestos 1, lines 12, 46). As we have seen, the system rewarded cooperation. Cooperation, however, is not the same as coordination. This is one of the conclusions of Levi in her fiscal sociology of revenue collection.Footnote 183 She argues that successful fiscal regimes promote “quasi-voluntary compliance,” through either institutional or ideological means. Compliance is higher where fiscal institutions are more cooperative. Yet people also cooperate with the tax-collecting state because they believe it is in their interest. The state gives them something in return. Ultimately, the cistophoric system engendered a level of economic integration in Asia Minor that buffered risk for all, and the revenues, along with the responsibilities, were likely shared. The Attalids offered their subjects the service of coordination, itself a public good and a reward worthy of their cooperation.

Monetary Change after Apameia

Explaining the Countermarks

In the cistophori, we have explained just one aspect of the monetary change ushered in with the Treaty of Apameia. Yet we have also developed a framework for analyzing two other numismatic puzzles of this period, the so-called cistophoric countermarks, which preceded the cistophori, and the Wreathed Coinages, which were an integral part of the money supply after the cistophoric reform. Again, we need to consider the broader context of Hellenistic coinage, since no one minted into a void. In Asia Minor of the 180s and 170s, the silver coinage of one state countermarked by another would not have been an uncommon sight. While the Seleukid anchor and Helios countermarks seem to begin slightly later than the cistophoric ones, nearby in the Propontis, the practice was time-honored.Footnote 184 From precisely this period, the Propontis hoard (IGCH 888) contains a tetradrachm of Phaselis bearing a cistophoric countermark of Pergamon.Footnote 185 Earlier, Byzantium and Chalcedon had countermarked large quantities of Ptolemaic coinage for much of the third century.Footnote 186 Moreover, the Propontis hoard shows that civic countermarks of Cyzicus, the letters ΚΥ ΖΙ within a wreath, were contemporaneous with the cistophoric countermarks, stamped on the very same Attic-weight silver tetradrachms from Pamphylia. For Thonemann, the ΚΥ ΖΙ countermarks are numismatic evidence that Cyzicus was not part of the expanded Attalid kingdom.Footnote 187 We should be more cautious. Like the countermark of bull protome, or the Tyche countermarks of Smyrna (?) and the grape cluster of Temnos (?), the Cyzicene one proves only that a city took action to control its local money supply.Footnote 188 The cistophori and the Wreathed Coinages both imply that the Attalids regularly afforded cities that latitude.

Therefore, in countermarking, the Attalids adopted a practice seemingly widespread in the nearby Propontis, which a number of other states took up at roughly the same time. Yet why they chose to countermark is not always clear. The standard explanation of the function of the countermark, as embodied by Seyrig’s telling of the “Phoenician episode” on the Bosphorus and in an influential essay of Le Rider, has clouded the discussion.Footnote 189 For a period of about 15 years (ca. 235–ca. 220), Byzantium and Chalcedon jointly minted silver on a reduced, so-called Phoenician standard, very close to the Ptolemaic standard of 14 or 13.5 g to the tetradrachm. Simultaneously, the two cities seem to have countermarked all Attic-weight silver, mostly foreign, but also their own Lysimachi.Footnote 190 Also, since at least the early 260s, Byzantium’s countermarks had been placed on Ptolemaic tetradrachms minted at Alexandria. Further, we now know that Byzantium and Chalcedon minted Lysmachi unceasingly into the second century. A number of different monetary experiments, then, seem to have taken place on the Bosphorus between the 260s and the 220s. So while for Seyrig, the “Phoenician” silver created a closed currency system in order to raise revenue during the acute crisis reported by Polybius (4.37.8–10, 4.45.1–53.1), Thomas Russell’s treatment of the new evidence concludes that under financial pressure from the Galatians, Byzantium and Chalcedon had already closed the system with Ptolemaic support several decades prior.Footnote 191

The unique ecological niche of the Bosphorus and the aggregate coercive power of Byzantium, Chalcedon, and the Ptolemies may have, for spurts of time, made it possible to close off the region’s currency system completely. We should not, however, use the case both as a general template for understanding countermarking and, specifically, to explain the cistophoric countermarks. The idea is that it only makes sense to countermark a (foreign) silver coin in order to either remonetize it or retariff it. The theory of remonetization has nothing to commend it. It was plausible when the cistophoric countermarks were seen to accompany the cistophori themselves, or if the cistophoric zone is seen to be hermetically sealed. Yet it is doubtful whether any ancient Greek state, other than Ptolemaic Egypt, could in fact demonetize good silver coinage, especially international nomisma hellenikon. The theory of retariffing is more suggestive, if by retariffing a coin, we mean increasing its local value relative to its value elsewhere. With the countermark, the state told the user that the coin was now acceptable for certain local payments. Was its new value reckoned in epichoric coinage, or was it assimilated to an epichoric coin? It is impossible to know, and the situation would have varied. If we want an axiom, it is that countermarking a precious metal coin increased its likelihood of remaining in the local money supply.

From this perspective, the logic of Attalid countermarking becomes clear. We can divorce our discussion of the cistophoric countermarks from speculation about the source of the host coins and the means by which they entered circulation. One tends not to challenge Bauslaugh’s suggestion that the Pamphylian host coins represent a part of the Seleukid indemnity paid to the Attalids according to the Treaty of Apameia.Footnote 192 With most having given up on the idea of using the indemnity to interpret the monetary behavior of the Seleukids themselves in this period, it makes little sense to place so much weight on it in the Attalid context.Footnote 193 Even more problematic is Bauslaugh’s reconstruction of the administrative procedure behind the countermarks, for it is based on an untenable notion of “earmarking.”Footnote 194 In his view, the cities of the Attalid kingdom possessed no revenues of their own, but only received “earmarked” revenues from the royal treasury. In similar fashion, Eumenes II would have received the indemnity directly from Antioch, and then disbursed various portions to twelve cities. Those cities would then have countermarked the coins with the common symbol of the bow in case and their individual ethnics, releasing the coins into circulation.

Lost in all this is what motivated the costly administrative procedure in the first place. These coins are good Attic-weight silver – if traceable to the indemnity, the “best” (to argyrion attikon ariston) (Polyb. 21.43.19). Why go to the trouble? Because the imperative was to keep the silver from leaking out of the local money supply, which the metal was wont to do in a world where its global price was steadily increasing, attracting silver coin to where its buying power was greatest.Footnote 195 The countermark reversed the imbalance, making the coin more valuable at home than abroad. Further, in the cistophoric countermarks, we see twelve cities, many of them newly Attalid, previously belonging to diverse monetary systems, suddenly cooperating to meet this challenge on an impressive scale. For presumably, the cistophoric countermark of one city was an expression of the acceptability of the coin in any of the other countermarking cities. The mental map of those who used these coins started to look ever more like the physical one drawn up at Apameia. Functionally, the countermarking system was an initial step in the process of political and economic integration that came to fruition after 167 in the form of the cistophori and Wreathed Coinages.

The Mineralogical Background

Before we turn to that changed landscape of the Greek East after Pydna, we must pause to consider the question of the ostensible scarcity of the silver in the Attalid kingdom, in the geology of western Anatolia. It has often been erroneously assumed that, no less than Egypt, the region lacked deep veins of silver. First, it is important to mind the difference between the general dearth of silver in the eastern Mediterranean of the late Hellenistic period and any local irregularities in its availability.Footnote 196 The distinction is crucial for interpreting any monetary behavior that economizes on silver – either the countermarking, as we have conceived of it, or minting on a reduced standard. Granted, Rome withdrew large amounts of precious metal from the money supply of the eastern Mediterranean in the form of spoils and indemnities, and as Pliny the Elder noticed, the Romans preferred to be paid in silver (HN 33.15.51).Footnote 197 Roman exaction was a major factor, but just one among several behind the gradually increasing scarcity of silver in this period.Footnote 198 The consequences of this slow, steady drain of silver were twofold. First, because the demand for silver coinage was basically constant, a silver coin was now worth more relative to its weight in bullion. In other words, the buying power of silver coin was on the rise. This means that the value added to silver bullion by measuring and minting it, by stamping it with the state’s imprimatur, was also greater than before. There was plenty of silver bullion around; states just had a greater incentive to monetize it, to mint it on a reduced standard, and to add more fiduciary value. This is most evident in the silver coinage of Antiochos IV, which descended toward a standard 2% below the true Attic.Footnote 199

The second, related consequence was that epichoric standards began to proliferate. Just like the countermarks, epichoric weight ensured that the coin remained nearby, and thus was protection against local irregularities in the supply of silver. But these standards also capitalized on the general uptick in the value of silver. It had become easier for states to add fiduciary value to the coins’ real value as a piece of bullion. In fact, the cistophori belong to an entire class of large epichoric coinages, including symmachic (reduced Aiginetan) and Rhodian coinages on various standards, which came to dominate certain regions in this period.Footnote 200

In an ironic twist to the standard explanation of acute shortage, the cistophori point to considerable Attalid reserves in silver. The introduction of a new epichoric coinage – on such a scale and at such a high degree of fineness – presupposes a vast accumulation of metal.Footnote 201 For a reform of this nature was designed to appear not in fits and starts, but as a deluge, which transforms a supra-regional monetary system. Indeed, the die counts tell us that the cistophori were in fact minted in much greater numbers in the initial two decades than after ca. 150.Footnote 202 While the tax receipts of the years 188–ca. 167 may have contained much of the needed silver, according to current archaeometallurgy, it is almost certain that sources of silver were in fact available to the Attalids within their own kingdom.Footnote 203 Interestingly, Strabo (14.5.28) tells us of a mining settlement between Atarneus and Pergamon (modern Ovacık?), which by his time had been worked to exhaustion, and also of the evocatively named Argyria on the Aisepos, the so-called birthplace of silver (13.1.45).Footnote 204 While the Troad was famed for its metals in Antiquity, it is difficult to match remains to the reports of Homer or Strabo, or to the testimony of early travelers and modern ethnographers about lead and silver mining near classical Neandria.Footnote 205 On the other hand, the western plain of the Kaikos contains a gold and silver mine at Ovacık still active today.Footnote 206 In the Attalids’ own backyard of Mysia, evidence of ancient mining and slag have been found at the well-known deposit of lead-silver at Balya Maaden (Balıkesir province), famous for cannonball manufacturing during Ottoman times, and one of the largest silver mines in the Middle East, exploited during a period of rapid industrialization between 1880 and 1939. Indeed, it is now active again because the entire Biga Peninsula, to which Balya belongs geologically, has been deemed one of the most active metallogenic regions in the world.Footnote 207 Further, the ancient route from Pergamon to Cyzicus passes by Balya, and it was on this road that Galen tells us a silver-mining settlement called Ergastêria was located (De Simp. Med. XII 229 line 16 to 230 line 5). On the site of Balya, an archaeometallurgical survey catalogued a tremendous number of ancient cuttings, but also clear evidence of Hellenistic occupation.Footnote 208 If in Rostovtzeff’s time it was simply assumed that the Attalids exploited Balya Maaden, today the archaeological case is much stronger. In 2017, Balıkesir University archaeometallurgist Ahmet Baştürk presented a history of lead-zinc exploitation in the region that takes 500 BCE as its starting point.Footnote 209 We have no reason to postulate a lack of silver in the Attalid kingdom.

Explaining the Wreathed Coinages

The Antigonid collapse in the Third Macedonian War permanently altered the political complexion of the Mediterranean. For contemporaries, Polybius tells us, the conflict was a final and decisive battle for absolute hegemony: “viewing the final decision and the subjection of the whole world by one power (ὁρώντων κρινόµενα τὰ ὅλα καὶ τὴν τῆς οἰκουµένης ἐξουσίαν ὑπὸ µίαν ἀρχὴν πίπτουσαν)” (30.6.6). In his speech Oratio pro Rhodiensibus, Cato the Elder shows us Greek onlookers reluctant to support Rome for fear of living in a monopolar world: “It was with an eye to their own freedom that they held that opinion, in order not to be under our sole dominion and enslaved to us (ne sub solo imperio nostro in servitute nostra essent, libertatis suae causa in ea sententia fuisse arbitror)” (fr. 95b). The destruction of Corinth was yet to come, as well as the creation of the provinces of Macedonia and Achaea, but it was already clear to both Rhodes and Pergamon that the rules of the game had changed.Footnote 210 This was the new geopolitical environment in which the cistophori as well as the Wreathed Coinages appeared. The production of both coinages entailed the cooperation of royal and civic institutions. Yet Attalid involvement with the Wreathed Coinages is not self-evident. No less an authority than Le Rider has seen them as purely civic in nature.Footnote 211 Taking the Attalid role seriously requires us to briefly consider the phenomenon of proxy coinage in the Hellenistic world. A proxy coinage is a coinage minted in the name of one polity at least in part out of bullion and institutional resources provided by another, larger polity – a cooperative, if not always coordinated minting arrangement.

The practice of coining by proxy was commonplace for Hellenistic kings and early Roman provincial administrators in Greece and Asia Minor. Specific cases may be open to question, but the phenomenon as such is well known. Some of these coinages openly declare the involvement of outsiders. For example, Erythrai, ca. 306–304, minted bronze coins bearing the portrait of Demetrios Poliorketes on the obverse, and the mark ΕΡΥ along with the name of a local magistrate on the reverse. The citizens of Smyrna under Lysimachus minted bronzes that seem to depict the king’s daughter Eurydike, accompanied by their new ethnic ΕΥΡΥΔΙΚΕΙΩΝ (“of the Eurydikeians”). Similarly, the Ephesians, as the Arsinoeis, put the face of Arsinoe II on their bronze, accompanied by distinctly civic control marks.Footnote 212 Such marks allow us to understand some drachms of Corinth under Ptolemaic rule as a proxy coinage.Footnote 213 Certain proxy coinages are easy to spot, such as the silver didrachms minted in Corcyra, bearing the face of Antiochos III on the obverse and the legend ΑΙΤΩΛΩΝ on the reverse.Footnote 214 For others, as Hans-Christoph Noeske has shown in attempting to track Ptolemaic gifts in the numismatic record of mainland Greece, we have to look beneath the surface.Footnote 215 This is usually a matter of evaluating the appropriate scale of a coinage, using the synthetic scale established for Hellenistic coinages by Callataÿ to measure appropriateness.Footnote 216 Interestingly, from ca. 170, suspiciously large coinages in the names of small- or medium-sized polities proliferate: the tetrobols of Histiaea, pseudo-Rhodian drachms from central and northern Greece, the Macedonian Meris coinage – even the Athenian New Style tetradrachms – have come in for interrogation. For the Histiaean and pseudo-Rhodian issues, some postulate Perseus as the source, but in most cases, Rome is the prime candidate, for the triumph of the denarius was yet a long way off in the second century.Footnote 217 Meadows has provided a helpful point of comparison for the Wreathed Coinages in the large silver issues of Pamphylian cities associated with Seleucid campaigns of the late third and early second century.Footnote 218

The size of the Wreathed Coinages, in total roughly equal to that of contemporary cistophori, has long seemed suspicious, but our analysis of the monetary habits of the Attalids now allows us to make sense of it. It is important to remember that each city minted on a different schedule, over the course of a generation and beyond.Footnote 219 The rhythm of production could reflect an Attalid payment schedule or a local need for coin, but it was most likely some combination of the two. We know that the Attalids ceded more than bullion here, as the iconography of the coins, often the cult image of a patron deity of the city, is expressly civic. The Wreathed Coinages lack the visual nod to the higher order polity that is common to many cooperative coinages of multiscalar states. If this minting arrangement relied on civic institutions and afforded civic actors some measure of control over the shape of their local money supply, it was not unlike the cistophoric system. In fact, these were two complementary and, to a degree, coordinated parts of the money supply of the Attalid kingdom. Yet the full scope of that complementarity is apparent only when we accept that the locally produced Attic-weight coinage was also exchanged between locals.Footnote 220 The monetary needs of the outwardly oriented coastal cities differed from those of communities of inner Anatolia. Yet as the Ahmetbeyli hoard from the territory of Colophon reminds us, cistophori also circulated on the coastal fringe. Ultimately, the nature of the transaction determined the choice of currency, not the geographic zone.Footnote 221

At root, neither the practice of minting a proxy coinage nor even a coordinated coinage sets the Attalids apart. In precisely this period, we see other minting experiments that meet our definition of coordinated coinage. One example is the so-called municipal bronzes of Levantine and Cilician cities under Antiochos IV, featuring royal portraits, civic ethnics, and an array of weight standards.Footnote 222 Another example are Macedonian coinages, minted in bronze and silver, in the name of the different merides. On the basis of Livy, it was long thought that these administrative regions were Roman inventions, but the numismatic record shows that Philip V and Perseus delegated the power of the mint to these regions.Footnote 223 Such coinages are an expression of civic and regional identities that received a new hearing after the humbling of the Antigonids and Seleukids in the early second century. Properly harnessed, the administrative infrastructure by which these identities were being expressed was, ironically, a tool of resistance wielded against the new hegemon, Rome. The coinage, then, from the countermarks to the Wreathed Coinages and cistophori, is simply a measure of how much farther the Attalids were willing to go to make use of these forces.

Our interpretations of each of these monetary practices, including our new understanding of the cistophori, do not rely for their validity on the firm dates that numismatics can seldom provide. Rather, they draw on a wide body of comparative material in order to explain the nature of Attalid imperialism, which in this domain, no less than taxation or benefaction, promoted civic identities and instrumentalized civic institutions. Still, if we place the start of the cistophori in ca. 167, with the Wreathed Coinages taking off over the following decade, the historical implications are significant. In terms of the political dynamics of the Mediterranean, we have emphasized the transformative impact of the Antigonid defeat in the Third Macedonian War. For the Attalids, the crisis did not end at Pydna, since the revolt of the Galatians had broken out in 168 and would continue until 165.Footnote 224 The notorious Attalid penchant for bolstering their power with the threat, real or perceived, of the Galatian menace, best known from officially commissioned works of art, should not obscure the gravity of the conflict. The anecdote of Polyaenus, which relates how a weakened Eumenes II sat in an open-air throne above a pass to deceive his Galatian pursuers, reminds us of the seriousness of the conflict from the Attalid perspective: this war required the personal attention of the king, who stationed himself on the front lines at Apameia.Footnote 225 Indeed, in this context, the short-lived cistophoric production of south Phrygia becomes much more comprehensible. In fact, the entire post-Apameian kingdom appeared to be coming apart at the seams, and the Attalids looked for a way to reconstitute and reinforce an imperial space. Their solution was this puzzling new monetary system, which confounds our categories, those rooted in an antiquarian and artificial distinction between royal and civic. Ptolemaic Egypt was not the model. Rather, this was an unprecedented and daring experiment in the devolution of the power of the mint – successful because it relied on both the pride and know-how of cities and also the silver stock of Anatolia.

Footnotes

1 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 120–25.

2 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 10; Szaivert 2008; Seyrig 1963. To compare two divergent characterizations in recent scholarship, Daubner (Reference Daubner2006, 74) emphasizes the initiative and profits of the cities (“nicht von oben oktroyiert”), while Thonemann (2013b, 33) writes of “projection of this ‘pseudo-federal’ ideology.”

3 Le Rider 1989, 189.

4 Picard 2010, 189–90. Meadows 2018 illustrates the transformation in Greek coin design, ca. 170 to ca. 140, which upended categories of Hellenic and epichoric, royal and civic. See esp. p. 310 on cross-pollination between new civic coinage and unusual royal issues of Antiochos IV and Ptolemy V.

5 Cf. Harl Reference Harl1991, 281: “The defeat of Antiochus III on the plains of Magnesia wrought major political and monetary consequences for the eastern Mediterranean.” On the mint of Pergamon specifically, see Chameroy Reference Chameroy2012, 154: no change in the bronze coinage of Pergamon can be linked to the events of 188.

6 Identifying numbers for Pergamene coin types are given from Marcellesi 2012.

8 Meadows (2013, 164) posits a gap from the end of Westermark Group VI B2 to the beginning of Group VII; cf. Marcellesi 2012, 122–23, assuming continuous production of Philetairoi. On her chronology, Group VII was launched with the cistophori, just before 190.

9 Meadows 2013, 163.

10 Cf. Marcellesi 2012, 180–83, arguing for continuous production of the Philetairoi, with Group VII minted from the 190s to the 160s. Contemporary Alexanders from Miletus: Marcellesi 2004, 137–39.

11 For the hoard evidence that points to 188–183, see Bauslaugh Reference Bauslaugh1990, 53–55. Cf. Meadows 2013, 170–73: a date range of 188–180; similarly, Callataÿ 2013, 225. For the Pamphylian host coinage, see Mørkholm 1978; Meadows 2009.

12 For Toriaion and Sala in Lydia, see Thonemann 2008. In a forthcoming contribution to the festschrift for Richard Ashton, Thonemann eliminates Sala from consideration and proposes the strategeia of the Hellespont for ΕΛΗΣ, ΕΛ/ΛΗ, ΕΛΛΗ.

13 Cf. Marcellesi 2012, 136–39: the years ca. 190–ca. 170 witnessed the production of the cistophoric countermarks, in her view, contemporary with the minting of the first cistophori.

14 Bauslaugh Reference Bauslaugh1990, 50.

15 The ancients were more precise. A Delian account specifically refers to the large-module coin as a tetradrachm: κιστοφόρον τετρᾶχμον (I.Delos 1443 A1 line 149). For a review of literary references to cistophori, see Szaivert Reference Szaivert2005.

16 I will discuss below the important question of whether we treat these legends as an abbreviation of a city’s name or as a proper ethnic. Le Rider 1990, esp. 685, and Drew-Bear and Le Rider 1991, e.g., treat them as an ethnic.

17 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 15.

18 For the relationship to the denarius, circulating in Greece from ca. 150 BCE, see Harl 1996, 68–69. While the ratio of 3:1 must have facilitated accounts during episodic joint military operations, it does little to illuminate the logic of the cistophoric system, as the denarius arrived in Asia Minor only in the second half of the first century BCE.

19 The most systematic exposition is Szaivert 2008.

21 Kosmetatou Reference Kosmetatou1998, 17.

22 Marcellesi 2012, 146. On the citizens of Pergamon as the Telephidai, see also Heres 1996, 83.

23 Ohlemutz 1968, 118–19. On Dionysos and the Attalids, see conveniently Dignas 2012, 134–35. However, the snake-in-cista motif does exist in the iconography of the cult of Dionysos (and Asklepios). See Ogden Reference Ogden2013, 363.

24 Picard 2010, 19. See also the bronze coin of Perinthos in nearby Propontic Thrace (ca. 138–192 CE) that features a veiled Demeter/snake emerging from cista: Schönert-Geiß, Die Münzprägung von Perinthos no. 173.2, p. 117, pl. 7, pic. 173/2 (Perinthos CN_2164, in Corpus Nummorum: www.corpus-nummorum.eu/CN_2164 [accessed June 29, 2020]). Further, the snake-in-the-box motif also appears in the Talmud (t. Yoma 22b) in connection with the worship of Persephone in Roman Palestine. See Meshorer Reference Meshorer1981. See further the important study of Krengel Reference Krengel2016, which argues that both the Palestinian and the Pergamene coins refer to an Orphic theogony. On the cistophoros, therefore, we should see Zeus-Sabazios in the form of a snake on both sides of the coin, begetting Dionysus on the obverse, and on the reverse, mating with Demeter to produce Persephone.

25 Cf. Szaivert 2008, 29–30, interpreting the snakes of the reverse as those strangled by young Herakles. Generally on benevolent snakes in Greek myth and religion, see Ogden Reference Ogden2013, 271–382.

26 Chalchis: BMC Central Greece nos. 38–40. For the eagle-destroys-serpent motif on grave stelai of late Hellenistic Bithynia, see Akyürek Şahin and Uzunoğlu Reference Akyürek Şahin and Uzunoğlu2019, 267–68.

27 The same scene appears on a late Hellenistic votive relief from just outside the Asklepieion. See Bauchhenss-Thüriedl Reference Bauchhenss-Thüriedl1971, 69–70.

28 Suda s.v. ἀργόλαι (Α3781).

29 Djurslev and Ogden Reference Djurslev and Ogden2018.

30 Strabo 13.1.14; Nollé 1992, 92–96; Krengel Reference Krengel2016, 18. On the serpentine dragons of Anatolian myth in popular memory of the Roman period, see Rojas Reference Rojas2019, 80–82, 127–37.

31 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 78–85.

32 Bauslaugh (Reference Bauslaugh1990, 48) announces the discovery of a pre-133 cistophoros of Adramyttion and planned publication. That coin, which is Paris 2600 ex Slg. Garriri, Smyrna, 1853, was later published by Josef Stauber as I.Adramytteion II, 208, no. 94. For a catalogue of cistophoric countermarks of Adramytteion and the city’s large production of late cistophori, see I.Adramytteion II, 206–11.

33 Thonemann 2008, 53–58. For other suggestions, see Marcellesi 2012, 118–20.

34 Callataÿ 2013, 239. For the methodology for calculating the original number of dies, see Carter Reference Carter1983. For the much more controversial calculation of the original size of the coinage from that number, see Callataÿ 2011b. By number of “obverse die equivalents,” I mean, according to the widely accepted method of Carter, how many obverse dies were used to strike the coinage, converted into a standard unit of an Attic drachm obverse die. The numbers presented in this chapter make no assumption about average die productivity (20,000 strikes per die?) other than that it was roughly constant.

35 See Kleiner-Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 10–16; Meadows 2013, 175–83, favoring a date of 167. Callataÿ 2013, 218–31, more cautious about the relationship between the Maaret hoard and the inception of the cistophori, offers a loose date in the 170s; Marcellesi 2012, 132–44, with a date just before 190.

36 Livy: 37.46.3–4, 37.58.3–5, 37.59.3–6, 39.7.1–2, 5. See further Harl Reference Harl1991 and Marcellesi 2012, 140–44.

37 Nicolet-Pierre Reference Nicolet-Pierre and Rider1989, 208–15.

38 Mattingly 1993.

39 The 1968 Larissa (Sitochoro) hoard (IGCH 237) has always been a problem for advocates of a late date for the cistophoric reform. For the hoard’s publication, see Price Reference Price and Rider1989, who adjusts the IGCH listing date of 168/7 to ca. 165. It contained a single cistophorus of Apameia (no. 241, Pl. LV). The existence of the coin had been reported in the Greek newspaper Estia in 1968, but the coin itself appeared in the British Museum only in 1979, with the accompanying story that it came from the hoard of 1968. According to Price (Reference Price and Rider1989, 240), it has the same “patchy black patina” as the hoard’s Perseus tetradrachms, but scholars on both sides of the debate now favor a prudent exclusion of the Sitochoro cistophorus from discussion: Meadows 2013, 181 n. 77; Marcellesi 2012, 134–35.

40 Ashton 1994; adopted by, e.g., Thonemann 2011b, 170; Kosmetatou 2003, 164; also Bresson 1996, 71 – though he no longer accepts Ashton’s arguments (personal comm.).

41 Part of the context for those hard times might have been the war with Prousias I and the Galatians referred to in the decree of Telmessos of 184/3, Segre Reference Segre1932 (Allen Reference Allen1983, no. 7).

42 As Marcellesi (2012, 134) points out, the reduced figure does not fit roundly into cistophori. Tietz (Reference Tietz2003, 312–13) recognizes the problem, but does not challenge Ashton’s theory. He sees in the letter of Eumenes II to Artemidoros a failed attempt to integrate Telmessos into the Pergamene monetary orbit. On the contrary, one could see flexibility and fiscal integration across monetary boundaries. Tietz’ conclusion that Telmessos fell squarely in the Rhodian zone is based on counts from the collection of the museum of Fethiye (Telmessos): ca. 600 of ca. 2,500 Hellenistic coins are Rhodian.

43 For ca. 175 as, in his view, the date of the introduction of the cistophorus, see Bresson 2018, 134.

44 Marcellesi 2012, 122–27, 149–54; Meadows 2013, 163–75.

45 On the portrait coins of Eumenes II, see Queyrel 2003, 144–46, boldly arguing that portrait style can confirm the date.

46 Meadows 2013, 184–86. Cf. Queyrel 2003, 146: the posture of the Dioscuri of Eumenes’ portrait coin interpreted as symbols of big-brotherly rule, with the figure to the right (Eumenes) leaning on the one to the left (Attalos), who meekly crosses his chest with an arm. On the other hand, the Kabeiroi, who are sometimes identified with the Dioscuri, are positioned identically on the ΘΕΩΝ ΚΑΒΕΙΡΩΝ ΣΥΡΙΩΝ coins. Despite the large differential in volume, Thonemann (2015a, 86) sees both as festival coinages.

47 Jenkins 1980, 186; Le Rider 1989, 173; Meadows 2013, 189.

48 Kinns 1999.

49 Cf. Allen Reference Allen1983, 110–11, who uses coinage to determine the tributary status of each city that minted 188–133.

50 Meadows 2013, 189–90: Temnos’ mint as an “active civic apparatus.” For Attalid control of Temnos, see RC 48 (D4). Temnos may also have been the recipient of the inscribed letter I.Sardis 2. In addition to these Alexanders of the 150s or 140s, Temnos, according to Seyrig (1973, 70), countermarked Alexanders of Alabanda of the mid-second century. The attribution of these grapes countermarks, however, has been questioned: for the coins and comment, see Meadows Reference Meadows, Meadows and Shipton2008, 73.

52 Cf. Psoma Reference Psoma and Thonemann2013, 271 n. 20.

53 For bibliography, see Callataÿ 2013, 233 Table 6.10.

54 Callataÿ 2013, 232–36.

55 For the debate on the meaning of the wreath, see Picard 2010, 175 n. 48, with earlier bibliography.

56 E.g., Kırıkhan (CH 1.87; 2.90), Aleppo (IGCH 1562), and Akkar (IGCH 1559).

57 Marcellesi 2012, 150.

58 Callataÿ 2013, 232–36. Compare also the individual Wreathed mints’ output (Kyme = 27.9, Herakleia = 22.5, Myrina = 26.2) with that of Pergamon, the largest cistophoric mint (20.3).

59 Rostovtzeff 1941, vol. 2, 658: “We can hardly suppose that the minting cities – important or unimportant – owned silver mines. It is more than likely that the metal was supplied to them by the kings, who, in all probability were the owners of the mines.” See also Rostovtzeff 1939. On Kyme, e.g., Kinns (Reference Kinns and Price1986, 169) emphasizes a transfer of bullion from Prousias II in the form of an indemnity.

60 Szaivert (2008, 34–37) compares cistophoric imagery to earlier Attalid coin iconography.

61 See, e.g., Kraay Reference Kraay1976, 356–57, nos. 600 and 601.

62 For the coin, see SNG München Lydien no. 695. For discussion, see Thonemann 2011b, 40–41, with n. 100 on bronze minted in name of Zeus Larasius (e.g., SNG München Lydien nos. 702–6). On its date, see Gökyıldırım Reference Gökyıldırım2016, nos. 842–46, assigning it to third to second century BCE.

63 Mørkholm (1979, 53–58) challenges the identification of Apameia as an early cistophoric mint. His view has not carried the day, but it is worth noting that he observes changes in the icon of the flute and argues that it does not belong to Marsyas.

64 Le Rider 1990, 685. Thonemann 2015a, 79: “city ethnics.” Cf. Marcellesi 2012, 145: “nom de différentes cités”; Bresson 2019, 294: “names of a series of cities.”

65 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 125.

66 In the case of Menas and Sestos, the new epichoric coinage was of course bronze.

67 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 125, with n. 19.

68 Meadows 2001, esp. 61–62; Meadows 2018, 298–301. Cf. Andrew Burnett et al. in RPC I, 1: coinage is a royal prerogative until the breakdown of kingdoms.

69 Picard 2010, 187.

70 Cf. on Roman cistophori, Butcher and Ponting 2014, 465–90, esp. 466. Although hindered by a lack of samples for metallurgical analysis, they note results that highlight the exceptionally high standard of fineness of cistophori of the second century BCE (96–98%).

71 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 120. For criticism, see Le Rider 1989, 186–88; Mørkholm 1979, 50–53. However, for support, see Bresson 2019, 294–95.

72 Cf. Callataÿ 2013, 228: “The amount of die sharing between mints strongly points to a single minting place for issues allegedly coming from different mints.” Similarly, see Kinns Reference Kinns and Price1986, 164.

73 Kleiner (Reference Kleiner1980, 50–51) suggests a third.

74 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 80–81.

75 Le Rider 1990, 697–99. Cf. Mitchell 1999, 25 n. 30, which places the south Phrygian cistophori in the wake of Sulla.

76 For the archaeological discussion, see Filges 2003, esp. 42.

77 For sources for Galatians at Sardis and Synnada, see Thonemann 2011b, 170–77.

79 The pi-alpha monogram was once read as Parion (Mørkholm 1979, 56–58), or as Apollonia-on-the-Rhyndakos (Kleiner Reference Kleiner1980, 48–51). But the communis opinio now reads it as Apameia – see here Le Rider 1990, 687–89; and Le Rider’s comments in Drew-Bear and Le Rider Reference Drew-Bear and Le Rider1991, 366–69, also for challenges to some of Kleiner’s attributions of certain obverses in the above sequence to Pergamon. Cf. Bresson 2019, 296, opting for Kleiner’s theory of a central mint at Pergamon serving Apameia, as well as less significant Sardis and Synnada.

80 See, e.g., Robert 1967, 87–105. Mackil and Van Alfen 2006 argue incisively (p. 227 n. 78) that die sharing implies centralization, but does not correspond to a particular state form.

81 Flament Reference Flament2010, 31–73.

82 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 88–89, 101, and 98 for the prediction that – one day – die links may substantiate the claim about Tralles and Laodikeia.

83 Ashton and Kinns Reference Ashton and Kinns2003, 46–47; Ashton 2016, 379, not ruling out a third-century date.

84 Carbone 2020, 1 n. 4.

85 See the weight tables of Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 128–29; for flans, 121.

86 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 52, 94. Kleiner 1972, 23: changing of guard from the reign of Attalos II to that of Attalos III is responsible for the anomaly. For regnal dates on the cistophori of Aristonikos/Eumenes III, see Robinson Reference Robinson1954.

87 Ephesus: Rigsby 1979. Pergamon: Kleiner 1978, 79.

88neve interesse quidquam putent, utrum Tralles an Formias venerint

89 Callataÿ (2013, 228) lists under “Tralles Half-Cistophori” 20 obverse and 30 coins, ECC lists 20 didrachm obverses and 25 coins. Note further the recent appearance of a cistophoric drachm of Tralles in the collection of Lydian Coins in the Istanbul Archaeological Museum, Gökyıldırım 2016, no. 722.

90 For the rare cistophoric hemidrachm in the form of fractional silver minted at Pergamon in the name of Athena Nikephoros, see Marcellesi 2012, 121–22.

91 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 122.

92 Callataÿ 2013, 228.

93 Thonemann 2011b, 170–71. Cf. Marcellesi (2012, 120), suggesting limited local initiative in the choice of denomination. On circulation, however, cf. CH IX 535 (Ahmetbeyli), from the territory of ancient Colophon, buried ca. 120. Of its 25 cistophoric tetradrachms, 15 come from nearby Ephesus – see Travaglini Reference Travaglini1997, 137–42. Similarly, IGCH 1415 (Afyonkarahisar), buried ca. 133: of 120+ cistophori, the 10+ described came from nearby Apameia.

94 Kleiner 1978. The drachms may have only begun ca. 125. See Marcellesi 2012, 184.

95 Kleiner 1978, 90.

96 Crawford Reference Crawford1985, 206–9.

98 Another example has turned up in commerce, reported in Valverde Reference Valverde2007, 34 n. 68.

99 Thonemann 2011b, 99–129.

100 French 2016b, 83; French 2016a, 52 for maps. This is what French calls the Tralles-Alabanda-Telmessos route.

101 French Reference French2012, 10 and milestone no. 6 for Tralles as station on the road of Aquilius with Ephesus as caput viae and Side as terminus.

102 Trans. Loeb. Φησὶ δὲ Ἀρτεμίδωρος ἀπὸ Φύσκου τῆς Ῥοδίων περαίας ἰοῦσιν εἰς Ἔφεσον μέχρι μὲν Λαγίνων ὀκτακοσίους εἶναι καὶ πεντήκοντα σταδίους, ἐντεῦθεν δ’ εἰς Ἀλάβανδα πεντήκοντα ἄλλους καὶ διακοσίους, εἰς δὲ Τράλλεις ἑκατὸν ἑξήκοντα· ἀλλ’ ἡ εἰς Τράλλεις ἐστὶ διαβάντι τὸν Μαίανδρον κατὰ μέσην που τὴν ὁδὸν ὅπου τῆς Καρίας οἱ ὅροι· γίνονται δ’ οἱ πάντες ἀπὸ Φύσκου ἐπὶ τὸν Μαίανδρον κατὰ τὴν εἰς Ἔφεσον ὁδὸν χίλιοι ἑκατὸν ὀγδοήκοντα.

103 For the problem of these puzzling measurements, see Radt 2002–11, ad loc. An interesting prosopographical link suggests itself in the figure of Apatourios of Alabanda, who Vitruvius (De arch. 7.5.5) tells us built the ekklêsiasterion at Tralles. Further, numismatic evidence from Aphrodisias tells a similar story. According to MacDonald (Reference MacDonald1992, 15), the circulation pattern of coins of Aphrodisias in the longue durée follows this route, from Caria to Lydia and Ionia along the roads of Maeander Valley. Only in late Roman times does Aphrodisian coinage flow east.

104 For the debated date of the introduction of the plinthophoros, see most recently Ashton 2005b.

105 Bresson 1993; Bresson 1996.

106 For Bresson 1993, the Rhodian zone is closed; pace Ashton 2001, 95–96, with personal observation from storerooms in Rhodes. For the regional pattern, cf. also IGCH 1330 (Priene), which contained both a Rhodian silver coin and a cistophorus of nearby Tralles. Unfortunately, the coin of Tralles cannot be located in Berlin and the denomination was not recorded (Karsten Dahmen, personal comm.). For disposition, see http://coinhoards.org/id/igch1330.

107 The persistence of the specialization of Tralles in fractions in Roman times can be explained by the persistence of the plinthophoric system in Caria, which was both outside the Roman province of Asia until after 84 BCE and full of autonomous civic mints. Eventually, the post-plinthophoric drachm on the so-called light Rhodian standard created a neat equivalence with the drachm of the cistophoric system, as documented in an inscription of the first century CE. See Carbone Reference Carbone2014, 28, with inscription from Kibyra IGR 4.915, a, lines 12–14.

108 Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 118–19, suggesting it is not a circulation hoard but a product of gradual accumulation. Important supplements in Onat Reference Onat1959 (http://coinhoards.org/id/igch1328): one didrachm of Ephesus and two uncertain didrachms.

109 For hoard methodology and circulation, see, Howgego Reference Howgego1995, 88–94.

110 For the movement of Roman soldiers on this road, see SEG XXXVII 1186 from Euhippe.

111 For Carian and Lycian revolts of 168, see Polyb. 30.5.11–16. In 167, the Senate ordered Rhodes to remove garrisons from Caunus and Stratonikeia, and then formally granted freedom to Caria and Lycia (Polyb. 30.21, 24). However, Rhodian influence on the mainland was not extinguished (see, e.g., Strabo 14.2.3; Cicero, Q.Fr. 1.1.33). For Caunus restored to Rhodes by Sulla, the Rhodian capture of Calynda in 163 with Roman confirmation (Polyb. 31.5.5), see, generally, Habicht 2006, 174–242. For the coins of independent Lycia before the First Mithridatic War, which remained on the Rhodian standard, see Troxell Reference Troxell1982 with Ashton and Meadows Reference Ashton and Meadows2008.

112 See, e.g., CH X 302, a hoard of 7+ Alabandan cistophori buried in 150 (from western Asia Minor?).

113 Errington Reference Errington2010, 129. See also the letter of Eumenes II to the Tabênoi (Guizzi Reference Guizzi2006; SEG LVII 1109). If the city is in fact Carian Tabai, the document is evidence of Attalid influence in the former Rhodian domain ca. 165. See Patrice Hamon BE (2009) no. 440. According to Livy (37.56.2), the Attalids had been granted the Carian district of Hydrela in 188, between the Maeander and the Lykos. See Magie Reference Magie1950, 762.

114 Meadows 2002, 99.

115 Ashton 2005a, 73. Cf. Callataÿ Reference Callataÿ and Descat2007, for whom this is a Roman proxy coinage from the First Mithridatic War.

116 The evidence of Aphrodisias is key here. See MacDonald Reference MacDonald1992, 17. Unfortunately, the weight standard of much of its first-century BCE silver (ca. 3.5 g = drachm) is unclear. Crawford (Reference Crawford1985, 160) mentions a small late-Hellenistic hoard of Aphrodisias. It contained coins of Tralles. Crawford also provides the following information: SNG von Aulock 7463, Pergamon, from before 134/3, worn; SNG Copenhagen 657, Tralles, ca. 100, fresh, two specimens.

117 Sargent and Velde Reference Sargent and Velde2002.

118 Kleiner’s numbers in ECC are 25 (n) and 20 (D), whereas the above numbers, 30 (n) and 20 (D), are taken from Callataÿ 2013, 228.

119 For methodology, see Carter Reference Carter1983.

120 Except for the figure for drachms, all figures from Callataÿ 2013, 228.

121 Kosmetatou’s unpublished study of the same coinage produced 4.47 (456/102) – see Callataÿ 2013, 236 n. 102.

122 Kaye Reference Kaye and Souza2013 collected 187 silver tetradrachms of Prousias II, but turned up just a handful of silver drachms. Similarly, the drachms are absent from Turkish museum collections, including those of the Bithynian heartland, surveyed by Güney Reference Güney2015.

123 For weights, see Ashton 1994, 59. Bresson is the chief advocate of the view that the “interoperability” of denominational systems does not imply that the ancients waved the exchange fee (agio). Rather, he adduces cases like that of Timon of Syracuse to show that one might – as a benefaction – wave it. See Bresson 1996 and 2001; but contra, see the arguments on mid-second-century Rhodian coinage of Apostolou Reference Apostolou1995. Kleiner’s point (1972, 31) that compatibility was not acceptability is helpful. He notes a cistophorus of Tralles now in Berlin, which was overstruck on a pre-plinthophoric didrachm of equal weight.

124 Picard 2006; Picard Reference Picard and Descat2009.

125 Migeotte and Kontorini Reference Migeotte and Kontorini1995.

126 Collections surveyed: SNG Copenhagen, American Numismatic Society, BMC, Arthur S. Dewing, SNG Leipzig, Jameson, Hunterian, and Waddington.

127 Discussion in Thonemann 2011b, 40 n. 100; see also Robert, OMS III, 290–91, for the possibility that bronze coins from Tralles signed Διὸς Εὐµενοῦ date from post-Apameian Attalid times. See also Marcellesi 2010, 199, who does not discuss this case in particular but argues for the appearance of numerous civic bronzes in the expanded Attalid kingdom after the cistophoric reform, even in places which had not coined before, e.g., Apameia, for which see Arslan and Devecioğlu Reference Arslan, Devecioğlu, Summerer, Ivantchik and von Kienlin2011. Note the loose date for several series of bronze of Tralles (second to first century BCE) offered by Gökyıldırım Reference Gökyıldırım2016, nos. 847–69.

128 Two examples of this countermark are known; the first is a tetradrachm of the New Athenian Style (ANS 1944.100.85073), for which see Bellinger Reference Bellinger1949, no. 5; Noe Reference Noe1954, 85; Thompson Reference Thompson1961 no. 184b. Until recently, an ethnic of Tralles was read: ΤΡΑΛΛΙ[ΕΩΝ]. Now, a second coin, a silver tetradrachm of Side, has surfaced on the market bearing the same countermark, as well as a cistophoric countermark of Sardis (Classical Numismatic Group, 364, Lot: 297, https://cngcoins.com/Coin.aspx?CoinID=299730). The second example makes clear that the still undeciphered legend cannot be read as an ethnic of Tralles.

129 Ashton and Kinns Reference Ashton and Kinns2003, 41–45. It is interesting to note here that the city of Pergamon under the Attalids employed a modified Aeolian calendar, while the royal chancery used the Macedonian calendar. See I.Pergamon 247 line 14 and 251 line 1, with Daubner 2008. For a discussion of calendrical diversity in Hellenistic federalism, see Graninger Reference Graninger2011, 87–114; cf. Savalli-Lestrade 2010.

130 The notion of an ancient Greek monetary anarchy dates to the nineteenth century. But see too Rostovtzeff 1941, 655, for a classic example. Regarding monetary supplicité, the vision here owes much to Francophone scholarship. See, e.g., Bresson Reference Bresson2005; Delrieux Reference Delrieux and Brun2007. It is becoming increasingly clear that many cities of the Attalid kingdom, as a matter of course, minted bronze and silver coins. Marcellesi 2010 provides a wealth of evidence of local minting at the lower range of value. Of particular interest here is the small silver (ca. 3 g) of Adramyttion and in the name of Athena Nikephoros (ca. 1.5 g).

131 For the worship of Zeus Eumenes at Tralles as a possible form of ruler cult, see Robert, OMS II, 287–91; however, for the suggestion that the cult, at least as it relates to the month Eumenaios in the Pergamene calendar, has nothing to do with the Attalids, see Daubner 2008. Further on the Attalids and Tralles, see Savalli-Lestrade 2001, 82–86.

132 Martin Reference Martin1985 provides a classic account of the relationship between sovereignty and coinage in ancient Greece, but his main focus is Thessaly under Philip II. The more recent study of Ziesmann Reference Ziesmann2005, largely confirming Martin’s conclusions, is also focused on the fourth century. Numismatists have begun to suggest that the second century BCE witnessed a transformation of the traditional, looser relationship between sovereignty and coinage, as outlined by Martin and Ziesmann. See Meadows 2001, 61–62, and the prolegomenon to RPC.

133 SEG XLVI 1434.

134 Mørkholm 1982, 301: “There can hardly be any doubt that the inspiration came from Egypt”; Marcellesi Reference Marcellesi2000, 330–31; cf. Rostovtzeff 1941, 1293–94: “The monetary policy of the Attalids was in many respects similar [to the Seleukids’]. Their own coinage was sound and abundant. Like the Seleucids they insisted on their monetary prerogative. But Eumenes II, in order to increase the issue of coined silver and thus to promote commerce, did not hesitate to grant several cities of his kingdom the right of minting under his control special uniform coins, the so-called cistophori, which soon became a Pan-Anatolian currency and circulated in large quantities both in Asia Minor and abroad. Nor did the Attalids differ from the Seleucids in their policy of allowing the local minting of small change.” See further Faraguna 2006, 132–36, comparing “open” and “closed” Hellenistic royal economies.

135 Le Rider and Callataÿ 2006, 113. Cf. Duyrat Reference Duyrat2014, 117–18, for the reverse argument: open systems as the norm and the Attalid zone as closed.

136 It must be noted that Marcellesi 2010 changed the contours of the debate, and my argument is largely in sympathy with hers. Marcellesi 2008, 250: “un système monétaire fermé. Les monnaies d’argent cistophorique sont désormais les seules qui aient cours à l’intérieur de l’État attalide … mais celui-ci n’atteint pas la rigidité du système lagide.” Fuller exposition of limits of closure in the Attalid system: Marcellesi 2012, 149–61. Rejection of Ptolemaic model: Meadows 2013, 196. Note, however, a harder closure – on a Rhodian model – proposed by Bresson 2018, 108–9, a major study too recent for adequate incorporation here.

137 Von Reden (2007, 43–45) has provocatively questioned the assumption of a deliberate design behind the Ptolemaic system. For her, the Ptolemies arrived almost haphazardly at their solution, which was a solution to the problem of monetizing rapidly huge volumes of metal. She characterizes the Ptolemaic system as a classic demonstration of the validity of Gresham’s law.

138 The exceptions are gathered in Cadell and Le Rider Reference Cadell and Le Rider1997, 10 n. 11. Only three out of 35 hoards from Ptolemaic Egypt deposited after ca. 300 contain foreign coins.

139 For an account of Ptolemy I’s minting, see Cadell and Le Rider Reference Cadell and Le Rider1997, 9–11.

140 For precious metal Ptolemaic coinage from hoards outside Egypt, see the table (of Meadows) in Appendix 1 of Von Reden 2007.

141 For the genre of royal order envisioned here, prostagma, see P.Cair.Zen. I 59021 line 14. For Ptolemy I’s general prohibition of the use of foreign coinage ca. 300, see Cadell and Le Rider Reference Cadell and Le Rider1997, 10. For the comprehensiveness of the ban, see the Olbia Coinage Decree, Syll.3 218 lines 13–16: “to buy and sell everything with the city’s coins, both the bronze and the silver of Olbia (πωλεῖν δὲ καὶ ὠν[ε]|[ῖσθαι] πάντα πρὸς τὸ νόµισµα τὸ τῆς [πόλ]ε̣ως, πρὸς τὸν χαλκὸν καὶ τὸ ἀργύριο[ν] [τὸ] Ὀλβιοπολιτικόν).”

142 See CLA line 61, which prohibits taxation on import and export of coinage. Does the prohibition imply its existence elsewhere? Just how strictly customs agents controlled monetary flow is difficult to gauge. Bresson 2007 likens the intensity of surveillance in ancient Mediterranean customs regimes to medieval European standards of enforcement. It may be helpful to note a striking example from the Cairo Genizah. Between Old Cairo and the port of Alexandria, a trader was forced to stop and make 45 different payments (Goitein 1967–93, vol. 1, p. 342). If we make this our model for Antiquity, it is not implausible to imagine customs agents of the second century BCE going so far as to search people for coins.

143 I recognize that the banking system changed over the course of the third century. By the end of the century, currency exchange was no longer the preserve of state-farmed monopoly banks, but for the earlier period, see the evidence of P.Rev. lines 73–78: only royal banks and state-farmed monopoly banks collected agio (allagê) on currency exchange (Bogaert 1998, 169). For an officially prescribed exchange fee, which varies in the papyri, hence my “about 10%,” see Bogaert 1984, 181–82. However, for the exchange rate (kollybos, at least in the papyri), we do not know if it was set officially, particularly since parts of the diagramma trapezôn of the P.Rev. are so fragmentary (Bogaert 1984, 184). For the vocabulary of exchange fees as opposed to exchange rates in ancient Greek banking, see Bogaert Reference Bogaert1968, 48–50; Bresson 2014.

144 Meadows 2013, 202–3.

145 See also the decree of Gortyn on bronze coinage, ca. 250–200 (Syll.3 525 = Austin 2006, no. 123). Gortyn voted to demonetize its silver obols and mandate the use of its bronze coinage. Again, this is a different, much stronger form of closure than the one we find in the Attalid kingdom.

146 Epigraphic record: Marcellesi 2012, 152–54.

147 Callataÿ 2013, 241–44.

148 Meadows 2013, 182; cf. Kleiner and Noe, Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 108, with date ca. 145–140.

149 Boehringer Reference Boehringer1972, 183: “Sollte die Vermutung der Herkunft des Hortes aus dem pergamenischen Grenzgebiet zutreffen, so ist man versucht, ihn mit den kriegerischen Ereignissen von 150–149 zu verbinden, in denen Attalos II. Kräftig mitmischte”; cf. Kleiner and Noe Reference Kleiner and Noe1977, 110: “As a rule, the cistophori did not leave Attalid territory, and it is almost certain that this hoard was buried in an area under Pergamene control.”

150 CH VIII gives a burial date of ca. 150–140 BCE, reproduced by Callataÿ 2013, 243: “near Ankara.” Türktaciri is about 100 km as the crow flies from Ankara. For a burial date not long after ca. 130, see Göktürk 1991.

151 On both Polatlı and Afyonkarahisar as related to campaigning, see Callataÿ 2013, 230.

152 The hoard record for Asia Minor of the mid- to late second century BCE is rather poor, which makes it difficult to generalize about hoarding practice. On the other hand, mixed hoards of any kind are very uncommon in IGCH for all of Asia Minor of the second century. A hoarding practice that separates epichoric from international coinages may be in evidence in a hoard of 25 cistophori from the territory of Colophon, buried ca. 120 (CH IX 535, Ahmetbeyli = Travaglini 1997, 137–42). Colophon was of course participating in a wider zone of circulation in this period, even if this hoard does not reflect it. Consider also the Muğla hoard (IGCH 1357; closed 84 BCE), republished in Meadows 2002 (CH X 324). Of all its 350+ silver coins of Rhodes and Stratonikeia in the Rhodian peraia, none belongs to Meadows’ “Group 1” of Stratonikeian coins, the subset of the city’s coinage that was minted on a standard that was compatible with both the Attic and cistophoric standards. According to Carbone 2020 (p. 33), as a rule, cistophori circulated (and were hoarded) unmixed from 133 until the 40s BCE. An exception is the aforementioned IGCH 1330 (Priene, ca. 125), which contained a single cistophoros among its 331 coins.

153 Antikythera: CH VIII 521, ca. 75–50 BCE, the only hoard of cistophori (late or early) to be found outside Asia Minor and, significantly, from a shipwreck.

154 There, the word “to exchange” is restored: κατ]αλλάτειν.

155 For Sestos: I.Sestos 1 lines 44–46 with Bresson 2016, 275–76. Was the official exchange rate set only against Attic-weight coinage? Bogaert (1984, 184) adduces the paradigm of the Olbia decree in discussing the possibilities for Ptolemaic Egypt. Olbia mandates an official exchange rate of one Olbian hemistater to one Cyzicene stater, making all other exchanges a matter of “persuasion.”

156 Marcellesi (2010, 198–200) raises the issue of the large number of civic bronze coinages the post-Apameian Attalid territory, though as she admits, it is not always possible for numismatists to agree on dates for these coins. The city of Apameia itself is a particularly interesting case, with some scholars dating at least one series to the period of Attalid control (obverse with Serapis, reverse of two piloi, a symbol shared with early cistophori in the name of the same city). See Ashton and Kinns Reference Ashton and Kinns2003, 46–47; Bresson 2019, 300.

157 The total premium postulated could be even higher if customs dues on imported coinage are added. For the conventional agio in ancient Greece, see Bogaert Reference Bogaert1968, 109, 115, for a norm of around 5%, slightly higher in the Delphic evidence (7–9.5%). See further on all three cases treated here, Le Rider and Callataÿ 2006, 112–14. Their view of the cistophoric system is the traditional one, which likens it to the Ptolemaic system and the experiment of Byzantium and Chalcedon, ca. 235–220. The Attalids are said to have taken a “tax au change” of 25%. For conventional rates of agio, as well as the standard assumption of a 25% premium for the cistophori, see Mørkholm 1982, 296, 301. See too an exchange fee of 25% on epichoric bronze for symmachic silver at mid-second century Thebes: SEG XLV 447.

158 This is the interpretation of Seyrig Reference Seyrig, Kraay and Jenkins1968 of the episode recorded in Polyb. 4.46–52. See further Russell Reference Russell2017, 119–32.

159 Callataÿ 2013, 234.

161 See Lewis Reference Lewis1962; Mattingly Reference Mattingly1971, 34–46, largely endorsing the low chronology of Lewis. See further, Mattingly 1990, and for a summary of the debate, Bresson 2016, 425 n. 43.

162 Picard 2010, 173. Thonemann 2015a, 126: dating of Thompson no. 184b to 144/3.

163 Cf. Thonemann (2015a, 126), “suggesting that Athenian coins had to be ‘validated’ in order to be used” in western Asia Minor. Yet the coin was in any case usable. The situation in the Attalid kingdom was not fundamentally different from Delphi of the Amphyctionic decree (Austin 2006, no. 125) – in both places the value of the coin was potentially ambiguous.

164 Cadell and Le Rider Reference Cadell and Le Rider1997, 18–19.

165 Marcellesi 2012, 127.

166 Marcellesi 2012, 157–58.

167 Chameroy Reference Chameroy2012, 145.

168 Cf. Evans Reference Evans2018, 129, introducing the notion of “Attalid 4-unit” and “Attalid 2-unit” bronze coins for two issues of Sardis (nos. 58 and 59; cf. figs. 2.12 and 2.13, the latter terming them Attalid), said to date from 188–133. However, there is no evidence for a specifically Attalid standard in bronze. On the contrary, the denominations of Attalid bronze, various fractions of the obol, conform to the pattern set by the regional civic mints, including Pergamon’s. See Marcellesi 2012, 75–77, 157–58.

169 See, e.g., the conclusion of Johannes Krauss in his edition of I.Sestos 1. He dates the civic minting episode of lines 44–46 to post-133, applying this rule of thumb. The same rule is applied throughout corpora such as BMC. However, cf. MacDonald (Reference MacDonald1992, 1) calling certain bronzes of Aphrodisias “pseudo-royal petty coinages.” More recent scholarship moves toward generic second-century dates. See, e.g., Gökyıldırım Reference Gökyıldırım2016, nos. 847–69 (Tralles); Aybek and Dreyer Reference Aybek and Dreyer2016, 12 (Apollonia-on-the-Rhyndakos); Ingvaldsen Reference Ingvaldsen, Aybek and Öz2010, 178, on bronze of Metropolis, allowing for possibility that his Type 1 Ares/Thyrsos is pre-133. Evans (Reference Evans2018, 24; 2019, 113) argues for continuous minting of bronze at the civic mint of Sardis across the Seleukid-Attalid transition.

170 Chameroy and Savalli-Lestrade Reference Chameroy and Savalli-Lestrade2016, 259–84.

171 Marcellesi Reference Marcellesi2000, 356. Of course, in Olbia, certain exchange rates were what was a matter of persuasion – and only Olbian coins were legal tender. Regarding the role of persuasion in currency exchange, see the case of the League of Islanders and the banker Timon of Syracuse (IG XII 5 817), as interpreted by Bresson 2001; Bresson 2014.

172 Meadows 2013, 202–3.

173 For a cistophoric frontier, see Psoma Reference Psoma and Thonemann2013, 272.

174 Colophon: Meritt Reference Meritt1935, 358–72, no. 1, with commentary of Migeotte 1992, 219. Teos: SEG XLIV 949 Column III lines 71–102.

175 Thus in Olbia the penalty for noncompliance was the confiscation of goods; in Gortyn, armed youths called neotai enforced a coinage reform (Syll.3 525).

176 OGIS 484. Cf. the incident of clandestine currency exchange in Mylasa, 209/10 CE (OGIS 515). Mylasa gained important revenues from its monopoly on exchange. Private, illegal exchange threatened the city’s fiscal stability. See the discussion of Bogaert Reference Bogaert1968, 266–68.

177 Cf. Kleiner 1972, 32 n. 30: “The Attalid silver must have had a higher value within Pergamene territory than outside it.” That postulate requires another – the postulate of the cities’ cooperation, which was absolutely necessary to enforce the overvaluation of the cistophori.

178 Mackil and van Alfen Reference Mackil, van Alfen and van Alfen2006, 204.

179 Mackil and van Alfen Reference Mackil, van Alfen and van Alfen2006, 220; Mackil 2013, 264–84.

180 Mackil and van Alfen Reference Mackil, van Alfen and van Alfen2006, 204. Cf. Mackil 2013, 264, on Antigonid Macedonia.

181 One can see the different economic orientations of these regions in the history of their coinages. Pamphylia, oriented toward the Levant, is obviously an outlier in the Attalid kingdom. The Propontis displays distinctive features, such as the typically Pontic use of electrum and frequent use of countermarking. For the Maeander Valley, consider again IGCH 1330, from a house in Priene, buried ca. 125. It includes 329 bronze coins of Priene, epichoric bronze for local needs, but also one silver coin of Rhodes, and one cistophorus of Tralles, an important Maeander city. The hoard is a witness to the region’s coherence, vaunted in Thonemann 2011b, as well as to its contiguity to the Rhodian zone.

182 On local elites in Asia Minor and Hellenistic kings, see Dreyer and Weber Reference Dreyer and Weber2011. For the enrichment of the great civic benefactors of second-century Asia Minor, see Thonemann 2011b, 249–51; and further on the leading families of Priene, Kyme, and Miletus, see Grandinetti Reference Grandinetti, Capdetrey and Lafond2010.

183 Levi Reference Levi1988, esp. 48–70.

184 For the vexed problem of dating these two Seleukid countermarks of the second or third quarter of the second century, see Le Rider Reference Le Rider1999, 229–33. Le Rider cautiously dates them to the years following 175, while for Bauslaugh (Reference Bauslaugh1990, 55–56), the hoard evidence points to ca. 170. Bauslaugh also presents the evidence of overstrikes (anchor countermarks struck over cistophoric countermarks), our only evidence for a slightly later date for the Seleukid countermarks. For the two countermarking systems in relation, see also the recently published hoard of silver tetradrachms from Uşak (CH X 293), which contained ca. 19 coins with cistophoric countermarks, but just one bearing the anchor.

185 Waggoner Reference Waggoner1979 no. 79 = Bauslaugh Reference Bauslaugh1990, 41, pl. 4 no. 1. For discussion of date of Propontis hoard, which has floated between ca. 180 and ca. 160, see Harl Reference Harl1991, 277–78.

186 Marinescu Reference Marinescu, Kluge and Weisser2000, 334–35: “The countermarking of Attic coins which Seyrig placed at ca. 235 BC can now be shown to be part of a long standing tradition at Byzantium, which began by countermarking Ptolemaic tetradrachms. … Therefore the countermarking of Attic weight coins must have commenced around 235 BC and seems to be a direct continuation of the same policy which first used Ptolemaic coinage.” Note also a different set of countermarks from Byzantium and Chalcedon that seem to be later than Seyrig’s “Phoenician episode.” Marinescu (Reference Marinescu, Kluge and Weisser2000, 335) places one countermark from Byzantium in the last decade of the third century. Moreover, the Propontis hoard (IGCH 888) contained two countermarks of Byzantium and one of Chalcedon. Seyrig himself dated the Byzantine ones 220–190. See discussion of Waggoner Reference Waggoner1979, 23–24.

187 Thonemann 2008, 59.

188 This entire phenomenon of civic countermarks on Attic-weight coinage – of, e.g., Kyme and Alabanda – is poorly understood, though obviously crucial for any understanding of the monetary system of the Attalid kingdom. Noe Reference Noe1954 was the first to flag the issue. See also Seyrig 1973, 70, on the Tyche and grape cluster countermarks of the Tell Kotchek hoard (IGCH 1773). Meadows Reference Meadows, Meadows and Shipton2008 dates these countermarks to the 140s.

189 Seyrig Reference Seyrig, Kraay and Jenkins1968; Le Rider 1975.

190 See the Büyükçekmece hoard (IGCH 867).

191 Russell Reference Russell2017, 124; see also p. 131, on the comparability of the cistophoric system.

192 The sources for the indemnity are Polyb. 21.43.20–21 and Livy 38.38.14. Bauslaugh Reference Bauslaugh1990, 63, and in substantial agreement, Meadows 2013, 172; also tempted to make the connection is Callataÿ 2013, 225, recalling the suggestion of Meadows 2009 that these Attic-weight Pamphylian coins were already a Seleukid “proxy coinage.” However, contra the indemnity hypothesis, see Bresson 2018, 74–75.

193 No one doubts that the indemnity was burdensome, which is the thrust of the literary sources, but see the caution of Le Rider 1993. Further on indemnities, see Meissner Reference Meissner, Burrer and Müller2008; Ungern-Sternberg Reference Ungern-Sternberg, Coudry and Humm2009.

194 Bauslaugh Reference Bauslaugh1990, 64.

195 The flow of Attic-weight silver from western Asia Minor to northern Syria is well documented in the hoards. For its relation to the long-term, incremental increase in the price of silver, see Bresson Reference Bresson2005, 58–63; Bresson 2016, 263–64. For countermarking as way to economize on silver, see already Le Rider 1975, 44; Szaivert 1983, 37. However, neither model gives the coordinating role of the Attalids its due.

196 Bresson Reference Bresson2005, 62–63.

197 Callataÿ 2006, 39. Callataÿ et al. (Reference Callataÿ, Depeyrot and Villaronga1993, 92) estimate that one-third of the volume of silver coinage in circulation in the Hellenistic world at the beginning of the third century was in Rome by the end of the second century. To judge the effect of this withdrawal on the supply of silver (coin or bullion), it is necessary to have an idea of the amount of bullion in the system. Callataÿ 2006 concludes that only a paltry amount of bullion was coined. A typical Hellenistic king would have had an estimated 70% of his store of precious metal in bullion, 55% in silver bullion. Cf. Panagopoulou Reference Panagopoulou2007, 335, on the “proliferation of silver during the Hellenistic period.”

198 Consider that the Seleukids’ gradual reduction of the Attic standard in the second century was accompanied by an increase in the number of coins produced. See Duyrat Reference Duyrat2014, 118–19.

199 Le Rider Reference Le Rider1999, 225–26. This 2% descent had already occurred elsewhere when Antiochos IV began to reduce. Before the end of his reign, it is observed only at the mint of Antioch; cf. the full 10% descent for the silver coinage of Perseus, noted by Dahmen Reference Dahmen, Roisman and Worthington2010, 54.

200 Thonemann 2015a, 127. See further Grandjean Reference Grandjean2007, esp. 21, on the spectacular size of the symmachic coinage in the Peloponnese in this period and the question of silver scarcity.

201 Fineness of 96–98% silver: Butcher and Ponting 2014, 466.

202 For the pace of cistophoric production, the evidence is based around IGCH 1453. See Meadows 2013, 182–83.

203 Cf. Meadows 2013, 152: “Like the Ptolemaic kings, or the cities of Byzantium and Chalcedon, the Attalids possessed no natural source of silver within their realm.” Thonemann (2015a, 80) sees the shuttering of Macedonian silver mines in 167 and “external supplies of silver drying up” as an impetus for launch of cistophori. Already, Will (1962, 99 n. 48) writes of a supposed lack of silver deposits in the Attalid kingdom and modern Turkey (!). Importantly, Bresson (2005, 60) points out that the cistophori have no bearing on whether the Attalids lacked silver. Note also that the Rhodian plinthophoros was heavier than earlier Rhodian and pseudo-Rhodian coins, hence the expression argyrion rhodion lepton (lightweight Rhodian silver coins) in the Mylasa leases, for which see Descat and Pernin 2008.

204 Strabo’s source is Kallisthenes (BNJ 124 F 54). For skepticism, see Sommerey Reference Sommerey2008, 139.

205 Troad: Panagopoulou Reference Panagopoulou2007, 318 n. 10; also, on the Troad and provenance analysis for ancient silver, see Pernicka Reference Pernicka2014, 154–59. For the pseudargyros of Andeira: Strabo 13.56.1, though the location of Andeira is debated – see I.Adramytteion I, 71–74. For early travelers, see Cook Reference Cook1973, 298–318: in 1740, Pockocke noted silver, lead, copper, and alum mined near the present-day village of Üsküfçü, in the Skamandros Valley, northwest of the Çığrı Dağ. This is the site of classical Neandria. Winter 1985, studying the fortifications, suggests that some reoccupation followed the late fourth-century abandonment of the site. The study of Schulz Reference Schulz2000 of the walls indeed identifies a second phase with associated habitation. By contrast, Maischatz Reference Maischatz2003 concludes decisively that both phases belong to the fourth century. However, ancient mines need not have been associated with settlements. Mines may even have discouraged permanent occupation.

206 Bayburtoğlu and Yıldırım Reference Bayburtoğlu, Yıldırım and Yalçin2008.

208 Pernicka et al. Reference Pernicka, Seeliger, Wagner, Begemann, Schmitt-Strecker, Eibner, Oztunali and Baranyi1984, 540. For Wiegand (Reference Wiegand1904, 264–71), the remains at Balya represented the site of Pericharaxis. The identification of Balya as Pericharaxis is often repeated in the literature, e.g., Gentner et al. Reference Gentner, Gropengiesser and Wagner1980, 180, and Panagopoulou Reference Panagopoulou2007, 318. However, see RE, s.v. Pericharaxis. See also Pernicka et al. Reference Pernicka, Seeliger, Wagner, Begemann, Schmitt-Strecker, Eibner, Oztunali and Baranyi1984, 548, for Kastel Kadıkalesi, 5 km north of Balya, a site Wiegand himself explored, as Pericharaxis.

209 Rostovtzeff Reference Rostovtzeff, Buckler and Calder1923, 367; Magie Reference Magie1950, 804–5; cf. Cary Reference Cary1932, 141 n. 4, who presumes that “Bulgar-Maden” was active ca. 246 BCE, seemingly confusing a place in Cappadocia with one in Mysia. Kovenko Reference Kovenko1940 lists Balya as one of the largest lead deposits in the world before 1914. See Oy Reference Oy2017, 13. In an October 2017 conference paper entitled, “Mining History of Balya Pb-Zn Deposit” (https://docplayer.biz.tr/155385604-Oztunali-2017-and-metallurgy-symposium-abstract-book.html), Ahmet Baştürk and Selman Aydoğan assert that mining activity began at Balya in the Classical period and was active in the Roman period.

210 See Kallet-Marx Reference Kallet-Marx1995, 11–41; Eckstein 2012, 371.

211 Le Rider 2001.

212 On all of these examples from Asia Minor, see Delrieux Reference Delrieux and Brun2007. The case of Kyme (BMC Troas 109, no. 58) is especially interesting. Under Antiochos I or II, Kyme minted tetradrachms with royal portrait/Herakles that share control marks with a more straightforwardly civic series, one which seems to bear the face of the Amazon of Kyme and certainly the identifying mint mark ΚΥ. We even possess a story of royal proxy minting in the lore of Kyme recorded in the excerpta politiarum of Heraklides Lembos (37): “They say that Hermodike, wife of Midas king of the Phrygians, was exceptionally beautiful, but also wise and skilled. They say that she was the first to mint coins for the people of Kyme” (Ἑρµοδίκην δὲ γυναῖκα τοῦ Φρυγῶν βασιλέως Μίδα φασὶ κάλλει διαφέρειν, ἀλλὰ καὶ σοφὴν εἶναι καὶ τεχνικὴν καὶ πρώτην νόµισµα κόψαι Κυµαίοις).

213 The Chiliomodi hoard (IGCH 85) included 14 drachms of Corinth and 12 of Ptolemy I, all fresh and sharing the mintmark ΔΟ. See Martin Reference Martin1985, 179–84. Consider also the possible civic origin of so-called Peloponnesian Alexanders (Troxell 1971).

214 SNG Copenhagen 4; BMC Thessaly to Aetolia 195, nos. 9–11; Noeske Reference Noeske, Bringmann, von Steuben, Ameling and Schmidt-Dounas2000, pl. 30, no. 6.

215 Noeske Reference Noeske, Bringmann, von Steuben, Ameling and Schmidt-Dounas2000 makes a laudable if perhaps quixotic attempt to use metallurgical analysis to unveil royal proxy coinage.

216 Callataÿ 2011b. Whatever reservations one may have about the absolute figures that Callataÿ has produced, his scale is a major contribution to scholarship and a powerful tool of analysis.

217 On the late cistophori as “hidden power” of Rome, see Carbone 2020, 14–34.

218 Meadows 2009.

219 See Meadows and Houghton Reference Meadows, Houghton, Hoover, Meadows and Wartenberg2010, esp. 185 (chart).

220 Note the two silver tetradrachms and two silver drachms of Myrina recently published from the Arikantürk collection (SNG Turkey 9), Tekin and Erol-Özdizbay 2017, nos. 503–6. All coins are said to have been purchased in Burhaniye, ancient Adramyttion.

221 Ahmetbeyli: CH IX 535. Cf. Marcellesi 2010, 200: “Quoi qu’il en soit, les tétradrachmes à la couronne ne font pas véritablement partie de la histoire monétaire du royaume attalide.” See also Jones Reference Jones1979, for whom the Wreathed Coinages are a response to the cistophori. On the Wreathed Coinages as a coinage solely for export, see Psoma Reference Psoma and Thonemann2013, 277.

222 Meadows 2001, 59–60; Mørkholm 1965; Ecker et al. Reference Ecker, Finkielsztejn, Gorre, Honigman, Syon, Feyel and Graslin-Thomé2017, 194, emphasizing the active role of civic mints in the short-lived experiment.

223 Thonemann 2015a, 171–72. Livy 45.18: in quattuor regiones discribi Macedoniam. Yet discribere should mean “distribute/divide into parts,” and need not imply the original creation of the parts, for which see, e.g., Livy 31.14.2. Suspicion of Livy’s testimony began with the study of the Larissa hoard (IGCH 237), deposited in or soon after 168/7. It contained six tetradrachms of the First Meris, while the Romans are thought to have closed the gold and silver mines of Macedonia until 158. Ultimately, we have been forced to recognize that the Roman merides were based on much older administrative divisions. (corroborative epigraphic evidence in Hatzopoulos 1996, vol. 1, pp. 231–60). Recently, ever more Meris coinage has been updated to the late Antigonid period. See esp. Kremydi-Sicilianou Reference Kremydi-Sicilianou2007; Prokopov Reference Prokopov2012; and for a summary of recent scholarship, Dahmen Reference Dahmen, Roisman and Worthington2010, 55. A further point of comparison for the phenomenon of coordinated coinage is the Mithridatic bronze coinage minted in large quantities in the name of Pontic cities. See Callataÿ 2011a.

224 For the sources for this war, see Mitchell 1993, vol. 1, p. 26; Ma 2013a, 77–82.

225 Polyaenus, Strat. 4.8.1, with no firm date for the incident. For Eumenes at Apameia, see the inscription announced by Drew-Bear Reference Drew-Bear1975, 357.

Figure 0

Figure 3.1 Silver tetradrachm of Eumenes II minted in the name of Philetairos, Westermark Group VII.

(16.35 g, ANS 1944.100.43195; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 1

Figure 3.2 Silver tetradrachm of Side minted ca. 210–190 BCE, bearing countermark of bow-in-case + ΠΕΡ.

(15.91 g, ANS 2015.20.1206; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 2

Figure 3.3 Cistophoric silver tetradrachm of Pergamon, ca. 160–150 BCE.

(12.58 g, ANS 1951.5.13; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 3

Figure 3.4 Cistophoric silver didrachm of Tralles, ca. 145–140 BCE.

(5.91 g, ANS 1944.100.37564; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 4

Figure 3.5 Cistophoric silver drachm, ca. 134–128 BCE.

(2.58 g, ANS 1984.5.35; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 5

Figure 3.6 Standing serpent on reverse of large module (hemiobol?) bronze coin in the name of Philetairos, ca. 270s–200 BCE.

(4.27 g, BNF Fonds général 1486; courtesy of Bibliothèque nationale de France)
Figure 6

Figure 3.7 Fragmentary bedroom scene from the Telephos Frieze with standing serpent warning hero and Auge.

(T.I. 37, © Antikensammlung, Staatliche Museen zu Berlin – Preussischer Kulturbesitz; Photo: Johannes Laurentius)
Figure 7

Figure 3.8 Silver tetradrachm of Eumenes II, ca. 166–162 BCE.

(15.24 g, BM 1849,0717.10 © The Trustees of the British Museum)
Figure 8

Figure 3.9 Silver tetradrachm in the name of Athena Nikephoros, reign of Eumenes II, ca. 180–165 BCE.

(16.06 g, BM 1975,0208.1 © The Trustees of the British Museum)
Figure 9

Figure 3.10 Silver drachm of Ephesus with legend “of the Ephesians,” ca. 150 BCE.

(4.02 g, BNF Fonds général 511 = Kinns 1999 obverse 70; courtesy of Bibliothèque nationale de France)
Figure 10

Figure 3.11 “Wreathed” silver tetradrachm of Myrina, ca. 160–135 BCE.

(14.51 g, ANS 1944.100.44235; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 11

Figure 3.12 Cistophoric silver tetradrachm of Ephesus, ca. 150–140 BCE.

(12.58 g, ANS 1944.100.37502; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 12

Figure 3.13 Proconsular cistophoric silver tetradrachm, signed by C. Pulcher and Aristokles, 55–53 BCE.

(11.95 g, ANS 1959.48.6; courtesy of the American Numismatic Society)
Figure 13

Map 3.1 The Maeander Valley and Rhodian Caria.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • The King’s Money
  • Noah Kaye, Michigan State University
  • Book: The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
  • Online publication: 02 March 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009279567.004
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • The King’s Money
  • Noah Kaye, Michigan State University
  • Book: The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
  • Online publication: 02 March 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009279567.004
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • The King’s Money
  • Noah Kaye, Michigan State University
  • Book: The Attalids of Pergamon and Anatolia
  • Online publication: 02 March 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009279567.004
Available formats
×