Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-2xdlg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-13T16:49:54.982Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

9 - Getting reform right in agriculture

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 June 2010

Yiping Huang
Affiliation:
Australian National University, Canberra
Get access

Summary

Agricultural reform from an institutional perspective

What was wrong with pre-reform agricultural institutions?

In the pre-reform period, the Chinese government adopted a heavy-industry oriented development strategy to catch up with and overtake the major capitalist economies in a short period. Under this strategy, economic institutions were framed to mobilise resources for heavy-industrial development. Control of foreign exchange, depressed interest rates and mandatory resource allocations were examples of policy measures introduced to facilitate this development strategy.

Agriculture was seen as the major supplier of resources required for industrial development. To facilitate resource flows from agriculture to industry, a set of agricultural institutions was established exhibiting three major features – an inward-looking approach, the unified purchase and marketing system and the collectivisation of agricultural production.

An inward-looking approach was the only possible choice for the government at that time. After the Communists took power in 1949 and the Kuomintang were driven to the tiny Taiwan, Western countries led by the United States adopted a policy that economically and politically blockaded mainland China. The Soviet Union and Eastern Europe was the only bloc with which China could trade, and at the time it was pursuing the same development strategy.

The inward-looking approach was also driven by the chosen development strategy. China was a large, densely populated developing country at the beginning of the 1950s. China would never be able, within a short period, to develop its heavy industry so as to participate in the international division of labour, as its comparative advantage clearly lay in labour-intensive manufacturing. To achieve its development objective, the government essentially had to cut off linkages between China and the world economy.

Type
Chapter
Information
Agricultural Reform in China
Getting Institutions Right
, pp. 156 - 170
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×